Krugman's always interesting, if nothing else:

A DOLLAR CRISIS? [from Paul Krugman's web site.]

Time does fly. A year ago Asian currencies were plunging, hedge funds were
attacking, and the world seemed on the brink of crisis. Now Asian
currencies are if anything too strong, it's the dollar that's under
pressure - and the world is, possibly, on the brink of another crisis. 

Is all the buzz - from investment newsletters, the Medley Report, and so on
- about a looming dollar crisis justified? The truth is, I don't know:
while the dollar is surely overvalued on any "sustainability" calculation
(see below), so is the stock market, and that bubble has gone on for a very
long time. But officials in Washington are reported to be worrying about
the subject (although the Medley Report's statement that there is a formal
working group turns out to be untrue), so some outside kibitzing seems to
be in order. 

Let's run through four questions: 

1. Why should we believe that the dollar is overvalued, and hence due for a
fall? 

2. Why might a dollar decline turn into a dollar plunge? 

3. Why would that be a bad thing? 

4. What should be done about it? 
  

1. Is the dollar overvalued? 
  
The basic reason for believing that the dollar is overvalued is, of course,
that the United States is running very large current account deficits, and
that the possessors of other major currencies - especially the yen - are
correspondingly running large current surpluses. 

Now current account imbalances are not necessarily a warning sign. Indeed,
they are the necessary counterpart of any transfer of funds from places
with excess saving (Japan) to places with high returns on investment (the
U.S.). Still, massive current account imbalances mean that the surplus
countries are holding an ever growing share of their wealth in the deficit
countries, a process that cannot go on forever; and (Herbert) Stein's Law
reminds us that things that cannot go on forever, don't. Eventually the
U.S. deficit and the rest-of-world surplus must be sharply reduced, perhaps
even reversed; and while this adjustment could take place in other ways, it
is likely that much of it will occur via a decline in the value of the
dollar vis-a-vis the yen, the euro, and so on. 

The "sustainability" question - which as far as I know I first posed back
in 1985, in a paper titled "Is the strong dollar sustainable?" - is whether
the market seems to be properly allowing for that required future currency
decline. If not, the dollar is doing a Wile E. Coyote, and is destined to
plunge as soon as investors take a hard look at the numbers. (For those
without a proper cultural education, Mr. Coyote was the hapless pursuer in
the Road Runner cartoons. He had the habit of running five or six steps
horizontally off the edge of a cliff before looking down, realizing there
was nothing but air beneath, and only then plunging suddenly to the ground). 

And the numbers do have a definitely Coyoteish feel. True, interest rates
in the United States are higher than those in Japan or Europe, which means
that the market is in effect predicting gradual dollar decline. But
inflation is also a bit higher in the United States; the real interest
differential on long-term bonds is probably only about 2 percent vis-a-vis
Japan, less vis-a-vis Europe. Thus investors are implicitly expecting only
a 2 percent per annum real depreciation of the dollar against the yen over
the long term; given the size of the current account imbalance, that just
isn't enough. Beep beep!  

2. A dollar plunge? 

There are, then, good reasons to expect a dollar decline, perhaps even a
sharp drop as markets start to pay attention to trade numbers again.
Remember that in 1985, when the U.S. current account deficit was about the
same share of GDP as it is today, a revision of market perceptions caused a
drop from 240 to 140 yen, from 3.3 to 1.8 Deutsche marks. 

But there is also a new element, which could amplify dollar decline, and
cause a truly dramatic plunge: balance-sheet domino effects. According to
people who ought to know, the "carry trade" that did so much to drive
exchange rates last fall is back in force: a relatively small group of
highly leveraged investors have borrowed in yen (and euros? the gossip is
less clear) and invested the proceeds in higher-interest dollar assets.
Should the dollar fall sharply, they will suffer losses - which will force
them to contract their balance sheets, selling dollars, and driving the
currency lower still, in what could be a massive overshoot. 

Now Rube Goldberg effects - mechanical linkages via balance sheets,
producing predictable mispricing - aren't supposed to happen in an
efficient financial market. Efficient markets theory would tell us that in
the face of an excessive depreciation of the dollar investors would
recognize the long-term profit opportunity and buy greenbacks en masse -
long-sighted Buffetts compensating for the balance-sheet problems of the
hedge funds. Well, maybe - but maybe not. 

3. Who cares? 

Currencies rise, currencies fall. Isn't it a zero-sum game, and for that
matter aren't the stakes pretty small in any case? 

In general, yes. And even if we are now facing an unsustainable dollar
overvaluation comparable to that of early 1985, those old enough recall
that despite grim warnings of an impending "hard landing", the correction
of that overvaluation was almost entirely benign. (Yes, some claim that it
led indirectly to Japan's bubble economy - but that is a complicated story). 

But matters are a bit different now, because we start from a different
place. Arguably, the state of the world economy right now is such that a
sharp dollar decline would be contractionary almost everywhere (except
Argentina and Hong Kong). 

To understand why, bear in mind that a currency depreciation (or, more
strictly, a revision of expectations leading to a currency depreciation -
the exchange rate is, of course, an endogenous variable) constitutes a
positive demand shock and a negative supply shock to the depreciated
country. It is a positive demand shock because the country's goods become
more competitive on world markets; it is a negative supply shock because
import prices increase. And conversely, of course, a currency appreciation
is a negative demand shock and a positive supply shock. 

The reason to be concerned about a sudden dollar decline, then, is that it
so happens that the United States is currently a supply-constrained
economy, while much of the rest of the world is demand-constrained. So the
net effect is negative almost everywhere. 

In the United States, where wages are finally beginning to reflect a
more-than-full-employment labor market [!!], a sudden dollar decline would
at least threaten to produce a wage-price spiral - and the mere threat
would mean that the Fed would likely be forced to raise rates. Whether this
would lead to a substantial contraction is unclear - who the heck
understands aggregate supply behavior these days? - but a dollar decline is
certainly not positive for the U.S. right now. 

As for the rest of the world, demand shocks from a currency appreciation
are normally easy to deal with: just cut interest rates, which among other
things limits the appreciation. But of course Japan is firmly in a
liquidity trap, and cannot cut rates; the euro-zone is not in a liquidity
trap, but a sufficiently sharp dollar decline could put it into one. The
only places that clearly benefit from a weaker dollar are
demand-constrained economies pegged to the dollar; and Argentina and Hong
Kong are just not big enough to change the general picture. 

Simple textbook open-economy macroeconomics, then, tells us that starting
from where we are right now - a U.S. economy at or beyond capacity, a large
part of the rest of the world well below capacity, and in or near a
liquidity trap - a drop in the dollar will be a global contractionary
force. How strong a force? Well, it depends on the drop; if markets were to
force the U.S. to move rapidly to current account balance or beyond, the
numbers would be very troubling. This is unlikely, I think; but then
serious crises usually are, ex ante. 

4. What is to be done? 

Can the disturbing scenario just sketched out be prevented? 

The U.S. cannot, of course, relax its supply constraint. We've already had
a virtual miracle in our ability to expand this far before inflation
started to appear; it's not just silly but greedy to ask for another. 

Can intervention stabilize the dollar? If it is sterilized, or more
generally if it is not backed by some fundamental change in policies, the
answer is probably not. Intervention can sometimes turn around a market
panic, but it cannot sustain the unsustainable. Look at the issue from
Japan's side: as I argued repeatedly last year, a liquidity-trap economy
faces the persistent problem that it cannot get its currency weak enough,
because even at a zero nominal interest rate its real rate is too high. You
wouldn't expect sterilized intervention - or any intervention that does not
change expectations about Japanese inflation - to work; and it won't. 

What will work is radical monetary expansion in the demand-constrained
economies - Japan definitely, maybe also Europe if necessary. I don't think
I need to go through the logic again - it's all there in  Japan: Still
trapped . But note that monetization will not only expand domestic demand,
but help to limit the dollar's fall (and relax the "sustainability"
constraint by increasing demand for U.S. exports). These are the same
effects that would flow from interest rate cuts in the appreciating
countries under normal circumstances. 

And that is the main point. The last time we had a seriously overvalued
dollar, the inevitable correction did little harm, mainly because the
appreciating countries were easily able to expand domestic demand. If the
current situation looks more troubling, it is because non-dollar countries
cannot increase demand using conventional policies, and are unwilling to
contemplate unconventional policies. That unwillingness, not the dollar per
se, is the source of the problem. 

Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED] &
http://clawww.lmu.edu/Faculty/JDevine/jdevine.html



Reply via email to