I'm reposting this ezine issue on good and bad reasons to oppose NAFTA and
Fast tract.

The Progressive Response is a publication of Foreign Policy In Focus, a
joint project of the Interhemispheric Resource Center and the Institute for
Policy Studies. 

Erik Leaver
Interhemispheric Resouce Center

THE PROGRESSIVE RESPONSE

Vol. 1, No. 4 Tom Barry, editor

***Issues of Debate: Assessing the Impact of NAFTA***


Trade Balance Tactics

Opponents of NAFTA, on both the left and the right, cite the current U.S.
trade deficit with Mexico as a sign that NAFTA has negatively impacted the
United States. It is certainly true that the U.S. now imports more goods
from Mexico than it exports to Mexico. In 1996 the United States suffered a
$16.2  billion trade deficit with Mexico, whereas in 1993 it experienced a
$1.7 billion surplus. Although those concerned about unemployment, poverty,
and low wage levels in the United States should examine the state of U.S.
trade in their attempt to find the causes of economic instability and job
losses at home, they should not adopt the dogma that a trade deficit with
Mexico means more unemployment in the United States.

When considering the U.S. trade deficit with Mexico, it should be
recognized that, while Mexico in 1995 and 1996 did export more to the
United States than it imported from this country, overall trade with Mexico
has expanded substantially since 1993. Despite the economic crisis in
Mexico, U.S. exports to Mexico have expanded by more than a third during
the first three years of NAFTA. It is not that the United States is
exporting less to Mexico than it did before, only that U.S. imports from
Mexico have increased faster than U.S. exports to Mexico.

It would be wrong to attribute the present status of U.S.-Mexico trade
balance primarily to NAFTA for the following reasons:

* Overall U.S.-Mexico trade was on the increase even before NAFTA.

* In the 1982-1991 period the U.S. experienced a persistent trade deficit
with Mexico.

* U.S. export growth to Mexico is largely related to the state of the
Mexican economy.

* The 1994 economic crisis in Mexico--in which consumption dropped
15%--helps explain why U.S. exports to Mexico did not rise as rapidly as
previously projected.

* The steady GDP increase in the U.S. has created increased demand for
goods and supplies, boosting the level of Mexican exports to the United
States.

Given that the balance of trade between Mexico and the U.S. is closely to
the state of the economy in each country, it is likely that the current
trade status will change. Consequently, arguments in favor or against NAFTA
based primarily on the size of the deficit or surplus are unlikely to stand
the test of time. Indeed, as the Mexican economy slowly recuperates, its
trade surplus is falling dramatically. The latest figures from Mexico show
that its total imports have increased by 27 percent while exports have also
increased although more slowly--but still at a healthy rate of 15 percent.
Those NAFTA opponents in the United States who point to the 1995-96 trade
deficit with Mexico may be left on shaky ground in a year or two as that
deficit turns into a surplus.

Similarly, more caution is needed in basing one's opposition to NAFTA on
reported or calculated job losses. For starters, it should be recognized
that the United States has experienced both relatively low unemployment and
economic growth since the NAFTA took effect. Opposing NAFTA on the basis of
the state of traditional economic indicators--GDP growth, unemployment,
trade balance, etc.--is a difficult argument to make, especially at this
time of comparatively good economic health in the United States.

There are two approaches to the job loss discussion that should be regarded
with caution. The first is the facile adoption of a Commerce Department's
multiplier that holds that $1 billion in increased exports creates 20,000
new U.S. jobs. By applying this multiplier to the trade deficit (which
implies that all Mexican imports take U.S. jobs and that this deficit is
due to NAFTA), the Economic Policy Institute concluded that the increase in
the U.S. trade deficit since 1993 has cost the United States 251,000 jobs.
As noted previously, this approach fails to recognize that, while the
United States may be experiencing a deficit with Mexico, its exports
continue to increase. Weintraub calls all the manipulations using
export/job multipliers "primitive arithmetic," pointing out that 1)
merchandise trade is only one part of the balance of payments and does not
include the export of U.S. services, 2) imports do not automatically
translate into job losses, 3) decreased Mexican exports would decrease
Mexico's ability to purchase U.S. products, thereby adversely affecting
U.S. jobs, 4) as a global trader, the U.S. should expect deficits with some
countries and surpluses with others, and 5) a substantial part of North
American trade is not in final products but in components of final products.

It is true that during the NAFTA debate the U.S. trade surplus with Mexico
was cited as a sign that the United States was creating jobs in the U.S.
economy at the expense of Mexico, using the export/jobs multiplier as the
proof. This was faulty argumentation as many NAFTA opponents rightly
observed at the time. However, now that the trade balance has temporarily
shifted, NAFTA opponents have opportunistically latched on to the
multiplier argument as evidence that NAFTA is hurting the United States.
This is specious argumentation and should be rejected.

The ostensibly more persuasive argument that NAFTA is costing the United
States jobs is based on figures from the Trade Adjustment Assistance (TAA)
program,  under which 128, 253 U.S. workers have received assistance
because they have lost their jobs either because of production relocation
or imports from Mexico. Public Citizen and the AFL-CIO argue that this
figure is just the tip of the iceberg, since the criteria for TAA are too
strict. It is certainly true that many workers have been affected adversely
by production shifts and changing trading patterns between Mexico and the
United States. This was true before NAFTA and continues to be true, and it
is also true that globalization of production results in a downward
pressure on wage scales. But this does not necessarily mean that the United
States has suffered a net job loss because of NAFTA. Clearly, U.S. jobs are
also being created as a result of more integrated North American economic
relations, although there is no parallel way to measure jobs created. Put
another way, the TAA figure clearly shows that some  U.S. workers have lost
jobs as a result of North American trade and investment patterns, but it's
not valid to use this figure to justify statements that NAFTA has resulted
in a net job loss for the U.S. work force when other U.S. workers have
gained jobs because of those same changing patterns. It may certainly be
true that the United States has experienced a net job loss because of
U.S.-Mexico trade and investment patterns, but opponents should acknowledge
that jobs are also being created.

Other points that Weintraub makes to support his contention that NAFTA has
been good for both Mexico and the United States include:

* Increases and decreases in trade cannot be attributed solely to NAFTA,
considering that even before NAFTA the trade preferences granted by the two
countries were not significantly different.

* Increased Mexican exports to the U.S have helped that country to pay off
debts to the United States.

* Without NAFTA, Mexico would have likely raised its import tariffs in an
effort to stem the 1994 balance-of-payments crisis, which would have
lowered U.S. exports and slowed the growth in overall trade.

* It is true that increased maquiladora production in Mexico has resulted
in localized hardships for U.S. workers who have lost their jobs, but it
should be remembered that 50 percent of the value of maquiladora production
comes from U.S.-supplied inputs and that if the opportunity to establish
production-sharing facilities (maquilas) in Mexico did not exist many
companies would likely shift all their production facilities overseas.

In any fight against free-trade globalization, it will also be necessary to
respond to Weintraub's assessment of NAFTA as being good for the consumer.
He concludes his progress report with this observation: "One should not
lose sight of an elementary point that is often forgotten. An import duty
is a tax on the consumer. If one believes in lower taxes, NAFTA moves
modestly in this direction. If one believes in the importance of a
competitive market, NAFTA encourages this. If one believes in consumer
sovereignty, NAFTA stimulates this."

There is a dangerous tendency among progressives in the United States to
side with U.S. producers rather than U.S. consumers and to assume an
ultranationalist posture. Unless one supports total national self-reliance,
there are self-evident benefits of trade (both intranational and
international). Too often progressives have lent support to industries,
particularly agroindustries like those that produce sugar, tomatoes, and
avocados, in the name of fair trade and U.S. workers. Such industries
operate behind costly protectionist tariffs and quotas, denying U.S.
consumers lower prices and foreign economies a source of foreign exchange.
Progressives should be cautious about protecting noncompetitive industries,
especially when restricting imports shifts the burden to consumers.

A Progressive Agenda

In making the case against the corporate agenda of free trade, progressives
need to steer clear of the mercantilist perspective that Weintraub outlines
and adopt a more internationalist approach. This does not mean that U.S.
workers and consumers should accept a downward harmonization of wages and
standards, but it does mean that any campaign for upward harmonization must
accept that U.S. businesses, workers, and consumers--are not the primary
victims of the current trends in economic globalization. Because of its
position in the global economy and its associated political influence in
international affairs, the United States more often benefits than loses in
the new configuration of economic relations. This is not to say that there
are not many negative consequences of NAFTA and other free trade accords
but only to acknowledge the privileged position of the United States when
compared, for example, with a country like Mexico.

If the corporate agenda of economic globalization, which NAFTA is certainly
a part of, is to be successfully opposed,  it will require enlightened
cooperation across borders. Ultranationalist positions that demand that the
U.S. government protect all sectors of the economy against foreign
competition undermine such alliances. This has become particularly clear in
the NAFTA evaluations that focus on documenting the "giant sucking sound"
while failing to look at the entire picture of U.S.-Mexico relations.

We must think globally. During the first three years of NAFTA, the United
States has enjoyed comparatively good economic health. Arguments that NAFTA
is hurting the United States at a time when Mexico has endured one of the
most severe economic crises in its entire history will not have much
resonance in Mexico and are not a good basis for establishing cross-border
citizen alliance. NAFTA opponents in the United States must take care not
to paint the United States as the main victim of regional economic
integration. It is simply not true. Pointing to the U.S. trade deficits
with Mexico and Canada and imputing job losses to these deficits portrays a
false picture of the winners and losers of free trade.

The facts of the economic relations of the United States with Mexico must
be kept clearly in mind when considering the impact of NAFTA:

* Mexico's merchandise exports to the U.S. constitute about 25% of its GDP,
whereas U.S. merchandise exports to Mexico are less than 1% of the U.S. GDP.

* Mexico's GDP is less than 5% of the U.S. GDP.

In Mexico, as in the United States, any evaluation of NAFTA should extend
beyond standard economic indicators to an examination of the economic
models on which the regional free trade accord is premised. In Mexico, the
country's leaders have dropped all pretense of directing economic
development and have instead hitched Mexico's economic welfare to the
vagaries of the global marketplace and in particular to U.S. capital and
trade. In the United States, the country's economic welfare is also
increasingly a function of the U.S. place in the global economy, and U.S.
political leaders wrongly assume that  aiding the overseas expansion of
corporate America is the most effective way to improve  the welfare of the
entire nation.

The ideological commitment to the benefits of the open regional marketplace
is much the same for the two nations. But as the world's economic
powerhouse, the United States stands in a much better position than Mexico
to shape this economic integration to the benefit of its leading economic
actors, namely the transnational corporations that control most regional
trade.

It is true that certain sectors of U.S. business have been affected
adversely and certain workers have seen their jobs transferred to Mexico.
But this does not mean that NAFTA has had an overall negative impact on
trade, investment, consumer prices, and job creation. Expanding NAFTA and
giving President Clinton fast-track authority for additional free trade
agreements should be opposed but without resorting to mercantilist
measurements of success or failure.

More than a trade treaty, NAFTA is, as Weintraub observes, a "framework of
economic relations" between the United States, Canada, and Mexico. As such,
it is a model for other frameworks of regional and international economic
relations. NAFTA should be opposed by policymakers and citizens because it
is a framework for economic globalization that privileges the interests of
large corporations and does not adequately consider the impact of these
economic relations on the environment and labor. It and  similar free trade
accords should be opposed because they  accelerate the forces of
corporate-driven globalization, thus making it ever more difficult for
countries (both those of the North and the South) to establish the basic
ground rules for sustainable development in this new era of globalization.

Before moving forward with further liberalization of trade and investment,
U.S. policymakers and citizens should make certain that they--and not the
transnational corporations--are the ones who formulate the framework of
economic development. The imperatives of profit-taking and market expansion
need to be conditioned by policies and regulations that ensure the common
good. Otherwise, these agreements will facilitate the downward
harmonization of labor, environmental, and consumer standards.

The framework of  economic relations that prioritizes the common good
should not and cannot be one that is anti-market or anti-business. But it
must be constructed to ensure environmentally sustainable and equitable
development. Specifically, this means:

* Creation of  a context for economic relations that includes a safety net
for those who are marginalized by the international market, including
assistance and retraining for those who lose their jobs because of relocation.

* Integration of labor and environmental standards into the heart of trade
agreements.

* Generation of funds through taxes on cross-border commercial and
financial transactions that can serve to provide adjustment assistance to
communities adversely affected by alterations in production and trading
patterns.

* Recognition that trade agreements should not necessarily be completely
reciprocal, meaning that they recognize that less developed nations will
likely need longer tariff phase-out periods and more regulations regarding
foreign investment and capital flows.

* Enforcement of guarantees that relocating companies adequately compensate
host communities for services, training, financing, and facilities they
have provided and that such companies supply fair notice and severance
benefits to workers.

* Strong support and advocacy for international standards and treaties on
human rights, labor rights, and natural resources that will serve as a
counterweight to corporate pressures for downward harmonization.

Weintraub is right that many of the arguments used as rallying calls
against regional economic integration are rubbish and narrowly
nationalistic. But he is wrong in his belief that NAFTA-style globalization
is, despite local hardships, good for the overall global economy and society.

Sources for More Information:

Center for Strategic and International Studies (CSIS) Email: (202) 775-9199
Website: http://www.csis.org

Sidney Weintraub NAFTA at Three: A Progress Report Center for Strategic and
International Studies, 1997

Economic Policy Institute Email: [EMAIL PROTECTED] Website:
http://epinet.org See: (Trade Deficit, Job Losses Soar since NAFTA)
epinet.org/tf970219.html

Global Trade Watch Public Citizen Email: [EMAIL PROTECTED] Website:
http://www.citizen.org/pctrade 
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
To subscribe to the Progressive Response, send an email to:
[EMAIL PROTECTED] with the words "join newusfp" in the body of the
message. Alternatively, if you do not wish to receive The Progressive
Response, please send an email message to [EMAIL PROTECTED] with the words
"leave newusfp" in the body of the message.

Visit the Foreign Policy In Focus website, http://www.zianet.com/infocus,
for a complete listing of "In Focus" briefs and text versions of the
briefs. To order policy briefs, our book "Global Focus: A New Foreign
Policy Agenda 1997-98", or for more information contact the
Interhemispheric Resource Center or the Institute for Policy Studies.

IRC (Orders/Information) Voice: (505) 842-8288 Fax: (505) 246-1601 Email:
[EMAIL PROTECTED] Contact: Erik Leaver

IPS (Information) Voice: (202) 234-9382 Fax: (202) 387-7915 Email:
[EMAIL PROTECTED] Contact: Martha Honey







Reply via email to