What a liability

The company is the most important kind of organisation in the world and
the best guarantee of our future prosperity, argues a new study by John
Micklethwaite and Adrian Wooldridge. Lawrence Norfolk takes issue

Saturday November 8, 2003
The Guardian


The Company: A Short History of a Revolutionary Idea
by John Micklethwaite and Adrian Wooldridge
192pp, Weidenfeld, £14.99

On December 3 1984, 50 tonnes of methyl isocyanate escaped from an Indian
pesticide factory operated by the American-owned multinational Union
Carbide. The poisonous gas cloud drifted into the town of Bhopal, causing
8,000 deaths and several hundred thousand permanent injuries. Four years
later, the company had fought off the Indian government's claim for $3.3bn
in compensation and settled for the equivalent of 43 cents per share. The
news sent Union Carbide's share price climbing by $4 in 10 days.

"The most important organisation in the world is the company: the basis of
the prosperity of the west and the best hope for the future of the rest of
the world," assert John Micklethwaite and Adrian Wooldridge in The
Company. Their account traces the jagged line of the company's fortunes
from Mesopotamia to the America of Enron, explains its continued survival
and offers some pointers to its future. The underlying trend is upward.
The company is good for us, argue this book's authors.

Who is that "us"? The Assyrians, the Romans, the Indians, the Chinese and
the Arabs all set up organisations for carrying out trade, but all of
these eventually lost out to the west owing to their "geographic and
cultural shortcomings". Florence, it seems, possessed a more conducive
geography and culture, not to mention a surprising fecundity and
generosity. The Medici bank, we are told, "spawned four popes, two queens
of France and provided much of the capital for the Renaissance".

Europe's early internal trade was conducted through loose partnerships and
networks of mutually beneficial interests. These relationships developed
slowly into self-protective organisations, paralleled by the money-lenders
who financed their operations, becoming more bank-like as time went on.

The first European joint-stock companies were created by royal charter,
which granted a monopoly on trade with a territory for a fixed period.
Instruments of foreign policy as well as profit, the East India Company
and its Dutch rival, the VOC, fought a long-running war for the right to
trade with India and the Spice Islands, ending up as proxy governments
supported by private armies in their respective fiefdoms. France, as ever,
went its own way, creating the Mississippi Company. No one was ever quite
sure what this company did, but its shares rose faster than a Montgolfier
balloon until it became, in effect, the national exchequer of France, at
which point it went bust and all but took the country with it. By the
middle of the 18th century Europe resounded with the popping of such South
Sea Bubbles, while governments see-sawed between heavy-handed regulation
and laissez-faire indifference.

With the Companies Act of 1862, the see-saw stopped. Henceforth, anyone
could set up a company, anyone could invest in it and, if it went bust,
all anyone lost was their original investment. Micklethwaite and
Wooldridge rightly stress the importance of the 1862 Act and the concept
of limited liability, which transferred risk from a company's investors to
its suppliers, creditors and customers. The modern company was born.

The rise of big business in Britain, Germany and Japan is dutifully
recounted, but the main thrust of the story gravitates inevitably to
America, where the growth of the railroads forced the companies that built
them to develop professional management, accounting and information
systems. Andrew Carnegie and Henry Ford demonstrated the importance of
economies of scale and of control of the manufacturing process from top to
bottom. Ford owned the land on which grazed the sheep that produced the
wool for the seat covers in his cars. Kodak Eastman went one better by
manufacturing not only film and cameras but even the consumers to buy
them: the "amateur photographer" was a corporate invention. Soap
manufacturers coined "BO".

US companies either ate or were eaten. Primitive anti-trust laws could
hardly check the growth of such behemoths as Standard Oil or American
Tobacco. The $1.4bn for which JP Morgan and Elbert Gary sold Carnegie
Steel was equivalent to two-thirds of all the money then in circulation in
the States.

Within these companies, a quiet revolution was taking place. The managers
were taking over, led by their Lenin, Alfred Sloan of General Motors. His
reorganisation of the ailing car giant in the 1920s provided a new
corporate model. The multi-divisional company consolidated some of its
operations (notably the purchase of raw materials) and factored out
others, always to its advantage. In GM's case, that meant separate
divisions making Cadillacs, Chryslers and Chevrolets, with production
switching between them according to demand. In theory, a multi-divisional
company could grow without limit. "I do not recognise size as a barrier,"
Sloan remarked. "To me it is only a problem of management."

Micklethwaite and Wooldridge term the next stage in the history of the
company "The Corporate Paradox". In the 1970s, managerial confidence
proved no defence against an economic downturn that saw mass lay-offs and
factory and office closures in even the biggest companies. But since then,
the authors argue, the "triumph of private sector capitalism, spurred on
by privatisation and deregulation", has seen the company "trampling many
of its rivals".

This "paradox" grows more puzzling in the pages that follow. Shareholder
(or fund manager) power has added to the volatility of companies' share
prices and the insecurity of their CEOs. Leveraged buy-outs, takeovers and
mergers have made any company potentially vulnerable to any other.
Emerging corporate models - the "gazelle companies" of Silicon Valley, the
"bamboo networks" of the Far East - are designed for an unstable economic
environment, and the notion that any company can guarantee a job for life
is, today, absurd. And then there is Enron. And following Enron, the
collapse of WorldCom, three times its size.

Micklethwaite and Wooldridge acknowledge that shareholder and employee
anxiety have both risen sharply since the 1970s, but dismiss the distrust
that surrounds the company as a backlash not "against business but against
bad business practices". Whether that distinction is finely drawn or
non-existent, the conclusion of The Company retreats from its initial
fanfare. After a perfunctory chapter on multi national companies,
Micklethwaite and Wooldridge settle for the company being "the key to
productivity growth in the private sector", adding: "We are all richer as
a result."

Once again, who is that "we"? Half the world's population, according to a
2002 Unesco report, subsists on less than $2 a day. The authors of The
Company note the difference between stakeholder and shareholder
capitalism, but the idea that a company might be beholden to any
constituency wider than its owners arouses their ire. Government
regulations are "bothersome rules". EU employment legislation costs the UK
£2bn a year, while US firms foot a $289bn bill for "social regulations".
That these costs might result in value elsewhere (for example, in society
at large) is not considered. Criticism of "the basis of the prosperity of
the west and the best hope for the future of the rest of the world" is, by
definition, ill-informed: "People who now protest about the new evil of
global commerce plainly have not read much about slavery or opium."

For Micklethwaite and Wooldridge, the company is its own yardstick, the
number of these entities that a country can boast being "a better guide to
its status than the number of battleships it can muster. It is also not a
bad guide to its political freedom." Hurrah, then, for such democratic
powerhouses as the Cayman Islands and Gibraltar. Even the company's abuses
are to be applauded because "they hastened the development of labour
unions and anti-trust laws".

But this astigmatism conceals a deeper truth. Largely protected from
liability for its actions, the company acts in a sociopolitical void. It
exists to make money for its shareholders, and cannot do otherwise.
Micklethwaite and Wooldridge have written too small a book for the larger
implications of this fact. Union Carbide was bought by Dow Chemicals,
whose CEO issued a letter to all employees on the 18th anniversary of the
Bhopal disaster. He explained: "Responsibilities to our shareholders and
to our industry colleagues... make action on Bhopal impossible." Not
difficult. Not costly. Impossible.

· Lawrence Norfolk's most recent novel is In the Shape of a Boar (Orion).

Reply via email to