The ECONOMIST on U.S. productivity growth.

2002-05-10 Thread Devine, James

[Interestingly, the ECONOMIST doesn't mention the role of the over 4%
average annual increase in the nominal major-currencies trade-weighted value
of the dollar -- or over 5% in real terms -- during the period 1996 to 2001.
This is a key factor that would hurt profits despite rising productivity.]

May 11, 2002

FINANCE  ECONOMICS
To these, the spoils

NOT only has America's productivity wonder survived its first recession; it
has positively thrived. Output per man-hour in the non-farm business sector
rose at an annual rate of 8.6% in the first quarter of this year, its
fastest growth in 19 years. Quarterly figures are volatile, yet the
year-on-year growth in productivity was also impressive, at 4.2%. This bodes
well for America's future economic growth--but not necessarily for company
profits, or for share prices.

Commentators cheered the latest evidence of rapid productivity gains, hoping
that it might promise fatter profits ahead. That America's productivity
continued to rise last year, in contrast to previous recessions, seems to
confirm that an increase has taken place in trend productivity growth.
Still, the latest numbers overstate the underlying trend.

First, the growth in output, and hence productivity, was inflated in the
first quarter by a big swing in inventories. Productivity often surges in
the first year of a recovery after recession, as firms produce more without
needing to hire extra workers. Productivity rose by 4-5% in the first year
following both the 1981-82 and the 1990-91 recessions. Firms have actually
continued to cut jobs this year, lifting the unemployment rate in April to
an eight-year high of 6%. Today's best guess is that trend productivity
growth is around 2-2.5%. That is less than the 3-4% claimed at the height of
the new-economy bubble; but still well above the 1.4% average over the two
decades to 1995.

A second, more fundamental quibble is that, although profits will certainly
rebound this year, as firms continue to trim their costs and revenues rise,
in the longer term faster productivity growth does not automatically mean
faster profits growth. A new study by Stephen King, chief economist at the
HSBC bank, concludes that workers and consumers have received the lion's
share of the productivity gains of therevolution in information technology
(IT). Companies have received relatively little reward for their
risk-taking.

In the late 1990s it was widely assumed that faster productivity growth
would mean higher profits (so justifying higher share prices). Over the
previous half-century a strong positive relationship had indeed held between
productivity and profits. In the 1990s that relationship broke down. Despite
a surge in productivity, national-accounts profits (as opposed to profits
reported by companies, a less accurate measure) fell between 1997 and 2000,
even before the economy dipped into recession (see chart). At the end of
2000 the profits of America's non-financial firms were no higher in real
terms than in 1994, implying a big fall in their share of GDP.

Mr King argues that workers (who are, naturally, also consumers) were
virtually the sole beneficiaries of the new economy, in the shape of faster
real wage growth. This was partly thanks to a fall in the prices of IT goods
that they bought. More important, the same IT that spurred productivity also
increased competition more widely across industries, from airlines and
banking to insurance and cars, squeezing prices and profits. Information
technologyreduces barriers to entry, and makes it easier for consumers to
compare prices.

What is more, globalisation, itself spurred by information technology, has
further trimmed the pricing power of firms. HSBC finds that, in most
economies, the correlation between domestic inflation and domestic
unit-labour costs has declined over the past 40 years; the correlation
between domestic inflation and average OECD inflation has risen. In most
countries in the 1990s domestic inflation was more closely correlated with
OECD inflation than it was with domestic costs.

The dismal performance of profits should not surprise. As the IMF's World
Economic Outlook last October pointed out, productivity gains from previous
technological revolutions, from railways and textiles to electricity and the
car, have gone largely to consumers. Each time, a decline in the prices of
goods and services has given a big boost to real incomes. Consumers gained
from cheaper travel or clothes, but profits disappointed. The difference
this time is that new technology has increased competition and squeezed
profit margins across the whole economy.

None of this lessens the overall benefit of faster productivity growth. But
it does lead to some interesting conclusions:

* The profit expectations built into share prices are unrealistic. Even if
productivity growth remains robust, long-term profits growth is likely to be
weaker than expected, making shares overvalued.

* A lower return on equities means 

Re: The ECONOMIST on U.S. productivity growth.

2002-05-10 Thread miychi
On 2002.05.11 02:08 AM, "Devine, James" [EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

 [Interestingly, the ECONOMIST doesn't mention the role of the over 4%
 average annual increase in the nominal major-currencies trade-weighted value
 of the dollar -- or over 5% in real terms -- during the period 1996 to 2001.
 This is a key factor that would hurt profits despite rising productivity.]
 
 May 11, 2002
 
 FINANCE  ECONOMICS
 To these, the spoils
 
 NOT only has America's productivity wonder survived its first recession; it
 has positively thrived. Output per man-hour in the non-farm business sector
 rose at an annual rate of 8.6% in the first quarter of this year, its
 fastest growth in 19 years. Quarterly figures are volatile, yet the
 year-on-year growth in productivity was also impressive, at 4.2%. This bodes
 well for America's future economic growth--but not necessarily for company
 profits, or for share prices.
 
 Commentators cheered the latest evidence of rapid productivity gains, hoping
 that it might promise fatter profits ahead. That America's productivity
 continued to rise last year, in contrast to previous recessions, seems to
 confirm that an increase has taken place in trend productivity growth.
 Still, the latest numbers overstate the underlying trend.
 
 First, the growth in output, and hence productivity, was inflated in the
 first quarter by a big swing in inventories. Productivity often surges in
 the first year of a recovery after recession, as firms produce more without
 needing to hire extra workers. Productivity rose by 4-5% in the first year
 following both the 1981-82 and the 1990-91 recessions. Firms have actually
 continued to cut jobs this year, lifting the unemployment rate in April to
 an eight-year high of 6%. Today's best guess is that trend productivity
 growth is around 2-2.5%. That is less than the 3-4% claimed at the height of
 the new-economy bubble; but still well above the 1.4% average over the two
 decades to 1995.
 
 A second, more fundamental quibble is that, although profits will certainly
 rebound this year, as firms continue to trim their costs and revenues rise,
 in the longer term faster productivity growth does not automatically mean
 faster profits growth. A new study by Stephen King, chief economist at the
 HSBC bank, concludes that workers and consumers have received the lion's
 share of the productivity gains of therevolution in information technology
 (IT). Companies have received relatively little reward for their
 risk-taking.
 
 In the late 1990s it was widely assumed that faster productivity growth
 would mean higher profits (so justifying higher share prices). Over the
 previous half-century a strong positive relationship had indeed held between
 productivity and profits. In the 1990s that relationship broke down. Despite
 a surge in productivity, national-accounts profits (as opposed to profits
 reported by companies, a less accurate measure) fell between 1997 and 2000,
 even before the economy dipped into recession (see chart). At the end of
 2000 the profits of America's non-financial firms were no higher in real
 terms than in 1994, implying a big fall in their share of GDP.
 
 Mr King argues that workers (who are, naturally, also consumers) were
 virtually the sole beneficiaries of the new economy, in the shape of faster
 real wage growth. This was partly thanks to a fall in the prices of IT goods
 that they bought. More important, the same IT that spurred productivity also
 increased competition more widely across industries, from airlines and
 banking to insurance and cars, squeezing prices and profits. Information
 technologyreduces barriers to entry, and makes it easier for consumers to
 compare prices.
 
 What is more, globalisation, itself spurred by information technology, has
 further trimmed the pricing power of firms. HSBC finds that, in most
 economies, the correlation between domestic inflation and domestic
 unit-labour costs has declined over the past 40 years; the correlation
 between domestic inflation and average OECD inflation has risen. In most
 countries in the 1990s domestic inflation was more closely correlated with
 OECD inflation than it was with domestic costs.
 
 The dismal performance of profits should not surprise. As the IMF's World
 Economic Outlook last October pointed out, productivity gains from previous
 technological revolutions, from railways and textiles to electricity and the
 car, have gone largely to consumers. Each time, a decline in the prices of
 goods and services has given a big boost to real incomes. Consumers gained
 from cheaper travel or clothes, but profits disappointed. The difference
 this time is that new technology has increased competition and squeezed
 profit margins across the whole economy.
 
 None of this lessens the overall benefit of faster productivity growth. But
 it does lead to some interesting conclusions:
 
 * The profit expectations built into share prices are unrealistic. Even if
 productivity 

Re: U.S. productivity

1997-12-10 Thread Jim Davis

How exactly are these productivity figures arrived at?

jd

---

There was a question the other day about productivity performance in the
U.S. Here are some numbers, current through last week's downward revision
of the 1997Q3 stats. Though there was a bounce in the 1997Q2  Q3 figures,
performance over the whole cycle is underwhelming.








Re: U.S. productivity

1997-12-09 Thread Doug Henwood

Tom Walker wrote:

Isn't this one for the entire period, rather than an annual average?

93Q1-97Q3   4.3% 15.3%  (Clinton years)

Ooops. Yeah. In fact the whole bottom half of that table was mislabeled.
Here's the way it should read. A thousand apologies.

Doug



U.S. LABOR PRODUCTIVITY
---
all nonfarm business and manufacturing, through 1997Q3


AVERAGE ANNUAL GROWTH RATE BY PERIOD
  nonfarm   manuf'g
1947-52
1952-57   2.7%
1957-62   2.2%
1962-67 3.2%  2.7%
1967-72 2.2%  3.9%
1972-77 2.1%  2.9%
1977-82 0.0%  1.1%
1982-87 1.9%  3.9%
1987-92 1.1%  2.1%
1992-97 0.8%  3.0%

1950-60 2.5%  2.2%
1960-70 2.5%  2.6%
1970-80 1.9%  2.9%
1980-90 1.1%  2.8%
1990-97 1.1%  3.1%


CUMULATIVE GROWTH
93Q1-97Q3   4.3% 15.3%  (Clinton years)
1991-97Q3   1.1%  3.1%  (1990s expansion)

26Qs after:*
49Q4   19.2% 15.6%
54Q2   13.6% 12.3%
58Q2   23.3% 21.6%
61Q1   26.4% 23.8%
70Q4   17.5% 24.2%
75Q19.3% 13.9%
82Q49.9% 21.3%
91Q18.6% 23.8%

*length of current expansion; starting points are previous business cycle
troughs









Re: U.S. productivity

1997-12-09 Thread Tom Walker

Isn't this one for the entire period, rather than an annual average?

93Q1-97Q3   4.3% 15.3%  (Clinton years)

Regards, 

Tom Walker
^^^
knoW Ware Communications
Vancouver, B.C., CANADA
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
(604) 688-8296 
^^^
The TimeWork Web: http://www.vcn.bc.ca/timework/






U.S. productivity

1997-12-09 Thread Doug Henwood

There was a question the other day about productivity performance in the
U.S. Here are some numbers, current through last week's downward revision
of the 1997Q3 stats. Though there was a bounce in the 1997Q2  Q3 figures,
performance over the whole cycle is underwhelming.

Manufacturing is doing a lot better than services, though this may be the
result of contracting out a lot of service activities that no longer appear
in the manfuacturing sector.

A brief commercial announcement: it takes a lot of time  effort to keep
these numbers current. If you don't already subscribe to LBO, hey why not
do it now, and help keep this little enterprise going.

U.S. LABOR PRODUCTIVITY - AVERAGE ANNUAL GROWTH RATE BY PERIOD
all nonfarm business and manufacturing, through 1997Q3

  nonfarm   manuf'g
1947-52
1952-57   2.7%
1957-62   2.2%
1962-67 3.2%  2.7%
1967-72 2.2%  3.9%
1972-77 2.1%  2.9%
1977-82 0.0%  1.1%
1982-87 1.9%  3.9%
1987-92 1.1%  2.1%
1992-97 0.8%  3.0%

1950-60 2.5%  2.2%
1960-70 2.5%  2.6%
1970-80 1.9%  2.9%
1980-90 1.1%  2.8%
1990-97 1.1%  3.1%

93Q1-97Q3   4.3% 15.3%  (Clinton years)
1991-97Q3   1.1%  3.1%  (1990s expansion)

26Qs after:*
49Q4   19.2% 15.6%
54Q2   13.6% 12.3%
58Q2   23.3% 21.6%
61Q1   26.4% 23.8%
70Q4   17.5% 24.2%
75Q19.3% 13.9%
82Q49.9% 21.3%
91Q18.6% 23.8%

*length of current expansion; starting points are previous business cycle
troughs

Doug

--

Doug Henwood
Left Business Observer
250 W 85 St
New York NY 10024-3217 USA
+1-212-874-4020 voice  +1-212-874-3137 fax
email: mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
web: http://www.panix.com/~dhenwood/LBO_home.html