The basic idea of PR methods is to create an assembly that represents the voters. While voters don't neatly fall into categories, we can measure the performance of the systems as if they did. In the end, the only category that matters is who the voter trusts most to represent them.

So if there is an assembly with N seats, and V voters, and there are V/N voters who prefer, out of all possibilities, a candidate, we can define a Proportionality Criterion. That candidate must be elected if the voters express this preference on the ballot.

Asset Voting satisfies this, so does Candidate Proxy. Both are simple methods; Candidate Proxy (which has been used to refer to a method where candidates state a preference order, before the election, and this order is used with the counting system to apply to the voter's ballot, it essentially substitutes for the voter's ballot. Asset Voting is more flexible and could theoretically allow for a candidate to be chosen who wasn't on the ballot and received no votes in the election at all.

"Win" must be interpreted as "has the right to unconditionally declare a person elected, which could be the candidate himself or herself, or anyone else eligible for the office."

And then more detailed criteria could be defined, like the Distributed Proportionality Criterion. If there is a set of M candidates who received together a sum of V/N votes as most-preferred, those candidates, by cooperating, could unconditionally elect a winner. This, to my mind, satisfies the intention of proportional representation even where no candidates, by themselves, gain a quota.

To try to simulate this with a single-ballot method can get tricky, but it could be done.

However, I'll suggest this simple method:

Bucklin ballot. For simplicity, I'm not going to allow multiple votes in each rank, but it would be improved if multiple votes are allowed, it simply complicates the counting and calculations.

First rank choices are counted. If any candidate gains a quota (for a single-ballot method, it must be a Droop quota, not the Hare quota that makes more sense with pure Asset Voting), that candidate is elected. This is done for all candidates who are direclty elected with a quota in the first round. The ballots with that candidate in first preference position are segregated. By the condition, the total vote count, T(C1), is at or over the quota. If only one seat were elected with these votes, it would be disproportionate, the voters would be underrepresented. So there must still be effective votes left to be exercised of T(C1) - Q. So each ballot is devalued by the ratio of (T(C1 - Q)) / T(C1). These ballots are then counted separately to examine the next rank listed, and those votes are multiplied by the devaluation factor and added in to the totals, and this is repeated as needed until no more ranks are available. At each point, the number of remaining votes to be distributed are V minus Q times the number of candidates elected thus far. It may be easier to understand than to describe!

If a ballot has a candidate in first position who is not elected, when all candidates which can be elected as described are elected, the ballot is opened to the next rank, and those votes are added in (from all ballots except those that are completely exhausted -- which is unlikely, for it to happen an candidate would have to be elected by an exact quota of votes.)

While your second rank choice may "harm" your first rank choice, it never actually reduces the chance of that candidate being elected unless the candidate wasn't going to gain a quorum of votes. The possibility that your ballot might elect your lower-ranked choice is balanced by the fact that your favored candidate might be elected by a lower-ranked choice of another. And because there are no eliminations, except of elected candidates, the "harm" would only occur at the very end of the process, and with one seat at stake, and, yes, Virginia, if you want to be represented by the best possible representative, you must be willing to make compromises. Hopefully, they are not large ones.

If voters voted in blocks, and each block wanted their favorite to be elected, and the block was Q in size or larger, all preferring the same candidate, the candidate would be elected provided they vote their sincere preference. As well, if a block places two candidates at the top of their preference lists, and votes the preference, and is 2 * Q in size, both candidates would be elected. If two blocks exist, one voting A>B>all others, and one voting B>A>all others, and the two blocks together are 2 * Q in size, then both A and B will be elected.

Has this method been described by anyone? If forget how Proportional Approval Voting is run, but I'd guess it would look like this, with just one Approval stage, i.e., as if all ballots in the Bucklin system I described were collapsed at once.

I described a method that depended on ballot patterns, it's possible to consider opening up the second rank simultaneously with all ballots, in which case individual ballot data is no longer needed. And I don't have time at the moment to review the details, so aspects of this may be incorrect or incomplete.

If write-ins are allowed, or there are a very large number of candidates and a lot of seats to be elected, there might be votes that end up unused. Lewis Carroll suggested a solution, and it's Asset Voting. Candidates get the leftover votes to recast at their discretion. So a bunch of candidates with vote counts, as devalued, at the end, less than a quota, could cooperate to name a seat. Asset Voting was invented and published in 1884 as a tweak on STV, and STV would be far more effective and far less dependent upon party affiliations, had this tweak been noticed and adopted.

If no votes are wasted, and Asset makes wasted votes unlikely, with a particular known individual being responsible for wasting *your* vote, you can vote accordingly in the future, and if voters aren't artificially constrained to listed candidates affiliated with empowered parties, then parties must necessarily become less important. They would still serve other functions, I'm sure. However, this situation sets up a conflict of interest between political parties and those vested within them, and the voters themselves, so I wouldn't hold my breathe for political parties to rush to support something like this. It is pure voter benefit, so it will probably have to be the voters themselves to make it happen, which will require direct voter organization for that purpose.

That is probably true for any truly major reform of the system. The people who have accumulated power under the present system are not likely to rush to support reforms that make their accumulated power less relevant. They wouldn't lose their natural influence, but who will stop to think like that? In fact, a party leader who did push for and successfully implement an Asset system would probably thereby be creating independent support, and would maintain effective power or influence even without needing to please a party elite or needing to satisfy wealthy donors.

But I'm not holding my breath.

I'm simply applying the organizational principles wherever and whenever I have a chance. Others can imitate if they choose.

----
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info

Reply via email to