http://www.dailytimes.com.pk/default.asp?page=2009\03\13\story_13-3-2009_pg3_6

VIEW: Blame economists, not economics -Dani Rodrik



 Paradoxically, the current disarray within the profession is perhaps a better 
reflection of the profession's true value added than its previous misleading 
consensus. Economics can at best clarify the choices for policy makers; it 
cannot make those choices for them

As the world economy tumbles off the edge of a precipice, critics of the 
economics profession are raising questions about its complicity in the current 
crisis. Rightly so: economists have plenty to answer for.

It was economists who legitimised and popularised the view that unfettered 
finance was a boon to society. They spoke with near unanimity when it came to 
the "dangers of government over-regulation." Their technical expertise - or 
what seemed like it at the time - gave them a privileged position as opinion 
makers, as well as access to the corridors of power.

Very few among them (notable exceptions including Nouriel Roubini and Robert 
Shiller) raised alarm bells about the crisis to come. Perhaps worse still, the 
profession has failed to provide helpful guidance in steering the world economy 
out of its current mess. On Keynesian fiscal stimulus, economists' views range 
from "absolutely essential" to "ineffective and harmful."

On re-regulating finance, there are plenty of good ideas, but little 
convergence. From the near-consensus on the virtues of a finance-centric model 
of the world, the economics profession has moved to a near-total absence of 
consensus on what ought to be done.

So is economics in need of a major shake-up? Should we burn our existing 
textbooks and rewrite them from scratch?

Actually, no. Without recourse to the economist's toolkit, we cannot even begin 
to make sense of the current crisis.

Why, for example, did China's decision to accumulate foreign reserves result in 
a mortgage lender in Ohio taking excessive risks? If your answer does not use 
elements from behavioural economics, agency theory, information economics, and 
international economics, among others, it is likely to remain seriously 
incomplete.

The fault lies not with economics, but with economists. The problem is that 
economists (and those who listen to them) became over-confident in their 
preferred models of the moment: markets are efficient, financial innovation 
transfers risk to those best able to bear it, self-regulation works best, and 
government intervention is ineffective and harmful.

They forgot that there were many other models that led in radically different 
directions. Hubris creates blind spots. If anything needs fixing, it is the 
sociology of the profession. The textbooks - at least those used in advanced 
courses - are fine.

Non-economists tend to think of economics as a discipline that idolises markets 
and a narrow concept of (allocative) efficiency. If the only economics course 
you take is the typical introductory survey, or if you are a journalist asking 
an economist for a quick opinion on a policy issue, that is indeed what you 
will encounter. But take a few more economics courses, or spend some time in 
advanced seminar rooms, and you will get a different picture.

Labour economists focus not only on how trade unions can distort markets, but 
also how, under certain conditions, they can enhance productivity. Trade 
economists study the implications of globalisation on inequality within and 
across countries. Finance theorists have written reams on the consequences of 
the failure of the "efficient markets" hypothesis. Open-economy macroeconomists 
examine the instabilities of international finance. Advanced training in 
economics requires learning about market failures in detail, and about the 
myriad ways in which governments can help markets work better.

Macroeconomics may be the only applied field within economics in which more 
training puts greater distance between the specialist and the real world, owing 
to its reliance on highly unrealistic models that sacrifice relevance to 
technical rigor. Sadly, in view of today's needs, macroeconomists have made 
little progress on policy since John Maynard Keynes explained how economies 
could get stuck in unemployment due to deficient aggregate demand. Some, like 
Brad DeLong and Paul Krugman, would say that the field has actually regressed.

Economics is really a toolkit with multiple models - each a different, stylised 
representation of some aspect of reality. One's skill as an economist depends 
on the ability to pick and choose the right model for the situation.

Economics' richness has not been reflected in public debate because economists 
have taken far too much license. Instead of presenting menus of options and 
listing the relevant trade-offs - which is what economics is about - economists 
have too often conveyed their own social and political preferences. Instead of 
being analysts, they have been ideologues, favouring one set of social 
arrangements over others.

Furthermore, economists have been reluctant to share their intellectual doubts 
with the public, lest they "empower the barbarians." No economist can be 
entirely sure that his preferred model is correct. But when he and others 
advocate it to the exclusion of alternatives, they end up communicating a 
vastly exaggerated degree of confidence about what course of action is required.

Paradoxically, then, the current disarray within the profession is perhaps a 
better reflection of the profession's true value added than its previous 
misleading consensus. Economics can at best clarify the choices for policy 
makers; it cannot make those choices for them.

When economists disagree, the world gets exposed to legitimate differences of 
views on how the economy operates. It is when they agree too much that the 
public should beware. -DT-PS

Dani Rodrik, professor of political economy at Harvard University's John F 
Kennedy School of Government, is the first recipient of the Social Science 
Research Council's Albert O Hirschman Prize. His latest book is One Economics, 
Many Recipes: Globalisation, Institutions, and Economic Growth


[Non-text portions of this message have been removed]

Kirim email ke