-- --------- Forwarded Message ---------
DATE: Wed, 22 Jan 2003 18:15:17 From: keith wilde <[EMAIL PROTECTED]> To: Rodney Shakespeare <[EMAIL PROTECTED]> Cc:[EMAIL PROTECTED], [EMAIL PROTECTED], [EMAIL PROTECTED] Rodney, I am using your response to Gunnar Tomasson as the text for my response to you, so that I can make some comments about his remarks as well. I will cut and paste, always trying to be coherent. [Gunnar referred to Bohm-Bawerk, via Samuelson]: Samuelson comments: > > "The experienced reader will recognize that these can be related to Bohm-Bawerk's three famous causes for interest. His third cause, technological superiority of roundabout processes, and his first cause, the expectation by the typical consumer that his future dollars will have lower marginal utility because his income will be higher in the future (as a result of technological progress or of the productivity of roundaboutness), relate to [Samuelson's own] factor (1). Bohm's second cause – systematic time preference by consumers for present rather than future goods, for rational reasons of life's uncertainties and brevity or for irrational > reasons - relates to (2)....." (p. 613) [You (Rodney) replied]: I was talking about a man and a shovel (and that's what Keith Wilde was talking about ) but rather than deal with this issue you give a lengthy quotation about an "experienced reader" recognising three causes for interest. [I (KW) interject: It was Samuelson who was talking about a man and a shovel.] [Rodney continues] As far as I can see, the quotation has little to do with the man and the shovel although it may possibly indicate a recognition that technical processes make an input into production and so the owner of those processes is entitled to a financial return. The first quotation is largely gobbledy-gook. What on earth are "roundabout processes"? [KW AGAIN]: This is the core of capital theory in economics, and is related to the question you ask below. It means Robinson Crusoe making himself some fishing tackle rather than standing in knee-deep water trying to catch a fish with his bare hands. [BACK to Rodney]: However, assuming that you really wish to discuss interest… . [KW Again]: For B-B and most later economists, waiting, roundaboutness and interest are the substance of capital. This is a contrast to your focus, which I call “embodied technology”. [Rodney]: These are matters of importance to discuss but they do not appear to relate to the man and the shovel. [KW]: They relate indirectly. Gunnar’s comments relate to capital; yours are focused on technology. Ultimately, you are concerned with the distribution of product (i.e.. incomes). You want the man and the shovel to divide the product between them on the basis of how much each contributed. I am telling you, and Samuelson is telling you, and William Petty is telling you, that what you want to do cannot be done. At least no one has succeeded yet—or so it seems to me. If you have succeeded and can point me to the appropriate pages in your book I will be most grateful that what I have been seeking for so many months finally does appear; that is, a cogent link between your productiveness argument and the Kelso financial techniques for spreading capital ownership. [Rodney (still to Gunnar)]: Quite why anyone should agree with the statement ".... THE WHOLE VALUE of the product must in principle be divided between LABOR AND LAND, if the process of production is to proceed with ideal perfection," I fail to see. [KW]: This relates to roundaboutness as the diversion from grabbing fish to stuff in one’s mouth to making tackle instead. All capital is a combination of labor and natural resources, plus accumulating ingenuity (a human contribution). To get a feel for this, read the poem that Michael Lane circulated a couple of weeks ago, about the evolution of technology for the past 12,000 years. There is a much shorter form (by my co-author), about the shovel directly, in our article in the JSE on binary economics. (I think it is called Democratic Capitalism vs. Binary Economics.) What B-B was saying is that all payments could be traced to either a human workman (a mechanic or the gardener who fed him while he built the tool) or to the owner of natural resources, if it were not for the fact that scalawags get in between and are able to profit from the imperfect knowledge or mobility of the other actors. I would like to believe that the following will now make more sense to you. (I.e. Gunnar’s quotation from Schumpeter): > "[In an exchange economy] the businessman considers as his costs those sums > of money which he must pay to other individuals, in order to procure his wares or the means > > of producing them, that is his expenses of production. > We complete his calculation in that we also include in costs the money value > of his personal efforts. Then costs are in their essence price totals of > the services of labor and of nature. And these price totals must always > equal the receipts obtained for the products. To this extent, therefore, > production must flow on essentially profitless. That the economic system in > its most perfect condition should operate without profit is a paradox. If > we remember the meaning of our statement, the paradox vanishes, at least in > part. Of course our assertion does not mean that if it is perfectly > balanced the economic system produces without results, but only that the > results flow entirely to the original productive factors. [...] > > "This is not so opposed even to classical doctrine as it may seem to some > readers. The cost theory of value and especially the Ricardian labor theory > very strongly suggest the same conclusion, and some doctrinal tendencies > such as the tendency to label all kinds of revenue, sometimes even interest, > as wages are explained by it. If in classical times it was not expressly > stated, it is first because the older economists were not very rigorous in > recognising the consequences of their own principles, and secondly because > our conclusion appears too blatantly to contradict the facts. Bohm-Bawerk > was indeed the first who expressly said that THE WHOLE VALUE of the product > must in principle be divided between LABOR AND LAND, if the process of > production is to proceed with ideal perfection." ('The Theory of Economic > Development', Oxford University Press, 1961, pp. 31-32). [All of the above was cut and pasted from]: ----- Original Message ----- From: "Gunnar Tomasson" <[EMAIL PROTECTED]> To: "Rodney Shakespeare" <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>; "Keith Wilde" <[EMAIL PROTECTED]> Cc: <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>; <[EMAIL PROTECTED]> Sent: Tuesday, January 21, 2003 2:49 PM Subject: Re: Re productiveness of capital [Passing now to Rodney’s direct response to me]: > ----- Original Message ----- > From: "Rodney Shakespeare" <[EMAIL PROTECTED]> > To: "Keith Wilde" <[EMAIL PROTECTED]> > Cc: <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>; <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>; > <[EMAIL PROTECTED]> > Sent: Tuesday, January 21, 2003 6:50 AM > Subject: Re: Re productiveness of capital >> > > Keith, > You say that my statement about conventional economics is false and add > > that conventional economics has many ways of calculating productivity. > Yes, and I can think of three -- labour productivity; capital productivity > and marginal productivity -- and binary thoughts on the matter are on pages > > 122 -122 of the Ashford/Shakespeare book. Please read those pages and > them comment further, should you wish. … KW: Interesting list. I am not familiar with the ratios that you call labor productivity and capital productivity. Capital to Output ratios are a similar calculation, and I understand their use in ideas for development strategy from the past, but the two you illustrate are not part of my experience. Your exposition of marginal productivity in relation to distribution of final output is, however, and your account is generally conventional up to the point of your inferences about its application. Further comment below. [BACK to Rodney]: > > In the case of the fully automated factory, there is no human input into > > the production -- THAT is the matter which you are trying to avoid. [KW]: No, I am not trying to avoid it. I have understood your meaning on that point from the beginning, although you do make it progressively more clear and definitive. That is what I have in mind by saying that your concept of productivity is focused on one man operating one progressively better machine. It doesn’t make a lot of difference (to me) if the one man gets wonderfully more productive as the machine gets better or if what previously took a few men to operate now gets done with no directly visible input. So, yes, I’ll accept the elevator with no operator as an example of what can happen with technological progress. Disagreement arises with your next statement:  > Maintenance is not input (my doctor maintains me but, after payment for my > > repair, has no claim on my output); nor are repair, design or construction > > part of the production process. That is how binary economics views the > > situation whereas you are choosing to view it through the glasses of the > > "congealed" labor theory.  I believe that “congealed labor” is a term used by Marx. Bohm-Bawerk’s notion of roundaboutness is less tendentious. I believe there are some distinctive differences also, which I can’t call to mind at the moment. It is useful to have this definitive clarification of the binary position. [NO comment on this next section, which merits discussion separately, in another place.] > > Yes, fuel is also an input factor in production becasue it does work -- look at the foot of  > page 24 of the A/S book where, under the list of examples of non-human capital asset,  > >there is "minerals, raw materials" and these are separate from "quarries, mines, oil and  > >gaswells." The Green insight that everything depends on fuel is really a focus on just  > > part of the non-human contribution to production. > > > > And did I say that the automated machine does all the work? I think I said the  > >automated factory which includes all the non-human inputs which would include computers, electricity and fuel. > > [KW]: I am excising most of my original quotation from Samuleson, about the shovel and the man. Your (Rodney) reaction follows: > > > > Well, for a start, if my memory serves me correctly, certain people in > > COG Ownership debate objected to my saying that man and shovel work > together and co-operate together. They preferred to allege that all the work is > done by the man. However, I now call in the Arch-high-priest of conventional > > eocnomics (samuleson) in support for he says "Together the man and shovel can dig my cellar." And he says TOGETHER. He does NOT attribute it all to the man. [KW]: This is what I referred to yesterday as your straw man. I don’t recall that anyone in the COG discussion said that all the work was done by the man. Certainly no conventional economist would have said it, which is why I quoted Samuelson to you. The sense in which product is attributable to labor and “land” only is the one provided by B-B—i.e. “waiting” or roundaboutness. You can use “co-operating together” as a metaphor if you wish, but if you are contemplating a long-run future for binary economics I think you should re-consider this attribution of will to inanimate objects. Now we come to the really critical problem: [Rodney]: > > However, as I have most certainly stated to you before, Keith, the difficulty in deciding exactly what proportion is attributable to man or spade is NOT an excuse for saying that therefore they must be equal or something. [KW interjection: I agree, but it seems to me that it is you who is calling down an arbitrary judgment on what the proportions are or ought to be. I don’t know of any economist who values his peer-group status who would dare make an assertion of this kind. Economists have measurements. Where are yours?] Very many court cases have difficult issues to decide and the court decides it -- if necessary, in a rough and ready way. [KW again: i.e., arbitrarily.] Conventional economics, however, always fodges the issue becasue, to make clear admisison of the role of non-human capital in production immediately opens up the issue of who owns what. [KW]: Well, you have just seen and seized the word of the arch high priest that economists do acknowledge the role of non-human capital, so where does that leave the inference in the back half of your statement? I don’t see that it follows, even if the premise were true. It isn’t fudging the issue to accept the principle in Petty’s metaphor of conception. Economists do not just lie down and die before the problem, however. They have made an effort to measure the shares (in AGGREGATE) that go to labor and owners, and they have developed a rationale that explains the empirical evidence in a way that is believable to most of us who care to put them together. This seems to be completely aside from issues of ownership. Economists can read, and we know that ownership is badly skewed—it is economists who make the measurements after all! Most economists I know would also prefer to see ownership more broadly distributed. But to see that the payments to labor are roughly 70% of the total, decade after decade, does not by itself inspire an ardent curiosity about who owns what. Your account of marginal productivity theory of distribution (in chapter 4 of your book) strongly suggests that economists believe entrepreneurs actually try to measure the value of marginal products in taking decisions on hiring more labor or investing in new plant or equipment. Students may get confused on that point, but a little experience soon disabuses them on the notion. There seems also to be an underlying implication that economists take the marginal productivity theory of distribution as the basis for arguing that the existing market system is optimal in the sense that every factor gets the share of collective product that it “deserves”. You could probably dig up some literature that lent credibility to this notion, but I don’t think it would get many signatories at a conference of professional economists. The theory simply puts together the concept of a marginal product (as you have described it) and the value of an incremental input given the price that people are willing to pay for the product. It is another way of saying that a businessman will hire either more labor or more capital, depending on which one looks most valuable to him at the moment of decision. It is a way of explaining why the aggregated data show that human inputs consistently receive about 70% of payments to factors. (See my Samuelson quotation.) It is not an assertion that the shares are optimal in a moral or political sense. The price or cost of capital is a different question, and brings up the issue of what capital really is. That is the subject addressed by Bohm-Bawerk, and your unfamiliarity with the notion of roundaboutness and waiting is why you are mystified by his assertion that the whole value of the product should be divided between labor and land. [BACK to Rodney] The binary concept of productiveness (as you should know after much lengthy debate with me) is designed to clarify the relative contributiuons of human and non-human physical contributions and thereby does NOT accept the cop-out of Samuleson and his friends who will do and say anything to avoid doing or saying anything which opens up the question of the present narrow ownership of large amounts of productive capital. [KW] That may be your intent, but I do not see where binarians have actually provided either a theory or empirical evidence to “clarify the relative contributions”. Kelso and Adler said that the actual contributions should be more like 10 for labor and 90 for capital, but where have they or you solved Petty’s problem of deciding whether it is the egg or the sperm that is to get the credit for the product, and in what proportions? Kelso saw under-used capital as a disgrace, and insufficient consumer spending power as the source of the problem. His solution was to increase collective output by bumping up tangible capital assets substantially and making consumers the owners of it. I see from re-reading your chapter 4 that the emphasis on binary growth is quite consistent with Stephen Kane’s explanation in terms of isoquants in 2001—that is, make capital cost less so that more of it will be chosen in production decisions. Your only argument in support of the 10-90 claim is therefore the binary growth fantasy. It’s an attractive notion, but is it realistic? You banish realism by arbitrarily excluding maintenance, design, etc. from your productivity concept. And then, because human employment is seen to keep increasing right along with capital investment, you explain this away by saying it must be due to government regulations or ounion power that force companies to hire and pay more than they ought. Where is your evidence for that claim? That was Samuelson’s complaint against the Kelso plan for Puerto Rico, remember? [Rodney again]  > Keith, one last matter, it's very easy for people to criticise others but everything really gets down to two matters:-- > > a) is the existing sytem/structure the best that can be done? > > b) what specific policy change is proposed to improve things? Binary economics criticised all the time but the critics ultimately lose the argument because, generally, they have no substantial alternative to offer and, at best, are reduced to saying that anything that is proposed for improving things always results in things getting worse. If that's always true, then discussions like this are pointless--and you do not believe that, and neither do I. > > Rodney  > > PS > > A huge amount of work is going on with the GJM of which binary economics is a part. [KW] The existing system is certainly not optimal. It would help matters substantially if only governments could be coerced into keeping the laws they are sworn to uphold. That was my preoccupation for several years prior to my encounter with Kelso disciples. I was diverted from that course because of a youthful enthusiasm for social justice of a kind similar to what you are promoting. I am cautious by nature, however, and like to cross the t’s and dot the i’s before casting my designs into the political arena. Change does require the energy of activists, but the campaign may sometimes gather more credible adherents and bear better fruit if the plan is rigorously shaken down before trying to get it implemented. The Kelso schemes for democratized credit and expanded ownership sounded very exciting to me at first. The binary productiveness and growth arguments did not appear to be critical elements in the prescriptions, but the insistence of you and others on their centrality caused me to wonder about the linkage between the physical and the financial parts. Your exchange with ‘creditary economics’ was therefore a very useful opening to evaluate the another part of the package. I look forward to more commentary of that kind. Keith  ===== Please address return mail to me at: [EMAIL PROTECTED] __________________________________________________ Do you Yahoo!? Yahoo! Mail Plus - Powerful. Affordable. Sign up now. http://mailplus.yahoo.com --------- End Forwarded Message --------- _____________________________________________________________ Get 25MB, POP3, Spam Filtering with LYCOS MAIL PLUS for $19.95/year. http://login.mail.lycos.com/brandPage.shtml?pageId=plus&ref=lmtplus ==^================================================================ This email was sent to: archive@mail-archive.com EASY UNSUBSCRIBE click here: http://topica.com/u/?a84IaC.bcVIgP.YXJjaGl2 Or send an email to: [EMAIL PROTECTED] TOPICA - Start your own email discussion group. FREE! http://www.topica.com/partner/tag02/create/index2.html ==^================================================================