The Economic and Political Weekly
December 11, 2004
Commentary


National Rural Employment Guarantee Act
A Historic Opportunity

The proposed employment guarantee programme will generate work for 
the poorest; it is also an opportunity to revive public investment in 
agriculture, tackle the prevailing environmental crisis that is 
gripping rural India and galvanise the panchayat raj institutions. 
The proposed legislation should not put in place a weak and diluted 
jobs programme.

Mihir Shah


The National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (NREGA) proposed to be 
enacted during the current winter session of parliament represents a 
historic opportunity for socio-economic transformation in rural 
India. The 1990s have brought the crisis of rural India to the fore. 
For the first time since independence, the decade witnessed a decline 
in per capita output in Indian agriculture. Crops grown and eaten by 
the poorest suffered the greatest neglect. The per capita net 
availability of pulses declined to less than half of what it was in 
the 1950s. The rate of growth of output of coarse cereals fell to 
almost zero. According to the Food and Agricultural Organisation, the 
number of hungry people in India increased by 19 million between 1997 
and 2001. Nearly half our children remain chronically malnourished. 
India has the highest percentage of anaemic pregnant women in the 
world. Reports of starvation deaths and suicides by farmers abound in 
the media. If there was any doubt that rural India was crying out for 
change, this was firmly dispelled by Verdict 2004. It is good to see 
those brought to power by this verdict now seeking to fulfil the 
people's mandate by enacting the NREGA legislation.

Argument in Economic Theory

This, however, is not the point of view of the pro-market 
liberalisers. For them the NREGA is a dangerous piece of legislation 
that threatens to snowball India's fiscal deficit out of control. 
They see it in direct conflict with the Fiscal Responsibility Act. To 
understand the issues involved, we need a brief theoretical 
interlude. Historically, this argument echoes the response of the 
British Treasury to former premier David Lloyd George's suggestion of 
starting public works during the years of the Great Depression. The 
assumption implicit in such a view is that there is a fixed pool of 
savings available for investment and that an increase in public 
investment would 'crowd-out' private investment. This vision of the 
economy was challenged by Kahn (1931) and comprehensively demolished 
by Keynes (1936). In the Keynesian view, savings are no longer 
exogenous, depending as they do on the level of income. So long as 
there is a slack in the economy such that income can be raised 
through an increase in the level of public investment, the resultant 
deficit would finance itself through a rise in the savings following 
the increase in incomes. However, with reference to underdeveloped 
economies facing a major 'agrarian constraint', Keynesian economists 
themselves argued that the assumption of a slack in the economy would 
not apply [Kalecki 1945; Rao 1952 and Dasgupta 1954]. In a strict 
Keynesian sense, these economies could be viewed as being at a 'full 
employment' level.1  Deficit financing would necessarily be 
inflationary in these conditions.

Following Malinvaud's (1977) pioneering contribution to the theory of 
unemployment, however, Rakshit (1989, 2004) has provided a powerful 
theoretical reiteration of the relevance of 'classical Keynesianism' 
(if one may call it that!) to the Indian context. Rakshit points to 
the existence of large excess capacity in Indian industry, massive 
increases in rates of saving and the fact of a large proportion of 
savings being held in the form of financial assets. This has the 
implication of a widening gap between the acts of saving and 
investment. To this we may add the massive stocks of foodgrains and 
burgeoning foreign exchange reserves of recent years. And we get a 
very different picture of the economy from the one portrayed by V K R 
V Rao and others in the 1950s - quite far from Keynesian full 
employment, an economy where there are significant slacks that can be 
deployed productively for employment generation. The key word here is 
'productively'. Spending money on the most critical national 
priorities - universal access to primary education, midday meals, 
healthcare, water, food and work - could actually 'crowd-in' private 
investment and create the foundations for non-inflationary growth in 
the medium-term.

Placed in the context of the current crisis of Indian agriculture, 
the argument against the 'crowding-out' view becomes even more 
telling. The single most important factor contributing to the dismal 
performance of Indian agriculture in the 1990s is the decline in 
public capital formation. Gross capital formation in agriculture as a 
proportion of total capital formation in the Indian economy declined 
from an average of 17 per cent in the 1970s to under 12 per cent in 
the 1980s and it was just 9 per cent in the first half of the 1990s. 
Public capital formation in agriculture that grew in real terms at 19 
per cent per annum in the 1970s, actually fell by an average rate of 
nearly 5 per cent annually in the 1980s and even more precipitously 
by 7 per cent annually between 1986 and 1993. Public investment in 
agriculture in real terms (1980-81 prices) was just Rs 1,200 crore in 
1991-92 compared to Rs 1,800 crore in 1979-80 [Dhawan and Yadav 1995, 
1997]. Gross public capital formation in Indian agriculture (at 
1993-94 prices) fell from Rs 4,947 crore in 1994-95 to Rs 3,919 crore 
in 2000-01. Over the same period its share in gross capital formation 
in agriculture declined by 10 per cent [CSO 2004].

To understand the present crisis in rural India, we need to 
acknowledge that our villages are in the throes of a grave 
environmental crisis. This crisis has reached such proportions that 
it is endangering the very livelihoods of the peasantry. Following 
the green revolution of the 1970s, there has been a veritable 
explosion of tubewell irrigation in large parts of India. These 
include the 65-70 per cent of the country that is underlain by hard, 
impermeable rock formations. In these areas the use of this 
technology has engendered a man-made crisis of water. In less than 30 
years, tube-wells have literally 'mined' water that took thousands of 
years to accumulate beneath the ground. The hydrogeology of these 
regions allows water to recharge aquifers pitifully slowly. As a 
result water tables have fallen dramatically. Many rivers in the 
rural hinterlands of India, fed by groundwater base-flows, have dried 
up. The catchment areas of the main sources of water - rivers, wells 
and tubewells - have been progressively decimated. This has meant 
that rates of soil erosion have increased, which has significantly 
reduced the lifespan of all our dams, many of which were constructed 
at massive financial, social and ecological cost to the people of 
India.

Drinking Water Crisis

Falling water tables and rapidly silting water reservoirs have led to 
a major crisis of drinking water that has not spared our towns and 
cities either. At the same time, the productivity of India's 
drylands, already neglected by the green revolution strategy, has 
been endangered. Even in the headquarters of the green revolution, 
such as Punjab and Haryana, the government is urging farmers to 
switch to a less water-intensive cropping pattern.

What the situation calls for is a massive increase in public 
investment in rural India in the direction of sustainable 
environmental regeneration. Votaries of privatisation may note that 
agriculture in India is already completely private. Its future hinges 
on what we do to restore the health of the many 'public goods' that 
private agriculture critically depends on. The environmental crisis 
of Indian agriculture represents a classic case of market failure. 
Unregulated actions of individual economic agents have been neither 
adequate nor appropriate. They have, rather, precipitated a crisis of 
public goods that threatens the very future of farming in India. 
Attempts to maximise their share of water by competitive farmers and 
industries have, for example, led to over-extraction of groundwater, 
which by its very nature is a 'fugitive' common pool resource. To 
recharge this groundwater needs urgent and large-scale measures to 
treat the catchments of these depleted aquifers. This would slow down 
the velocity of fast running off surface water and convert it into 
more usable groundwater. This fast flowing surface run-off is also 
the main cause of soil erosion, a principal contributor to declining 
soil fertility and agricultural productivity in India. Catchment area 
treatment and rain water harvesting are, therefore, key areas of 
public investment in rural India that can help restore water tables, 
improve agricultural productivity and increase the lifespan of our 
dams. These catchments comprise forests and wastelands, which are 
also common pool resources, decimated mainly by actions of various 
industries and corrupt government forest departments. The investments 
needed to protect and treat them are beyond the capacities of 
individual farmers, especially the vast majority of small and 
marginal peasants. The future of these farmers depends on critical 
investments that can only be undertaken by the state. Similarly, in 
the flood-prone and waterlogged areas of eastern India, restoring the 
profitability of agriculture requires massive investments in drainage 
systems comprising interlinked ponds across many villages and 
hundreds of farmers in each micro-watershed. These have to be 
undertaken by the state. Till these investments are made, assisted by 
local grass roots institutions in the requisite social mobilisation, 
agriculture in most parts of India, neglected or inappropriately 
impacted by the green revolution, will have no future.2 However, once 
the necessary public investments are in place, a whole chain of 
complementary private investments are likely to be set into motion, 
setting off the economy on to a path of sustainable agricultural 
growth. Which is the only way the non-agricultural sector could also 
gain momentum in rural India. Once there is water, we can conceive of 
many non-farm activities that can be sustained such as pisciculture, 
dairy development, agro-processing, etc.3

Public investments of this kind would, therefore, not have a 
crowding-out effect on private investment. Because they would 
contribute positively to higher growth rates in the economy, their 
inflationary potential would also be held firmly in check. Especially 
in a situation where there are comfortable stocks of foodgrain 
available for financing these investments. One argument made against 
the feasibility of using foodgrain stocks is that they are only a 
temporary phenomenon. Such a claim does not quite match up with the 
facts. For the last 10 years food stocks have been much higher than 
the buffer stock requirements. And the investments we are advocating 
would help continuously replenish these stocks. Indeed, I would argue 
that it is only these sort of investments that can help sustain the 
attempt by the government to both provide support prices to farmers 
and cheap grain to the poor through the Public Distribution System 
(PDS). Let me explain. What a massive employment programme will do is 
to raise offtake of grain in two ways - directly when wages are paid 
in grain4  and indirectly by putting incomes in the hands of the 
poor. These will enable them to buy PDS grain, which they are 
currently too poor to afford. Today, nearly two-thirds of the food 
subsidy comprises the 'carrying cost' of grain [Abhijit Sen Committee 
Report 2002]. This is because the offtake of grain from the PDS is 
much lower than it should be. This is, of course, partly a 
consequence of the government's decision to raise PDS prices in 
recent years as also the introduction of the targeted PDS. 5  But 
most fundamentally it reflects the inability of the poorest to buy 
grain due to lack of purchasing power. Thus, a rise in purchasing 
power of the poor can help lower the burden of food subsidies by 
raising PDS offtake and thereby reducing the carrying cost of grain. 
This will also enable government to continue to provide price support 
to farmers. Otherwise the scissors will get too tight. The pressure 
to reduce food subsidy will require either that PDS prices be raised 
or that support prices be frozen. Ours is a win-win suggestion. 
Public investment in environmental regeneration could not only 
improve the environment and water supplies, it will make possible a 
quantum increase in agricultural productivity of small and marginal 
farmers in the neglected regions of India that have a massive 
untapped potential. This will keep up the supply of food available 
for employment programmes, midday meals, ICDS and the PDS, where 
offtake levels will rise because of higher incomes with the poor. 
Which will allow the food subsidy to be kept under control.6  The 
need for public investment will also come down over time because the 
number of people who need support through public works will decline. 
For millions of those who are forced to work outside their land will 
be able to support their families on their own farms. Indeed, the 
share of private investment in gross capital formation in agriculture 
will gradually increase over time.

Significance of the NREGA

The best way of undertaking the necessary public investment is by 
enshrining it as a constitutional right. This employment programme 
cannot be allowed to remain dependent on the moody munificence of a 
vacillating welfare state. It has to be seen as a national imperative 
and as an inalienable right to be exercised by the people as and when 
they require to.

The NREGA that aims to cover all of rural India within five years, is 
an attempt in this direction. It is an act with a potential 
socio-political significance for the rural poor that is matched only 
by the 73rd Amendment. One version of the proposed NREGA bill seeks 
to provide "at least one hundred days of guaranteed employment at the 
statutory minimum wage" to adult members of every rural household who 
volunteer to do casual manual work. For this a dedicated National 
Employment Guarantee Fund is to be set up that will be expended 
exclusively for implementation of the act. It is disappointing that 
the right has been restricted to households, rather than opening it 
up to each individual in need, especially in view of intra-household 
gender discrimination. The household condition also opens up a 
minefield of recording problems, since there is a great fluidity in 
the way members of the same household typically report to work in 
rural employment programmes in India. The restriction to only 100 
days also does not make sense. The right to work is to be exercised 
by people in need. These needs will vary depending on the vagaries of 
nature. They could be for more or less than 100 days. In years and 
areas of severe drought the requirement could be greater. In other 
seasons and places, the demand for work will be less. Is the 
government saying that it will not respect this right when people 
need it the most? An act is different from a government scheme. The 
financial allocations for schemes can vary from year to year. If the 
necessity for it declines over time, as it should if implemented 
properly in the right direction, the allocations can be reduced. But 
the whole point of an employment guarantee act must surely be to 
provide work to people as a matter of right when their need is the 
greatest. The saving grace is that the act leaves it open to the 
central and state governments "to raise the household entitlement 
beyond 100 days, or extend it to every adult, in some or all areas of 
India, through suitable provisions made in the rules".

Indeed, the act has many remarkable provisions. Wages are to be paid 
every week and in any event not later than a fortnight. In case of 
any delay in the payment of wages, labourers will be entitled to 
compensation as per the Payment of Wages Act. It is also provided 
that under no circumstances "shall there be any discrimination on the 
basis of gender in the provision of employment or the payment of 
wages, as per the provisions of the Equal Remuneration Act 1976". 
There are provisions for compensation and treatment in case of injury 
and for on-site safe drinking water, care of small children, periods 
of rest and a first-aid box. The act also forbids the use of 
contractors and labour displacing machines. At least 60 per cent of 
the expenditure under any project has to be on wages. These are all 
provisions so commonly violated in many parts of rural India that 
their significance cannot be sufficiently underscored.

At least 50 per cent of the projects, in terms of value, are to be 
implemented through the gram panchayats. Each gram panchayat is to 
prepare a development plan and maintain a shelf of possible works to 
be taken up under the programme as and when demand for work arises, 
taking into account the recommendations of the gram sabha (and, if 
applicable, ward sabha). Proposals for these projects, including an 
order of priority between different works, will be sent to the 
programme officer for scrutiny and preliminary approval. The 
programme officer will be responsible for the implementation of the 
employment guarantee programme in the block.

Adult members of every rural household who are willing to do casual 
manual work at the statutory minimum wage will apply to the gram 
panchayat for registration. The gram panchayat will register the 
household, after making necessary enquiries and issue a job card 
containing details of its adult members along with their photographs. 
The registration will be for a period not less than five years, and 
may be renewed from time to time. Employment will be provided to 
every registered person within 15 days of receipt of an application. 
Applications must be for at least 14 days of continuous work. The 
gram panchayat is bound to accept valid applications and to issue a 
dated receipt to the applicant. Group applications may also be 
submitted. Applicants who are provided with work will be notified in 
writing, by means of a letter sent to the address given in the job 
card and by a public notice displayed at the gram panchayat office. 
As far as possible, employment will be provided within a radius of 5 
km. Even if work is provided beyond 5 km, it will be provided within 
the block, and the labourers paid 10 per cent of the daily minimum 
wages extra, to meet additional transportation and living expenses.

Daily Unemployment Allowance

If the applicants are not provided with work as described above, they 
will be entitled to a daily unemployment allowance after 15 days from 
the date of application. The unemployment allowance will be at least 
one-fourth of the prevailing statutory minimum wage for the first 30 
days and not less than half of the minimum wage for the subsequent 
days. Of course, there is a provision that applicants who do not 
accept the employment provided and/or do not report for work within 
15 days of being notified or remain continuously absent from work, 
without a valid exemption, for more than one week, will be debarred 
from claiming unemployment allowance for a period of three months. 
There is a whole section in the act dealing with transparency, 
accountability and audit. The gram sabha is to monitor the work of 
the gram panchayat through regular social audits where all relevant 
documents, including muster rolls, bills, vouchers, measurement 
books, copies of sanctions, etc, will be made public. Completion and 
utilisation certificates of works are to be issued by the gram sabha. 
There is also provision for penalty: "whoever fails to carry out 
his/her obligations under this act, without any reasonable cause, 
shall be liable upon summary conviction to a fine of not less than Rs 
1,000".

However, just as with the 73rd Amendment empowering panchayats, the 
real significance of all these provisions will be directly 
proportionate to the extent and manner in which they are creatively 
pushed to their limits by the very same forces of change at the grass 
roots who played a critical role in their being included in the act 
in the first place. In a society beset with deep social and economic 
inequities, any such act can only create an additional space for 
change. The NREGA can become a major new instrument for galvanising 
panchayat raj institutions in India. But how far this actually 
happens will depend a great deal on the mobilisation of the 
disadvantaged in society - women, dalits, adivasis and the poor. In 
most parts of India, these sections have virtually no voice in the 
gram sabhas, which have been reduced to a farce. Without their 
mobilisation and empowerment, the full socio-political potential of 
the act will not be realised. The role of grass roots civil society 
institutions will be crucial here.

Postscript: Now comes the news that the draft of the NREGA approved 
by the ministry of rural development (referred to in this paper) is 
being sought to be badly diluted prior to its being placed before 
parliament. The right to work is sought to be restricted to 'poor' 
households, the extension of the act to the entire country within 
five years has been put on hold and the payment of minimum wages is 
sought to be made 'non-obligatory'. These changes are a major setback 
in the movement towards a genuine right to work. If the poor are 
going to be understood as those holding BPL cards, the entire meaning 
of the act would be lost. The right to work will then get substituted 
by yet another scheme mindlessly targeted to those identified by the 
blatantly distorted and eminently discardable BPL survey. There is 
clearly more work to be done by those manning the trenches!

Notes

1       For Keynes at full employment, the effective demand 
elasticity of output and employment is zero.
2       Given the grim scenario of India's water resources, there is 
little consolation in arguing that the Indian economy would be better 
off depending less on agriculture. Without water, growth prospects of 
all sectors would be under threat. Catchment area treatment and water 
harvesting are, therefore, indispensable public investments for the 
Indian economy as a whole.
3       These are at least the indications from one of India's 
largest civil society initiatives for food and water security led by 
Samaj Pragati Sahayog in 50 districts across the four states of 
Madhya Pradesh, Chhattisgarh, Jharkhand and Bihar.
4       The NREGA allows up to 75 per cent of the wages to be paid in kind
5       This is also aggravated by practices such as the insistence 
(contrary to recent Supreme Court orders) that people buy in one shot 
all the grain they are entitled to in a month. The poor never have 
enough money at any given time to be able to do this. Of course, the 
very poor quality of much of PDS grain does not help either.
6       In no event should the government continue the current resort 
to exports as a way of keeping down the food subsidy. Between 1999 
and 2004, the annual diversion of food away from welfare schemes and 
employment programmes to exports and open market sales, has been 
around 25 per cent on an average.
References

Abhijit Sen Committee Report (2002): Report of the High Level 
Committee for Formulating a Long-term Grain Policy set up by the 
Union Ministry of Consumer Affairs, Food and Public Distribution.
Dasgupta, A K (1954): 'Keynesian Economics and Underdeveloped 
Countries', Economic Weekly.
Dhawan, B D and S S Yadav (1995): 'Private Capital Formation in 
Agriculture', Economic and Political Weekly, Vol XXX, No 39.
- (1997): 'Public Investment in Indian Agriculture', Economic and 
Political Weekly, Vol XXXII, No 14.
Kahn, R (1931): 'The Relation of Home Investment to Unemployment', 
Economic Journal.
Keynes, J M (1936): The General Theory of Employment, Interest and 
Money, Macmillan, London.
Malinvaud, E (1977): The Theory of Unemployment Reconsidered, Basil 
Blackwell, Oxford.
Rakshit, M (1989): 'Effective Demand in a Developing Country: 
Approaches and Issues' in M Rakshit (ed), Studies in the 
Macroeconomics of Developing Countries, Oxford University Press, 
Delhi.
- (2004): 'Some Puzzles of India's Macroeconomy' in K N Raj, 
Festschrift, Planning and Development: Institutions and Markets 
(mimeo).
Rao, V K R V (1952): 'Investment, Income and the Multiplier in an 
Underdeveloped Economy', Indian Economic Review.


_________________________________

Labour Notes South Asia (LNSA):
An informal archive and mailing list for trade
unionists and labour activists based in or
working on South asia.

LNSA Mailing List:
Labour Notes South Asia
To subscribe send a blank message to:
<[EMAIL PROTECTED]>

LNSA Web site:
groups.yahoo.com/group/lnsa/

Run by The South Asia Citizens Web
www.sacw.net
_________________________________








------------------------ Yahoo! Groups Sponsor --------------------~--> 
$4.98 domain names from Yahoo!. Register anything.
http://us.click.yahoo.com/Q7_YsB/neXJAA/yQLSAA/e0EolB/TM
--------------------------------------------------------------------~-> 

To join the Labour Notes South Asia Mailing List, send a blank message to:   
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
To Unsubscribe, send a blank message to: [EMAIL PROTECTED] 
Yahoo! Groups Links

<*> To visit your group on the web, go to:
    http://groups.yahoo.com/group/lnsa/

<*> To unsubscribe from this group, send an email to:
    [EMAIL PROTECTED]

<*> Your use of Yahoo! Groups is subject to:
    http://docs.yahoo.com/info/terms/
 



Reply via email to