Wednesday August 4 1999

Financial Times Euro
European Performance League

   Not so new economy
   Managers from Mars

   Comment / Columnists

Not so new economy

Computers may have revolutionised the workplace, but they have not had much
impact on productivity in the US

The US economy of today is unquestionably new. But that newness is not news.
Ever since modern economic growth began, the sole constant has been change.
Those who insist that things are different this time - to justify perhaps
the most highly valued stock market of the century - need to show that the
economy is new in a new way.

So what might be new about today's economy? There are several possibilities.
But the most important for the market is the proposition that productivity
growth has been transformed for the better. While such an improvement would
not itself be sufficient to justify the extraordinary stock prices, it would
be a necessary part of such a justification, since higher productivity
growth also means higher economic growth in the long run.


Yet since the present expansion began, in the first quarter of 1991, output
per hour in the US non-farm business sector has risen by only 1.6 per cent a
year. This is a little faster than the 1.3 per cent a year since the last
quarter of 1973. But it is well below the 2.6 per cent a year achieved
between 1953 and 1973. At best, the post-1991 improvement seems a modest
reversal of the still-unexplained post-1973 productivity growth collapse. To
describe this as "new" is to stretch the meaning of the word beyond breaking
point.


If there is anything new, it has to be still more recent. That is what Alan
Greenspan, chairman of the Federal Reserve, argued in his Humphrey-Hawkins
testimony on July 28.


"That American productivity growth has picked up over the past five years or
so has become increasingly evident," he argued. "Non-farm business
productivity (on a methodologically consistent basis) grew at an average
rate of a bit over 1 per cent per year in the 1980s. In recent years,
productivity growth has picked up to more than 2 per cent, with the past
year averaging about 2= per cent."


In explaining what is going on, Mr Greenspan noted that "output has grown
beyond what normally would have been expected from increased inputs of
labour and capital alone. Business restructuring and the synergies of the
new technologies have enhanced productive efficiencies."


This is an appealing story. It is what US business believes, not to mention
equity investors. But is it true?


Robert Gordon of Northwestern University, one of the foremost experts on US
growth performance, has analysed just this question.* He does find that
growth in output per head since the last quarter of 1995 "has recovered more
than two-thirds of the productivity growth slowdown registered between"
1950-1972 and 1972-1995. Thus between the last quarter of 1995 and the first
quarter of this year, non-farm output per hour rose at an annual rate of 2.2
per cent. This is not far below the 2.6 per cent of the period between 1950
and 1972, and far above the 1.1 per cent of the period between 1972 and
1995.






Yet Professor Gordon also argues that all of this productivity rebound can
be explained by three factors: improved measurement of inflation; the
response of productivity to the exceptionally rapid output growth of the
past few years; and the explosion of output and productivity in the
production of computers


Big efforts have been made in recent years to improve the accuracy of
measures of US inflation, to allow properly for quality improvement, which
has been underestimated in the past. For any given growth in money gross
domestic product, lower estimates of inflation necessarily mean higher
growth of real output and so productivity.


Equally, this has been an unusual business cycle, with a sluggish beginning,
followed by a strong acceleration. Output growth was only 2.6 per cent a
year between the first quarter of 1991 and the fourth quarter of 1995, but
3.9 per cent a year thereafter. Since productivity is always strongly
affected by output growth in the short term, the productivity acceleration
was inevitable.


Of the 1 percentage point improvement in productivity growth in non-farm
private business since 1995 (in comparison with 1972-1995), professor Gordon
concludes that 0.3 percentage points are explained by the recent cyclical
acceleration in growth and 0.4 percentage points by the improvement in
measurement of inflation. This leaves a structural improvement in
productivity growth of just 0.3 percentage points a year, all of which is
explained by productivity improvements in the manufacture of computers
alone.


Productivity growth in the production of computers has risen from 18 per
cent a year between 1972 and 1995 to 42 per cent a year since 1995. This,
argues professor Gordon, explains all the structural improvement in
productivity growth in durable goods as a whole, from 3.1 per cent a year
between 1972 and 1995 to 6.8 per cent a year thereafter. The computer has
brought about a productivity miracle - in the production of computers. A
tail can wag a dog, if it wags hard enough - this is what the dramatic
improvement in the productivity of computer production has achieved.


How can all the investment in computing have so small an impact on
productivity in the rest of the economy? The answer is suggested in a paper
by Dale Jorgenson and Kevin Stiroh, of Harvard University and the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York, respectively.** The fundamental point is that
computers have simply substituted for other inputs, particularly other forms
of capital. Growth in computer inputs exceeded those in other inputs by a
factor of 10 between 1990 and 1996.


Yet substitution of one form of capital for another need not raise
productivity in the economy as a whole. The fundamental measure of technical
progress is "multifactor productivity" - the increase in output per unit of
all inputs. The question about the computer revolution is not whether there
has been technical progress in the production of computers, but how far this
has spilled over to the other 99 per cent of the economy.


The evidence is that it has not. The chart below, taken from another paper
by professor Gordon, places recent performance in the context of what he
calls the "long wave" in technical progress.*** This reached a crescendo in
1950-64, before subsiding. His explanation is that the inventions of the
late 19th century and early 20th centuries were far more fundamental sources
of economy-wide productivity improvement than the electronic/internet era of
today. What were those improvements? They were electricity; the internal
combustion engine; chemicals; and communications/ entertainments (radio,
television and films).


Remember that computer manufacture accounts for 1.2 per cent of the US
economy. Computers also accounted for only 2 per cent of the capital stock
at the end of 1997: businesses may indeed be spending a vast amount on
computers, but largely to replace old ones.


Underlying productivity performance today may be a little better than in the
two decades after the first oil shock. But this performance remains far from
that of the pre-1973 golden era. If the economy is new in a new way, as the
optimists argue, it is not in productivity that this brave new world is, so
far, to be found.


* Has the New Economy Rendered the Productivity Slowdown Obsolete? June 1999
- see external links


** Information Technology and Growth, The American Economic Review, May 1999


***US Economic Growth since 1870: One Big Wave? The American Economic
Review, May 1999


Contact Martin Wolf by e-mail on [EMAIL PROTECTED]





Reply via email to