Thanks for your quick response, but it leaves me a bit perplexed. 

The vast majority of Yugo's debt in the '80s was from commercial banks
making commercial loans  to industrial enterprises (initially without
sovereign guarantee)  - the same type loans made to Latin America and made
for the same reasons.  How can this be the "same old soft budget constraint
problem" found between Socialist enterprises and their central planners for
natl. currency budgeting?    Clearly the dynamics are different (obviously
the lenders' motives were profit in an overheated international lending
climate;  the borrower certainly new that Chase Manhattan was not a soft
lender) and fall squarely in the classic international financial crises
scenario.

The crisis for Yugoslavia (and Latin America) came precisely because this
was "good old hard debt" and had to be paid back in hard currency.  

Of course the *Banks* were treated to a sort of "soft budget constraint":
debtor governments succumbed to pressure to nationalize the debt guarantees,
eliminating the option of bankruptcy protection; lender cartels were formed,
eg the London Club, which helped block default as an option; and finally
some of the Bank's funds were replaced with IMF, World Bank and U.S Treasury
guarantees.  All this ensured that any lender default would confront most of
the private and public power of the Western world.  Can this unprecedented
pressure - leading to an unprecedented squeeze - really be called a soft
budget constraint?

I agree that the foreign aid loans of the '50s, made to the Yugo govt, are
another matter, but by the '80s the remanent of these loans were a tiny
fraction of debt (they were never very large).  Isn't it a critical point
that whatever its internal and intra-firm arrangements, in its international
economic arrangements (and its large international debt) Yugo had become a
full fledged member of the periphery - and was crushed by the usual forces?

Paul Altesman



At 03:07 PM 3/26/97 -0800, Rosser Jr, John Barkley wrote:
>     The question of Yugoslav indebtedness is a complex one 
>with Susan Woodward/Louis Proyect being at least partly 
>correct that a lot of easy credit was given in the 50s 
>essentially to pay Tito off for Cold War reasons and that 
>the conditions of that changed later.  However, the 
>indebtedness continued to rise afterwards as well, and many 
>argue that this is a tendency that can happen in market 
>socialist economies.  It is essentially the old soft budget 
>constraint problem, which both Poland and Hungary 
>experienced as well.  State-owned firms that are not 
>subject to central command planning find it easy to borrow 
>from abroad, and may do so in large amounts, with the state 
>as a whole owing this debt.  In Yugoslavia this tendency 
>became even more exaggerated as policy control became more 
>decentralized to the republics over time, but ultimate debt 
>responsibility remained centralized.
>Barkley Rosser
>On Wed, 26 Mar 1997 14:44:07 -0800 (PST) Paul Altesman 
><[EMAIL PROTECTED]> wrote:
>
>
>> At 09:40 AM 3/26/97 -0800, [EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:
>> 
>> >.....
>> >Re the analysis of Yugoslavia outlined by Louis, it certainly doesn't
>> >appear much like what I saw in Yugoslavia over the last 10 or so
>> >years.  Ferfila and I give a much different interpretation in our
>> >book *The Rise and Fall of the Third Way: Yugoslavia 1945-1991*.  In
>> >fact, one of the causes we cite for the collapse of the country was
>> >the imposition of utopian schemes by the top theoreticians (e.g.
>> >Kardelj in particular) rather than working through praxis to modify
>> >the system.  However, the whole argument is too long to present here.
......
>> 
>> I find your analysis of present day Slovenia interesting, but when
>> discussing the former Yugoslavia most analysts seem to forget that through
>> the 80s the then Yugoslavia was among the "10 most debt-distressed"
>> countries - and received even less debt relief  than most others.  Virtually
>> all of the "top 10" suffered a massive economic collapse that lasted longer
>> and deeper than the Great Depression of the '30s.  Surely Yugo.'s economic
>> collapse had much to do with the way the international system "worked" to
>> impose deflationary solutions - rendering the wisdom or folly of national
>> policy an academic question.
>> 
>> In most of the debt-stricken countries the economic collapse put enormous
>> pressure on the political systems (sometimes not for the worse).  But IMHO,
>> for Yugoslavia the callousness of the intl. system and the economic collapse
>> contributed directly to the rise of virulent ethnic nationalism and human
>> tragedy. Sadly, most of the media played to "ancient rivalries" as an
>> explanation (for Africa they say "tribal conflict"), but in truth this is
>> not the first time Europe has seen ruinous neo-classical "solutions" produce
>> murderous nationalist regimes. 
>> 
>> Paul Altesman
>> 
>> (P.S. I recall that a while back Diane Flahrety an useful article in the
>> Camb. J. of Eco. on policy errors of the Yugo models - a yet different
>> interpretation of the various approaches tried and their failures.)
>> 
>
>-- 
>Rosser Jr, John Barkley
>[EMAIL PROTECTED]
>
>
>



Reply via email to