full speech at
http://www.federalreserve.gov/BoardDocs/Speeches/2000/20000918.htm


...The subsequent evidence appears persuasive that the combination of a
lender of last resort (the Federal Reserve) and federal deposit insurance
have contributed significantly to financial stability and have accordingly
achieved wide support within the Congress. As has often been the case in our
long financial history, such significant government intervention has not
been without cost. The federal safety net for banks, which clearly
diminishes both the incentive for, and the effectiveness of, private market
regulation, creates perverse incentives for some banks to take excessive
risk. Indeed, the safety net has required that we substitute more government
supervision and regulation for the market discipline that played such an
important role through much of our banking history.

Although the safety net necessitates greater government oversight, in recent
years rapidly changing technology has begun to render obsolete much of the
bank examination regime established in earlier decades. Bank regulators are
perforce being pressed to depend increasingly on greater and more
sophisticated private market discipline, the still most effective form of
regulation. Indeed, these developments reinforce the truth of a key lesson
from our banking history--that private counterparty supervision remains the
first line of regulatory defense. This is certainly the case for the rapidly
expanding bank options and swaps markets and other off-balance-sheet
transactions. The speed of transactions and the growing complexities of
these instruments have required federal and state examiners to focus
supervision more on risk-management procedures than on actual portfolios.
Indeed, I would characterize recent examination innovations and proposals as
attempting both to harness and to simulate market forces in the supervision
of banks.

The impact of technology on financial services and therefore, of necessity,
the way it will affect supervision and regulation as we move into the
twenty-first century is the critical issue that frames the supervisory
agenda now before us. The acceleration in the growth of technology that has
so greatly affected our economy in general has also profoundly expanded the
scope and utility of financial products over, say, the past fifteen years.
The substantial increase in our calculation capabilities has resulted in a
variety of products and ways to unbundle risk. What is particularly
impressive is that there is no sign that this process of acceleration in
financial innovation is approaching an end. We continue to move at an
exceptionally rapid pace, fueled by both computing and telecommunications
capabilities.

How should the Federal Reserve, as the functional regulator of
state-chartered member banks and, more importantly, as an umbrella
supervisor of both bank holding companies and the financial holding
companies forming under the Financial Modernization Act, react to this
ongoing wave of innovation? The ability to answer that question rests on an
understanding of how information technology has changed the nature of your
business.

The explosion in the quantity and quality of information is reducing
uncertainty, and that is particularly important because the banker's stock
in trade, the basis of an institution's franchise value, is information. The
knowledge of the potential viability of their customers is all that prevents
bankers from the equivalent of lending on the outcome of a roulette wheel's
spin.

To the extent that the newer technologies have opened up vast new areas of
information, the banker's knowledge of the borrower's capacity to repay a
loan is significantly enhanced. Risk premiums, internal risk classifications
and modeling, and credit scoring are becoming ever more finely tuned.

But the same advances in information innovation and communication are
available to all of a banker's competitors as well. Thus, although increased
information lowers the risk of lending, competition inhibits those
advantages from translating into longer-run enhanced profit margins.

Moreover, the quickened pace of market adjustments resulting from the newer
technologies has significantly shortened the interval over which a debt can
move from investment grade to default. This delimits the capacity of a bank
to adjust its exposure to a failing borrower before the bank is confronted
with default.

Uncertainty is the creator of risk premiums, the creator of higher funding
costs throughout the financial system and indeed throughout the economy
generally. The increasing availability of accurate and relevant real-time
information, by reducing uncertainty, is over time reducing the cost of
capital. That is important to financial holding companies and financial
institutions generally in their roles of both lender and borrower.

It is important in their role as borrower because their funding costs are
critically tied to the perceived level of uncertainty about their condition.
It is important in their role as lender because a dramatic decline in
uncertainty as a consequence of a large increase in real-time information
availability engenders a reduction in proprietary information.

One of the major reasons that financial intermediation worked well in years
past, in addition to the values of diversification, was that financial
institutions possessed information others did not have. This asymmetry of
information was capitalized in fairly significant rates of return. But this
advantage is rapidly dissipating, as any bank lender will testify. We are
going to real-time systems, not only with transactions but with knowledge as
well. The continued success of banking organizations, as at the time of the
ABA's founding, is dependent upon their ability to reinvent themselves by
providing new and different services and creating new and different ways to
lend and to manage assets.

Financial institutions can endeavor to preserve the old way of doing
business by keeping information, especially adverse information, away from
the funders of their liabilities. But that, I submit, would be unwise.
Inevitably and increasingly it will become more difficult to do. And, when
it becomes clear that the information coming out of an institution is
somehow questionable, that institution will pay an uncertainty premium,
perhaps a costly one. It is well worthwhile remembering that stock prices
almost invariably go up when companies write off investment mistakes. The
reason is the removal of uncertainty and the elimination of a shadow on the
companies' credibility.

What does all this mean for supervision and regulation in the twenty-first
century? If the supervisory system is to effectively enhance the capacity of
the country's financial systems to function, it must adjust to the changing
structure of that system. There is no frozen fix on supervision and
regulation. We are always changing and moving forward, endeavoring to adjust
in a manner that facilitates innovation.

We are in a dynamic system that requires not just us but also our colleagues
in the Group of Ten to adjust. Today's products and rapidly changing
structures of finance mean that supervisors are backing off from
detail-oriented supervision, which no longer can be implemented effectively.
We are moving toward a system in which we judge how well your internal risk
models are functioning and whether the risk thus measured is being
appropriately managed and offset with capital. And we are moving toward a
system in which public disclosure and market discipline are going to play
increasing roles, especially at our large institutions, as a necessity to
avoid expansion of invasive and burdensome supervision and regulation. We
have a long way to go, but this is where competitive pressures and the
underlying economic forces are pushing both you and the supervisory system.

The Financial Modernization Act is only a flag on the way to future changes.
It is a piece of legislation that will bring major changes for the good, I
trust, in all respects. During the transition, the Federal Reserve and other
supervisors must work through the issues of how to blend functional
regulation and umbrella supervision. Creating that blend will not be easy.
And it must be done substantially right the first time because, with the
financial system changing so rapidly, we do not have the luxury of reversing
course and going in a wholly different direction.

Reply via email to