Sub-Prime Economic
Theory


Melvyn Krauss


 


The possibility that the European Central Bank may raise
interest rates in the midst of a financial crisis recalls the great American
orator William Jennings Bryan’s famous “cross of gold” speech in 1896.
Referring to the international gold standard’s deflationary bias, Bryan
railed: “You shall not press down upon the brow of labor a crown of thorns. You
shall not crucify mankind upon a cross of gold.”


In other words, ordinary people should not be made to
suffer for the foibles of policymakers enthralled by some defunct economic
theory.


Today, the defunct economic theory is that a rapid shift
in preferences – colorfully called a “reduced appetite for risk” – is the key
reason behind the current sub-prime mortgage and financial crisis. To avoid
future increases in this appetite, policymakers and pundits have focused on the
so-called “moral hazard problem”: the “bad guys” must pay for their mistakes,
lest they make them again.


One would have expected the modern-day William Jennings
Bryan to be warning central bankers not to crucify mankind on a “cross of moral
hazard and no-bailouts.” But, surprisingly, the opposite is occurring.


Some on the left, motivated in part by revulsion against
financial types who are thought to reap unjustified incomes, have joined forces
with conventional economists, whose almost religious belief in their models has
blinded them to the harm their dubious economic theory can do to the real
economy and the interests of ordinary people. No bailouts can mean no college
for the kids – or, for many, no house.


The key question economists should now be asking is why
financial markets are “seizing up” when banks and other financial institutions
are flush with liquidity.


The conventional explanation – a reduced appetite for risk
– is not convincing. The sub-prime market seems too small to have caused such a
broad-based change in risk preference.


A more convincing explanation is that the current crisis,
with its unknown dimensions and scope, has so clouded the economic landscape as
to freeze market participants in their tracks, so to speak, until things clear
up.


That is the fundamental lesson of an important new book,
Imperfect Knowledge Economics: Exchange Rates and Risk, by Roman Frydman and
Michael Goldberg. The key to understanding financial markets, especially when
they are as unsettled as they have been in recent weeks, is not a change in
preferences, but inherent imperfection of knowledge and altered expectations
concerning the future course of macroeconomic fundamentals.


What policy prescriptions does the “imperfect knowledge”
approach imply for the current crisis? The most important one for central
bankers is that they should cut interest rates – and cut them fast – to
re-assure market participants that turmoil in financial markets will not be
allowed to affect the real economy.


Judging by its recent policy reversal, the US Federal
Reserve acts as if it were a late convert to the imperfect knowledge
hypothesis. Led by Ben Bernanke, a former leading academic economist, the Fed
at first fell into the trap of turning a blind eye to the wider consequences of
the sub-prime mortgage crisis. It injected money into the system, but ruled out
interest-rate cuts.


The results of this misguided policy proved so disastrous
– financial markets seized up almost immediately – that a mere ten days after
its “What, me worry?” message, the Fed made an embarrassing but necessary
about-face and lowered the discount rate by 50 basis points. Downward risks to
growth had significantly increased, Fed officials explained.


It matters little that the Fed could have gone further and
cut the federal funds rate as well as the discount rate at its emergency
meeting – indeed, that may have to be done. The important thing is that the
Fed’s policy crossed the bridge from indifference to re-assurance. Could it be
that Bernanke obtained an advanced copy of the Frydman-Goldberg book during
those pregnant ten days in August?


Bernanke certainly had time to reflect upon how his
legendary predecessor, Alan Greenspan, handled the Long Term Capital financial
crisis in 1998. Greenspan was not the kind of economist who would crucify
mankind on either a cross of moral hazard or the mechanistic models of
conventional economic theory. He cut interest rates to re-assure markets that
the financial crisis caused by the hedge fund’s collapse would not affect the
real economy. The markets and economy responded with vigor and enthusiasm.


After an initial stumble – a rookie mistake, as one
commentator put it – Bernanke appears to be following in the master’s
footsteps. But what about Jean-Claude Trichet, the president of the European
Central Bank, who more or less promised the markets a rate hike in September
and now finds that, like the Fed, he may have to reverse course? Will he delay
or go forward with the September rate hike?


No one really knows how much the sub-prime mortgage crisis
will affect the euro-zone economy. Faced with such dangerous uncertainty,
prudent central bankers do not use their independence to make a bad situation
worse by raising interest rates. Acting as if normality has returned and the
financial crisis is over doesn’t make it so.


** Melvyn Krauss is a
senior fellow at the Hoover Institution, Stanford University.


Copyright: Project
Syndicate, 2007. http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/krauss34







      
____________________________________________________________________________________
Luggage? GPS? Comic books? 
Check out fitting gifts for grads at Yahoo! Search
http://search.yahoo.com/search?fr=oni_on_mail&p=graduation+gifts&cs=bz

Kirim email ke