Liberation, November 2000
Published by CPI(ML)


Reading Lenin’s Imperialism in Y2K

-Dipankar Bhattacharya

Next only to The Manifesto of the Communist Party, Lenin’s Imperialism,
the Highest Stage of Capitalism has proved to be the second most
insightful tract of the modern times. Written in the midst of the First
World War, Imperialism had the privilege of being overwhelmingly
vindicated within a few months. To bypass the tsarist censor, Lenin was
constrained to adopt an uncharacteristically oblique style in writing
this classic, which he later described as ‘that accursed Aesopian
language’. “It is painful, in these days of liberty, to re-read the
passages of the pamphlet which have been distorted, cramped, compressed
in an iron vice on account of the censor”, remarked Lenin in his April
1917 preface to the text which was written between January and June
1916. Yet this pain was amply rewarded as those cramped and compressed
passages went on to spring the historic surprise of the world’s first
victorious socialist revolution in November 1917.
Lenin had succeeded in not only helping his readers ‘to understand ...
the economic essence of imperialism ... and appraise modern war and
modern politics’, he had also shown the revolutionary way of outsmarting
imperialism by breaching the imperialist chain at its weakest link. The
history of the first half of the twentieth century was the history of
the incredible transformation of tsarist Russia into the Union of Soviet
Socialist Republics. An epochal product of the First World War, the
Soviet Union went on to overpower the fascist onslaught of the Second
World War, before being done in eventually by the insidious logic of the
Cold War. Meanwhile, the continuing scientific and technological
revolution has given imperialism a new lease of life; it has acquired a
new look, and even a new name - ‘globalisation’! The air is thick with
talks of a dramatic transition from the monotonous ‘old economy’ to a
mesmerising ‘new economy’. And, to be sure, a re-reading of Lenin’s
Imperialism at this juncture can once again offer a whole range of most
illuminating clues to the economic and political dynamics of the new
era. The recent reprint of Imperialism by LeftWord Books is therefore a
most timely move. The thought-provoking introduction by Prabhat Patnaik
is an added bonus.
In Imperialism, Lenin’s objectives were twofold. First, he had to
identify the economic essence of imperialism, to show that imperialism
did neither reflect the bad habits of certain nations nor was it a
matter of ‘preferred policy’ of capitalism under certain circumstances,
rather it constituted a special stage of capitalism itself. In the
process, he also exposed what he called the ‘ultra-nonsense’ of
Kautsky’s thesis of ultra-imperialism or super-imperialism, and revealed
the depth of imperialism’s crisis and the severity of inter-imperialist
rivalries. Second, he had to show the organic link between imperialism
and the rise of opportunism in the working class movement or between
imperialist superprofit and the bribing of not just a thin stratum of
labour aristocracy but a considerable minority of workers of imperialist
nations.
In pursuing both these objectives Lenin drew enormously on the whole
range of available literature on imperialism and on the Marxist analysis
of capital and colonialism, British colonialism in particular. If Marx
had laid bare the material basis of what he called commodity fetishism
by focussing particularly on the role of one key commodity -
labour-power - in the genesis of surplus value, the key categories for
Lenin in Imperialism were monopoly and finance capital. Indeed, the
journey from Capital to Imperialism is a journey towards ever-greater
concentration of production and centralisation of capital; it is an
analytical transition from competition to monopoly, from the export of
goods to the export of capital, from ‘normal’ profit (surplus value) to
superprofit, from the domination of capital in general to the domination
of finance capital. But this transition did not mean any fading of the
essential Marxist focus on the underlying crisis of capitalist anarchy
stemming from the insoluble contradiction between the social nature of
production and private character of appropriation.
Interestingly, Lenin designated imperialism as the highest, and not just
the latest, stage of capitalism. He called it moribund, parasitic and
decaying, yet he made it abundantly clear that “it would be a mistake to
believe that this tendency to decay precludes the rapid growth of
capitalism,” and that indeed “on the whole, capitalism is growing far
more rapidly than before.” In other words, moribund capitalism is
perfectly capable of experiencing bouts of rapid growth now and then,
and here and there, but this growth would not add up to a qualitatively
new or post-imperialist stage of capitalism.
It is this predictive value or definitiveness of Lenin’s analysis, which
is nowadays questioned by many theorists of globalisation who would like
us to believe that globalisation has ushered the world into a new
post-imperialist phase of democratic capitalism where we have all the
brilliance of the capitalist motion described by Marx and Engels in The
Manifesto of the Communist Party, but none of the horror of Lenin’s
Imperialism. The same bourgeois writers who would dare to repackage and
celebrate Marx as the original guru of globalisation are bent upon
banishing Lenin and his analysis of imperialism as an ancient
aberration! They conveniently forget that if the Manifesto talks of
‘constant revolutionising of production’, ‘everlasting uncertainty’ and
‘cosmopolitan character of production and consumption’, it also
emphatically points to the other side of the capitalist coin where we
have ‘epidemic of over-production’, ‘enforced destruction of productive
forces’ and ‘universal war of devastation’, propelling capitalism
inexorably to its eventual collapse. And the edifice of Lenin’s analysis
of imperialism was erected on this Marxist logic of capitalist wealth
progressively stretching and outgrowing the narrow limits of bourgeois
society.
How well do the key features of Lenin’s analysis of imperialism
correspond to the emerging contours and dimensions of globalisation? Let
us begin with Lenin’s assertion concerning monopolies permeating and
dominating every field of the economy and society. The monopolies have
attained greater heights with the rise of MNCs/TNCs and their routine
practice of mega-mergers and acquisitions. With the spectacular growth
of communication technology and especially the mind-boggling rise of the
Internet, we were of course told that monopoly would fast become
technologically obsolete or redundant. But with the biggest billionaire
of the world having just been legally indicted as the latest
computer-aided and Net-borne monopolist of our times, the non-monopoly
illusions can surely be given a decent burial!
Lenin had written Imperialism decades before the appearance of the
Bretton Woods twins, the World Bank and the IMF, not to mention the
subsequent debt crisis and the devastating domination of the Fund-Bank
establishment. Yet in Imperialism, Lenin already traces the growth of
capitalism into a world system of not just colonial oppression but also
‘the financial strangulation of the overwhelming majority of he
population of the world by a handful of ‘advanced’ countries’ (preface
to the French and German editions); he talks of the usurer state and
usury imperialism (a term he used for French imperialism), of the
division of the world between a handful of usurer states and creditor
countries and ‘the rest of the world (which) is more or less the debtor
to and tributary of these international banker countries’. From ‘these
international banker countries’ to the rise of multilateral lending
institutions, the world capitalist economy has surely covered a
considerable distance, but the dynamics of usury imperialism were
anticipated quite accurately way back in 1916.
Let us also look at the contemporary discourse on the relative loss of
sovereignty or autonomy of nation-states. This loss is certainly
relative, neither absolute nor universal. In other words, the loss of
autonomy on the part of the overwhelming majority of states is of course
a reflection of the accumulation of ‘excessive autonomy’ or
interventionist powers around the remaining tiny minority of states, as
demonstrated so arrogantly by the phenomenon of global policing by the
US whether in the institutional guise of the UN or alliances like the
NATO. While focussing on the politics and economics of ‘redivision’ of
colonial possessions, Lenin’s Imperialism also notes the growing trend
of finance capital subjecting to itself ‘even states enjoying the
fullest political independence’ thereby giving rise to middle categories
like semi-colonies and other forms of combination of political
independence and financial and diplomatic dependence.
 The buzzword of the global economy today is finance and it is often
argued that by its sheer volume and velocity, and the resultant
speculative thrust, today’s finance has moved worlds away from the
finance capital of Lenin and Bukharin. Even Prabhat Patnaik describes
finance today as “an altogether different totality, ... an altogether
different entity.” He cites three basic differences - (i) finance has
decisively outgrown its national moorings, (ii) it has moved away from
production to speculation, and (iii) it operates in the context of
pan-imperialist collusion rather than inter-imperialist rivalry. Before
we examine Patnaik’s points (i) and (iii), let us consider his second
point dealing with the growing speculative forays of finance capital. It
is wrong to suggest that Lenin saw finance capital as a predominantly
productive coalescence of bank capital and industrial capital. There are
several passages in Imperialism where Lenin locates finance capital in a
non-industrial or speculative setting. Take, for example, this
extraordinary reference to speculation in land - “Speculation in land
situated in the suburbs of rapidly growing big towns is a particularly
profitable operation for finance capital. The monopoly of the bank
merges here with the monopoly of ground-rent and with monopoly of the
means of communication ...”
While endorsing Bukharin’s phrase of coalescence of bank capital and
industrial capital, Lenin also approvingly cited the German bourgeois
economist Kestner who had observed ‘a certain change  ... from
commercial activity in the old sense of the word towards
organisational-speculative activity’. “Translated into ordinary human
language this means”, Lenin added, “that the development of capitalism
has arrived at a stage when, although commodity production still
‘reigns’ and continues to be regarded as the basis of economic life, it
has in reality been undermined and the bulk of the profits go to the
‘geniuses’ of financial manipulation. At the basis of these
manipulations and swindles lies socialised production; but the immense
progress of mankind, which achieved this socialisation, goes to benefit
... the speculators.” He also quoted this admission by Liefman, ‘an
unblushing apologist of capitalism’: ‘In all probability mankind will
see further important technical revolutions in the near future which
will also affect the organisation of the economic system’ ...
electricity and aviation ... ‘As a general rule, in such periods of
radical economic change, speculation develops on a large scale.’ The
most recent Nasdaq nosedive following the dotcom frenzy of venture
capital has once again amply borne out Liefman and Lenin.
There are also categorical references in Imperialism to the organic
overlapping of productive investment and speculative investment and the
increasingly complete isolation of the rentiers from production.
Referring to the distinction made by E. Aghad, author of Big Banks and
the World Market (1914), between ‘productively’ invested capital
(industrial and commercial undertakings) and ‘speculatively’ invested
capital (in Stock exchange and financial operations), Lenin attributed
this dichotomy to the author’s petty-bourgeois reformist point of view
which made him think “that it is possible, under capitalism, to separate
the first form of investment from the second and to abolish the second
form.” Pointing to the immense accumulation of money capital in a few
countries, Lenin explained the “extraordinary growth of a class, or
rather, of a stratum of rentiers, i.e., people who live by ‘clipping
coupons’, ... whose profession is idleness” and showed how “the export
of capital, one of most essential economic bases of imperialism, still
more completely isolates the rentiers from production and sets the seal
of parasitism on the whole country that lives by exploiting the labour
of several overseas countries and colonies.”
Another analytical cornerstone of Imperialism is the completion of the
territorial division of the whole world among the biggest capitalist
powers, which continually necessitates war for achieving redivision of
the world’s resources.  Indeed, Lenin wrote this pamphlet in the midst
of the First World War, which was followed within two decades by an even
more devastating Second World War. Since then we have not however seen a
third world war in that old form and the air is thick with illusions of
a war-free, carefree capitalism finally entering a phase of permanent
peace and durable democracy.
Here it is important to grasp the economic context of war - in the
memorable phrase of the Manifesto it is ‘universal war of devastation’,
war as a means of achieving forced periodic destruction of productive
forces to be followed by hectic economic reconstruction and
reorganisation. It is also imperative to understand the dialectical
inter-relation between war and peace, war growing within and out of
peace. From the point of view of the political economy of war, the war
industry/economy or what has come to be known as the
military-industrial-scientific complex is no less important than the
actual execution of war. If between them, the two actual world wars had
led to a substantial redivision of the world and a significant redrawing
of the world map alongside massive doses of destruction and
reconstruction, the net outcome of the Cold War and the periodically
erupting local wars has been no less spectacular.
Like the epidemic of over-production mentioned in the Manifesto, the
epidemic of over-speculation we see nowadays also has the demonstrated
potential of engineering enormous landslides of capital. Huge chunks of
finance worth billions of dollars can be, and have indeed been, wiped
out overnight paving the way for large-scale actual realignments of
industrial capital. From the trauma of capitalist restoration in Russia
to the tremors in the East and South-East Asian ‘tiger’ economies
following the recent bouts of currency turmoil to the ongoing spectacle
of ‘public sector disinvestment’ in our own country, the essential rules
of the game of capitalist restructuring were brilliantly summed up by
Lenin in Imperialism: “During periods of industrial boom, the profits of
finance capital are immense, but during periods of depression, small and
unsound businesses go out of existence, and the big banks acquire
‘holdings’ in them by buying them up for a mere song, or participate in
profitable schemes for their ‘reconstruction’ and ‘reorganisation’.”
Now, to return to Patnaik’s points (i) and (iii), he argues that even
though finance is drawn from particular nations, “(it) is neither
amenable to the control or discipline of any nation-state, nor engaged
in promoting any definable ‘national interest’.” The difficulties being
faced by the weak third world nation-states and even by some developed
countries of Europe in tackling the volatility of finance capital are
indeed well-known, but does Patnaik really mean to say that global
finance has started playing truant with the control or discipline
mechanism of the world’s most powerful nation-states, the US in
particular, or that finance has acquired a truly supra-national interest
overriding the supreme national interest of the US? Such a proposition
would  indeed be too sweeping to be treated as tenable by any serious
student of conttmporary world economics and politics unless one is
prepared to be taken in  by the statastical deception of facts like the
us figuring  as the world’s biggest debtor country.  Similarly, his
assertion regarding finance operating in the context of a very
noticeable unity among the leading capitalist players would also seem to
fly in the face of the widely admitted breakdown of the notorious
Washington Consensus.
The technological environment,  and  particularly the technological
milieu of finance capital has indeed undergone a sea change. But the
growing autonomy of finance from production and its sweeping mobility
across national frontiers have by no means insulated it from the
underlying crisis of capitalism. If anything, globalisation of finance
has only led to a heightened and globalised crisis, sharply exposing the
inherent mismatch between the narrow conditions of bourgeois society and
the enormity of wealth and want. After all, finance cannot be infinitely
self-generating or self-sustaining; it is parasitic capital, and at the
end of the day, it has to have some corespondence, however intricately
mediated, with the real economy of production. It takes one realty
check, one major hike of oil prices by the OPEC countries to reassert
the primacy of the ‘real’ over the ‘virtual’.
After asserting that finance today is ‘an altogether different totality,
... an altogether new entity’ from Lenin’s time, Patnaik of course tries
to distance himself from any possible ultra-imperialist misreading of
contemporary reality on the lines of Kautsky’s thesis of
super-imperialism based on internationally united finance capital.
Lenin’s basic argument against Kautsky’s lifeless abstractions of
ultra-imperialism was that the latter would “serve exclusively a most
reactionary aim: that of diverting attention from the depth of existing
antagonisms” and encourage “that profoundly mistaken idea which only
brings grist to the mill of the apologists of imperialism, i.e., that
the rule of finance capital lessens the unevenness and contradictions
inherent in the world economy, whereas in reality it increases them.”
Under globalisation, the fundamental processes and trends of capitalism
described and analysed in the whole range of Marxist classics from the
Manifesto to Imperialism have become much more acute and intense. The
spectacular growth of information and communication technology has
facilitated the new flexi-time, flexi-place approach to work which in
turn has paved the way for a major intensification of the process of
generation and appropriation of surplus by breaking the limits of a
fixed working day and working place and blurring the hitherto
established distinctions between home and place of work or between
leisure and work. Finance capital has acquired unprecedented volume and
mobility, but only to lead to financial meltdowns and currency turmoils.
Computers have rewritten the ways people communicate, but only to lend
new cyber-expressions to the inherent anarchy and everlasting
uncertainly of the capitalist economy. The world today has to live with
sudden attacks of one lethal computer virus after another and only the
other day that gnawing global doubt about Y2K compatibility overshadowed
a lot of euphoria and hype of the new millennium.
Many tested and trusted tools of world capitalism have also started
yielding diminishing returns if not turning into their opposites. In
Imperialism, Lenin, for example, quoted the financial magnate Cecil
Rhodes who had candidly confessed way back in 1895 that “The Empire, as
I have always said, is a bread and butter question. If you want to avoid
civil war, you must become imperialists.” Lenin subverted this lethal
logic of war by actually turning an imperialist war into a revolutionary
civil war and now a Vietnam war is opposed right inside the US more out
of bread and butter nationalist concerns rather than noble feelings of
internationalist solidarity. The MNCs shifting their bases to low-wage
Third World countries are no longer celebrated as the benign procurer of
lucrative superprofits, but are increasingly being resented as savage
destroyers of jobs and high wages in their own homelands. Loud cries
demanding the dismantling of IMF, World Bank and WTO are rending the air
not in Bombay, Calcutta and Delhi, but in Seattle, Washington and
Melbourne.
Of course, it is futile to expect capitalism to resolve its own
contradictions through a global levelling of the economic and living
conditions. As Lenin repeatedly pointed out in Imperialism, capitalist
imperialism   continues to be enmeshed in close networks of
pre-capitalist relations here and there, and more importanly, the
pressures of levelling are being systematically counteracted by
capitalism’s inherent tendency to promote parasitism and unevenness. The
result is a deepening capitalist crisis and accentuation of the
contradiction between the growing technological foundation for  bringing
about real all-round prosperity and the narrow bourgeois fetters which
cannot be blurred by the blinding speed or daunting volume of
speculative finance or all that ‘virtual’ razzmatazz of the cyberworld.
The result is a continuing and growing possibility of delivering more
revolutionary blows to the imperialist wall in individual countries
backed perhaps by a stronger wave of global solidarity. Faced with this
task of comprehending the crisis and nurturing the revolutionary
possibility, Lenin’s Imperialism remains not just a valid historical
reference of a previous comparable conjuncture, but a live guide to
applied history as it is being made and unmade today under conditions of
a globalisation that is thoroughly imperialist.
A review of Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism by V.I. Lenin,
introduction by Prabhat Patnaik, pp vi+164,
LeftWord Books, New Delhi, Rs. 85 (paperback)








_______________________________________________
Leninist-International mailing list
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
To change your options or unsubscribe go to:
http://lists.wwpublish.com/mailman/listinfo/leninist-international

Reply via email to