Sid Schniad's and Doug Henwood's figures on speculation
and foreign investment in the world economy, and Bill
Burgess's on Canada were interesting. I'd always had the
impression Canada was more neo-colonised than New
Zealand. However you might like to consider these figures
for New Zealand:

A New Zealand Reserve Bank survey in 1996 [1] showed
*daily* New Zealand foreign exchange market turnover in
1992 of US$4.2 billion, which had risen to US$7.2 billion
by 1995. In 1995 only 56% involved the NZ$.

By way of comparison, New Zealand's GDP in the March 1993
year was about US$41 billion and in the March 1996 year
about US$59 billion. The *annual* New Zealand Stock
Exchange turnover is about US$8.5 billion. Merchandise
exports in the year to March 1993 were about US$10
billion, and to March 1996 about US$13 billion, so
exports accounted for about 0.9% and 0.7% of currency
turnover in the two years. The New Zealand dollar is said
to be the 7th most traded currency in the world!

To add to Doug's table, New Zealand exports have gone
from 24.8% of GDP in 1980 to 23.8% in 1994. The ratio
rose more or less steadily from 1961 to 1980 and 81, then
began falling until 1990, when it began rising again,
peaking in 1993.

However, the picture is considerably different in foreign
investment, to the extent it can be estimated. The last
official figures for foreign ownership of assets (a la
Bill Burgess) were in 1982-83, which indicated foreign
companies had 25.6% of the paid-up capital of the
companies in the survey (which was not complete). 36.8%
of tax-assessable income and 32.4% of dividends paid went
to these foreign companies. In a paper I completed
recently [2], using data from the New Zealand Top 230
companies (including financial institutions) and
elsewhere, I concluded that in 1995, over half of company
operating surplus (earnings before interest and tax) went
to foreign companies in New Zealand. There are no asset
figures available for such a comparison. However it
appears there has been a substantial increase in foreign
control of the New Zealand economy in that period.

Since 1989 there have been official statistics on New
Zealand's International Investment Position, which shows
assets held in New Zealand by foreigners and overseas
assets held by New Zealand residents. Foreign investment
in New Zealand (including portfolio) has risen from NZ$51
billion to NZ$97 billion from 1989 to 1995 and New
Zealand investment abroad from NZ$7.2 billion to NZ$23.4
billion. The net position has gone from -NZ$44.1 billion
to -NZ$73.3 billion. By this measure, the ratio of inward
FDI to GDP was 14.4% in 1989 and 46.7% in 1995. Outward
FDI to GDP was 1.3% in 1989 and 13.4% in 1995, though one
wonders whether some of these increases are simply
because Statistics New Zealand have got better at
measuring.

Almost the entire New Zealand financial sector is foreign
owned. In 1996, 24 out of the "Management" magazine top
30 institutions, including almost all the biggest ones,
were foreign, as were 122 out of the top 200 non-
financial companies.

Some of the effects:
- when the economy "booms" to the extent that company
profits increase, the current account goes worse into
deficit because of the increasing dividend and interest
payments abroad.
- a dysfunctional exchange rate. It is set by interest
rates attracting foreign investors and foreign investor
"confidence" in the New Zealand government rather than
"real" transactions.
- hence New Zealand has a chronic, worsening, current
account deficit (currently 4.2% of GDP) and steadily
increasing foreign debt. Private foreign debt has risen
from 9.8% to 54.6% of GDP between 1983 and 1996, though
government foreign debt has fallen, offsetting the rise.
Total foreign debt has risen from 46.7% to 79.1% of GDP
in the same period.
- funnily enough, it wrecks the monetarist Reserve Bank's
attempts to control inflation using the exchange rate
(encouraging it to rise to reduce internal prices) and
interest rates. Higher interest rates increase the
exchange rate because they attract foreign investors,
threatening inflation targets and damaging exporters.
Importers of course don't reduce their prices when the
exchange rate rises.
- craven foreign-investor-friendly policies by New
Zealand governments, with which you'll be familiar.

Why should we protect national capitalists via opposing
the MAI, etc, asked Bill Burgess. In New Zealand's case,
primarily to reduce dependence on foreign capital, which
is demonstrably leading government policy. But a few
other figures I calculated from the Top 200 are
interesting:
- after-tax profit per employee was $20,000 for New
Zealand companies, and $29,800 for foreign companies
- though they took half the operating surplus, they
employed only 18% of the full-time workforce.
- turnover per employee was lower for foreign than New
Zealand companies in most industrial classifications. New
Zealand's overall rate of growth in labour productivity
has fallen since 1989.
- foreign companies had higher returns on assets but paid
lower rates of tax.

That provides some evidence for the old arguments that
less dependence on foreign capital could be used to
improve employment, wages, and government services, and
with less risk of a current-account blow-out.

Regards

Bill Rosenberg

[1] "Reserve Bank Bulletin", Vol 59 No.1, 1996, quoted in
Jim Delahunty, "Getting Fat on the Kiwi's Back", in "New
Zealand Political Review", April/May 1997, p.12-15.

[2] To be published in "Foreign Investment: The New
Zealand Experience", Ed. P. Enderwick, 1997. "Chapter 6:
Foreign Investment in New Zealand: The Current Position."
I can send a MS-Word copy to anyone who can take a mail
attachment.


Reply via email to