I'd said:


ERIRV(whole) meets WDSC. Surprisingly, ERIRV(fractional)
seems to also.

Markus replied:


ERIRV(fractional) doesn't meet WDSC. Example:

  20 A=B=C>E>...
  20 A=B=D>E>...
  20 A=C=D>E>...

  7 B>E>...
  7 C>E>...
  7 D>E>...

38 E>...

  A majority of the voters strictly prefers candidate A
  to candidate E and ranks candidate A tied for top.
  Nevertheless, candidate E is the winner.

I reply:

WDSC doen't say that if a majorilty prefer X to Y, then Y mustn't win if that majority rank X tied for top.

Here's what WDSC says:

If a majority of the voters prefer X to Y, then they must have a way of voting that will ensure that Y won't win, without any member of that majority reversing a sincere preference.

Because you say that a majority prefer A to E, we can assume that you're saying that your rankings represent sincere preferences. Then, as you said, a majority prefer A to E.

Do they have a way of voting that ensures that E won't win, without any of them reversing a sincere preference? Sure. They can all insincerely vote A alone in 1st place.

When they do that, A has an immediate majority and wins.

The A=B voters who insincerely vote A over B, and the A=C voters who insincerely vote A over C, are falsifying a preference, but they aren't reversing a preference. WDSC only requires that they be able to keep E from winning without reversing a preference.

Of course, in that example, even unmitigated IRV doesn't fail WDSC. But I've posted examples in which unmitigated IRV fails WDSC.

For instance, my standard 3-candidate example:

Sincere preferences:

40: ABC
25: BAC
35: CBA

A majority prefer B to A.

But A wins unless at least some of the C voters insincerely vote B in 1st place, over C.

In ERIRV(fractional), if the C voters voted C=B>A, then we have these initial vote totals:

A: 40
B: 25 + 35/2 = 42.5
C: 17.5

C is eliminated and transfers its 17.5 votes to B, who then has 60 votes, the votes of all the B>A voters.

Bucklin & Participation:

But your Bucklin Partilcipation failure example is valid. It had seemed to me that Bucklin couldn't fail Participation because no X>Y voter ever gives a vote to Y without first giving one to X. But, as you pointed out, a set of X>Y voters who don't vote X 1st can, by adding to the total number of voters, prevent X from having an initial majority.

But, though Bucklin doesn't meet Participation, it's still the most easily-counted method that meets SDSC. WDSC & SDSC are a good accomplishment for such an easily-counted method.

I want to clarify that I still say that Approval is a strong 2nd to Condorcet, because I'm referring to actual proposals. Bucklin isn't proposed as a public method. Among methods proposed for public use, Approval is the 2nd best, after Condorcet.

As I said, if rank balloting is used, and since computer counting is available for public elections, there'd be no point in using any less than Condorcet. Condorcet meets SFC & GSFC, two criteria that Bucklin doesn't meet. SFC & GSFC are Condorcet's most impressive advantages.

Mike Ossipoff

_________________________________________________________________
Free up your inbox with MSN Hotmail Extra Storage. Multiple plans available. http://join.msn.com/?pgmarket=en-us&page=hotmail/es2&ST=1/go/onm00200362ave/direct/01/


----
Election-methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info

Reply via email to