The A.G.Frank of Re-Orient is a great admirer of Smith, not Marx. 
Except for a minor point, every reference to Marx is 
highly negative, whereas those to Smith are always positive. 
As will become evident later, this is a new Frank, a sinocentric 
(anti-eurocentric) one; the old Frank of "underdevelopment or 
revolution" is no longer.

Let me emphasise that the figure I posted yesterday (Rostow, 
1978) to the effect that Europe accounted for 69% of world trade in 
1720 appears to be a generally accepted one as it is also cited by 
Chilsom (1982) and Aldcroft (1994). And Frank, as one would hope, 
knows about such figures, as he cites Holtfrerich's figure that the 
European share of all world trade was 69% and 72% in 1720 and 
1750. But his reaction is the rather blind one that "this unabashedly 
Eurocentric claim is disconfirmed by the evidence discussed in the 
present book" (183). I think those readers of my posts who read Re-Orient 
will agree I have been as fair as possible to Frank's side of 
the argument, presenting  all  his key figures;  yet none of 
these figures constitute an adequate response to that simple fact 
given by Holtrerich, or the others I cited. 

Instead Frank digs himself into a deeper hole, adding precisely 
the point I made yesterday that Asia's exports to Europe were a 
"very small share of Asia's trade" - which of course simply suggests 
that Asia had its own world-economy with a hyphen, one that was 
secondary to Europe's own world-economy. Some may wonder why is he 
digging himself into such a hole? Well, because he wants to convice 
us that Europe was an insignificant player in the assumed Asian 
dominated world market. And that's not all,  the hole gets bigger 
as he adds immediately that Asian exports to Europe "remained higher than 
Europe's imports from the Americas" (183) - which brings us to the 
role of the colonial trade, and  the relation of the old to the new 
Frank. 

I am leaving for now Frank's arguements on the 
technological-institutional superiority of Asia to concentrate on the 
question "Why did the West Win (temporarily)?

Frank approaches this using the theory of long waves. He speaks of a 
major "A" phase period of  world expansion from AD 1000/1050 to 
1250/1300, followed by a contraction from 1250 to 1450, followed by a 
a new "A" phase expansion after 1450. In both these two "A" 
phases, he says, China was the center of  world expansion. This post 
1450 growth lasted into the 18th century, followed  by "B" phase 
contraction after 1800. Now, this long post-1450 expansive cycle, 
like any other long wave, experienced a Kondratieff "B" phase 
downturn in the 17th century, one which, however, hit the "weaker" 
European economy harder than it did Asia. 

But another Kondratieff  "B" cycle that hit after the 1760s gave 
Europe the chance to overcome its (still) marginal position in the 
world economy - seemingly using Wallerstein's argument (1979) that, 
contrary to strict dependency theory, at certain historical junctures 
opportunities are created for some less developed economies to move up. 
So, what were the opportunities that Europe had?  A favorable factor 
endowment of natural resources and relative prices of labor and capital. 
For one, it had cheap sources of capital , from the extraction of gold,
the slave trade, the plantations, and the re-export trade. But what 
about O'Brien's powerful finding that the colonial trade amounted to 
no more than 2%  of Europe's GNP in the late 18th century? On 
the one hand, Frank appears to take this evidence seriously but 
thinks there other types of evidence do suggest this trade was 
highly important to Europe's economy: "we must agree with 
O'Brien that the evidence will never settle this issue" (42).  On the 
other, he says that O'Brien's figures do not "bear so much on the 
real dispute between us" (42). What he means, I take it, is that it 
was the monies extracted from the Americas which allowed Europe to 
enter the Asian market, and that Europe, without ever 
dominating the world market, accumulated huge profits "from the carrying 
trade and from parleying multiple transactions in bullion, money, and 
commodities in multiple markets (177). In the end, actually, Frank 
more or less dismisses O'Brien's evidence, as he goes on to say 
that the colonial trade was the crucial source of capital for Europe, for 
colonies "supplied not only almost free money, but also servile 
labor and the cheap sugar, tabacco, timber, cotton, and other goods 
produced in the Americas for European consumption [which] gave them 
access to the silk, cotton textles, and spices" of  Asia (295). To 
boot, he even cites such outdated sources as Mandel and Eric 
Williams, with the additional, if rather lame argument, that the 
supply of colonial capital brought interest rates down  from 12% in 
the 1690s to 8% in 1694 to 3% in 1752, thus cheapening investment 
(296).  

But a simple quesion now needs to be posed:  did not the bullion 
extracted  from the Americas, or at least a high proportion of it, 
ended up in Asia or China as the ultimate "sink"?!   
Whatever happened to Asia's "massive balance of trade 
surplus with Europe"? 



Reply via email to