Posted by Eugene Volokh:
Cass Sunstein & Adrian Vermeule for the Death Penalty:

   Their essay is [1]available for download here; here's the abstract
   (paragraph breaks added):

     Recent evidence suggests that capital punishment may have a
     significant deterrent effect, preventing as many as eighteen or
     more murders for each execution. This evidence greatly unsettles
     moral objections to the death penalty, because it suggests that a
     refusal to impose that penalty condemns numerous innocent people to
     death.

     Capital punishment thus presents a life-life tradeoff, and a
     serious commitment to the sanctity of human life may well compel,
     rather than forbid, that form of punishment. Moral objections to
     the death penalty frequently depend on a distinction between acts
     and omissions, but that distinction is misleading in this context,
     because government is a special kind of moral agent.

     The familiar problems with capital punishment -â potential error,
     irreversibility, arbitrariness, and racial skew -â do not argue in
     favor of abolition, because the world of homicide suffers from
     those same problems in even more acute form. The widespread failure
     to appreciate the life-life tradeoffs involved in capital
     punishment may depend on cognitive processes that fail to treat
     âstatistical livesâ with the seriousness that they deserve.

   I've read the paper, and though I don't entirely agree with all the
   analysis in it, I think it makes some very important points, and will
   attract a lot of attention. What most intrigued me, incidentally, was
   its summary of the recent deterrence studies, which I hadn't known
   about. (I support the death penalty on retributive grounds, but
   obviously if it's a powerful deterrent, that would reinforce the
   retributivists' support and may also bring around many
   nonretributivists.) Here's their summary of the evidence; for
   footnotes, please see the paper itself:

     For many years, the deterrent effect of capital punishment was
     sharply disputed. But a great deal of recent evidence strengthens
     the claim that capital punishment has large deterrent effects. The
     reason for the shift is that a wave of sophisticated econometric
     studies have exploited a newly-available form of data, so-called
     âpanel dataâ that uses all information from a set of units (states
     or counties) and follows that data over an extended period of time.
     A leading study used county-level panel data from 3,054 U.S.
     counties between 1977 and 1996. The authors find that the murder
     rate is significantly reduced by both death sentences and
     executions. The most striking finding is that on average, each
     execution results in 18 fewer murders.

     Other econometric studies also find a substantial deterrent effect.
     In two papers, Paul Zimmerman uses state-level panel data from 1978
     onwards to measure the deterrent effect of execution rates and
     execution methods. He estimates that each execution deters an
     average of fourteen murders. Using state-level data from 1977 to
     1997, Mocan and Gittings find that each execution deters five
     murders on average. They also find that increases in the murder
     rate come from removing people from death row and also from
     commutations in death sentences. Yet another study, based on
     state-level data from 1997-1999, finds that a death sentence deters
     4.5 murders and an execution deters three murders. The same study
     investigates the question whether executions deter crimes of
     passion and murders by intimates. The answer is clear: these
     categories of murder are deterred by capital punishment. The
     deterrent effect of the death penalty is also found to be a
     function of the length of waits on death row, with a murder
     deterred for every 2.75 years of reduction in the period before
     execution.

     In the period between 1972 and 1976, the Supreme Court produced an
     effective moratorium on capital punishment, and an extensive study
     exploits that fact to estimate the deterrent effect. Using
     state-level data from 1960-2000, the authors make before-and-after
     comparisons, focusing on the murder rate in each state before and
     after the death penalty was suspended and reinstated. The authors
     find a substantial deterrent effect. After suspending the death
     penalty, 91% of states faced an increase in homicides â and in 67%
     of states, the rate was decreased after reinstatement of capital
     punishment.

     A recent study offers more refined findings. Disaggregating the
     data on a state by state basis, Joanna Shepherd finds that the
     nation-wide deterrent effect of capital punishment is entirely
     driven by only six states -- and that no deterrent effect can be
     found in the twenty-one other states that have restored capital
     punishment. What distinguishes the six from the twenty-one? The
     answer lies in the fact that states showing a deterrent effect are
     executing more people than states that do not. In fact the data
     show a âthreshold effectâ: deterrence is found in states that had
     at least nine executions between 1977 and 1996. In states below
     that threshold, no deterrence can be found. This finding is
     intuitively plausible. Unless executions reach a certain level,
     murderers may act as if the death is so improbable as not to be
     worthy of concern. Her main lesson is that once the level of
     executions reaches a certain level, the deterrent effect of capital
     punishment is substantial.

     All in all, the recent evidence of a deterrent effect from capital
     punishment seems impressive. But in studies of this kind, it is
     hard to control for confounding variables, and a degree of doubt
     inevitably remains. It remains possible that these findings will be
     exposed as statistical artifacts or will be found to rest on flawed
     econometric methods. More broadly, skeptics are likely to question
     the mechanisms by which capital punishment has a deterrent effect.
     On the skeptical view, many murderers lack a clear sense of the
     likelihood and perhaps even the existence of executions in their
     state; further problems for the deterrence claim are introduced by
     the fact that capital punishment is imposed infrequently and after
     long delays. In any case many murders are committed in a passionate
     state that does not lend itself to an all-things-considered
     analysis on the part of perpetrators.

     As mentioned above, and as we discuss in Part IV, these
     suppositions are in some tension with existing evidence. But let us
     suppose that these doubts are reasonable. If so, should current
     findings be deemed irrelevant for purposes of policy and law? That
     would be an odd conclusion. In regulation as a whole, it is common
     to embrace some version of the Precautionary Principle -â the idea
     that steps should be taken to prevent significant harm even if
     cause-and-effect relationships remain unclear and even if the risk
     is not likely to come to fruition. Even if we reject strong
     versions of the Precautionary Principle, it hardly seems sensible
     that governments should ignore evidence demonstrating a significant
     possibility that a certain step will save large numbers of innocent
     lives.

     For capital punishment, critics often seem to assume that evidence
     on deterrent effects should be ignored if reasonable questions can
     be raised about it. But as a general rule, this is implausible. In
     most contexts, the existence of reasonable questions is hardly an
     adequate reason to ignore evidence of severe harm. If it were, many
     environmental controls would be in serious jeopardy. We do not mean
     to suggest that government should commit what many people consider
     to be, prima facie, a serious moral wrong simply on the basis of
     speculation that this step will do some good. But a degree of
     reasonable doubt does not seem sufficient to doom capital
     punishment, if the evidence suggests that significant deterrence
     occurs.

   In any event, as they say, read the whole thing -- and, better yet,
   also read the studies it cites (something I plan to do shortly).

References

   1. http://aei-brookings.org/publications/abstract.php?pid=922

_______________________________________________
Volokh mailing list
Volokh@lists.powerblogs.com
http://highsorcery.com/cgi-bin/mailman/listinfo/volokh

Reply via email to