http://business-standard.com/opinionanalysis/storypage.php?leftnm=4&subLeft=2&chklogin=N&autono=282806&tab=r


Alok Sheel: Inequality and the nation state

Alok Sheel / New Delhi April 29, 2007



The process of globalisation has been relentless historically, and
though it may face occasional retreats, it is unlikely that it would
ever face extinction.

Curiously, globalisation is a four letter word for several intellectuals
in both the developing and developed worlds. In the former,
globalisation has long been linked to imperialism, or more fashionably,
neo-imperialism/liberalism. Seen as a continuation of colonisation of
the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, it supposedly not only left
developing countries worse off than what they were before, but also
indeed made them structurally 'underdeveloped'. In the developed world,
globalisation is blamed for the export of jobs and consequential
prosperity to the developing world. Globalisation would, therefore,
appear to be a global threat!

The fact of the matter is that the prosperous Asian economies of China
and India, with higher per capita incomes than western Europe as late as
the beginning of the eighteenth century, had started falling behind well
before they were colonised. It is, therefore, moot to discuss whether
colonialism was the cause or consequence of backwardness. The per capita
income divide with western Europe, including its white settler
offshoots, and the colonies continued to widen during the 'enforced free
trade' of the colonial period. India's per capita income growth during
the colonial period was very nominal in the aggregate, a continuation of
the preceding trend. However, there was a burst of growth between
1880-1910, largely as the result of agricultural expansion and
commercialisation following infrastructural investment and integration
into the world system.

Per capita income growth declined between the two World Wars, which also
coincided with a retreat from globalisation. While per capita income
growth resumed modestly in the immediate aftermath of colonialism, when
several former colonies retreated into autarchy and dirigisme, the per
capita income gap with the developed world continued to widen despite
conscious attempts at 'de-globalisation'. The gap started converging
only after erstwhile colonies, first in east Asia, followed by China and
India, re-entered the globalisation process.

The Asian countries' experience with globalisation shows, firstly, that
periods of globalisation coincided with periods of accelerated growth.
Secondly, the first phase of globalisation coincided with widening
income disparities with the west, while the (current) second phase is
tending towards per capita income convergence.

Why should the two phases of globalisation have had differing outcomes
for developing countries? There are two possible explanations. The first
phase of growth was based largely on agriculture which, as Kaldor
postulated several years ago, has a much more modest growth impact than
manufacturing. The second phase of globalisation was based on
manufacturing and services (as in the Indian case) in the former
colonies, with higher attendant growth rates, while developed countries
show signs of postindustrial growth fatigue.

Secondly, it was not free trade per se but imperialism that was the
villain of the piece. Free trade was controlled and regulated by
developed nation states. Whereas the first phase of globalisation saw
the flag of advanced nation states follow trade and markets, the second
phase has seen trade, through the instrument of Trans-National
Corporations (TNCs), follow markets across various flags. The
globalising impulse today is multilateral, controlled and regulated by
TNCs. Perfectly willing to relocate production and services, including
the transfer of technology and capital overseas in search of higher
profits, the interests of TNCs are frequently in conflict with those of
the nation states. The latter often actively pursue policies as though
they feel threatened by globalisation.

The rise of absolutism and the nation state in the early period of
modernisation was a major factor in the market integration of
decentralised and fragmented feudal societies. In the current phase of
globalisation, however, it is a major force hindering global integration
of markets. In any case the nation state is being rendered increasingly
ineffective in its two main functions of national defence and
macro-economic policy. While the first is threatened by the growing
technological gap between the US and all other countries, globalisation
is rendering sovereign macro-economic levers increasingly ineffective.
Most other functions of the state, such as welfare and policing, can be
performed by local and regional governments and markets. Taxpayers may
realise sooner than later that the combination of increasingly modest
outcomes and high overheads make nation states more predatory than
benign.

The logic of globalisation in continually relocating production and
services to cheaper locations raises incomes in poorer countries.
Consequential efficiency gains lead to higher returns to capital
(through greater profitability). Returns to labour rise faster in
developing countries than in developed ones; and within developed
countries, faster for skilled knowledge labour than unskilled labour.
Globalisation rewards knowledge skills, both human and technological. It
has reduced inequality between nations but increased it within nations.
As per capita incomes in some developing countries rise, poorer
developing countries get the chance of becoming more competitive. It is
entirely possible that the logic of globalisation will relocate
production and services away from Asia to African countries in future
provided issues of governance, infrastructure and human capital are
sorted out.

Although widening inequality is a corollary of globalisation, purchasing
power has nevertheless risen all round in both developed and developing
countries through universal access to a wide variety of cheap (Chinese)
goods and (Indian) services. In that sense globalisation has been
'inclusive' as the standard of living of even the poorest has improved
through efficiency and productivity gains deriving from globalisation.
Widening gini co-efficients may well be acceptable as long as equality
of opportunity can be assured through universal access to knowledge.

Globalising forces are driven by efficiency gains deriving from trade on
the one hand, and productivity gains deriving from technological
improvements on the other. There were periods of widening global contact
in the past, driven by humongous empires such as the Roman, Mongol and
Ottoman, through dramatic long distance movements of peoples such as
Vikings, Huns and Visigoths, and through long distance trade, such as
the overland silk and Indian ocean routes linking the east and west.
Until fairly recently, however, technological advances were few and far
in between, and disseminated very slowly. The movement of goods and
people was consequently limited until the Industrial Revolution let the
genie of technology out of the bottle, leading to rapid mobility of all
factors of production (other than land) and services on an unprecedented
scale. The globalisation process has been relentless since, although
non-linear. For instance, the period following the First World War
witnessed a retreat from globalisation because stakeholders in the
erstwhile colonies felt that they had been shortchanged. The current
phase of globalisation that began with the east Asian surge in the
seventies could well witness another retreat if some stakeholders feel
that they are being left out. History, however tells us that this
retreat is unlikely to be permanent. Goodbye nation state?

The writer is a civil servant. The views are personal.

Reply via email to