To sum up my point of view suppose that the candidates publicly announce the 
respective preferences 
(with levels of support shown):

48 A
27 C>B
25 B

We cannot tell from these ballots alone if B is bluffing or if B really 
despises A and C equally.

If the decision is made only on the basis of these ballots, then the right 
decision for the case when B is 
bluffing will be the wrong decision for the case when B is not bluffing, so no 
method that relies on the 
ballots alone will solve the problem.

But if C is allowed to play before B, and C strongly believes that B is 
bluffing, then C can "bullet."

If C is right, then B will approve C also, and C will win.  If C is wrong, then 
A will win. 

Under actual conditions it is very unlikely that C is going to guess wrongly as 
to whether or not B is 
bluffing.

SODA allows C to play before B, so the problem is basically solved, as long as 
B is allowed to approve 
someone that she did not rank on her ballot, or else as long as there is a very 
strong incentive for B to 
rank significant preferences.

I've been thinking that perhaps we should allow candidtes to approve candidates 
that they did not rank 
ahead of time, as long as they also approve all candidates that they did rank 
in that case.

This would allow a candidate to back down when their bluff was called.  

Would the candidates then just rank themselves in the pre-election public 
rankings so that they would 
have free reign when it came to approval designations?

I don't thnk so, because there are other dynamics that make it advantageous for 
them to commit to 
ranking their significant preferences ahead of time, especially when there is 
no chicken standoff, but 
even in that case as well.

Am I misjudging this orI over-looking a worse problem?



----- Original Message -----
From: Jameson Quinn 
Date: Saturday, August 6, 2011 4:04 pm
Subject: Re: [EM] : Chicken problem (was: SODA and the Condorcet
To: fsimm...@pcc.edu
Cc: election-methods@lists.electorama.com

> 2011/8/6 
> 
> > Jan,
> >
> > IRV elects C like all of the other methods if the B faction doesn't
> > truncate. But IRV elects A when the B
> > faction truncates. Of course, with this knowledge, the B 
> faction isn't
> > likely to truncate, and as you say C
> > will be elected.
> >
> > The trouble with IRV is that in the other scenario when the B 
> faction> truncates sincerely because of
> > detesting both A and C, IRV still elects A instead of B.
> >
> 
> Also, if the A faction votes A>B, then B clearly should win, but 
> does not
> under IRV. So yes, IRV solves the chicken dilemma, but in so 
> doing causes
> other problems. (This same argument, as it happens, works 
> against tree-based
> methods.)
> 
> I still claim that SODA is the only system I know of that can 
> solve the
> chicken dilemma without over-solving it and making other problems.
> 
----
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info

Reply via email to