Few days ago I came across a paper published in the last issue of 
EHR (LIII, 2000) "A critical survey of recent research in Chinese 
economic history" by Kent G. Deng. Paper evaluates one of the most 
heated questions of world history: why premodern China did not 
industrialize despite enjoying, at least until 1500,  Euroasian 
superiority in metallurgy, military power, navigational equipment, 
manufacture of silk and of porcelain, paper making, block printing, 
mechanical clocks, number and organization of  professional merchants, 
long-distance communication systems (roads and canals) throughout 
the country, "a remarkable degree of social mobility", standardized 
weights and measures, a non-agricultural population of about 20% of 
China's total, a multi-layerd network of  45, 000 market towns 
supported by a large number of "free, small-scale farmers, working 
under a system of private land-ownership"  - all this together with a 
single national government ("active in maintaining food supply, 
famine relief, and price control), a standardized written language, a 
dominant Confucian code of ethics".  

Although Deng questions the  Hegelian/Marxist unilinear conception 
which underlies "the use of  the European experience as a gauge to 
measure China", he recognizes that this has been a major 
preoccupation of historians, particularly of western scholars, among 
whom he detects nine schools of thought: those who emphasise, 
respectively, ideological factors, the way  the market functioned,  
environmental/geographical differences, the balance of class forces, 
population, technology, rent-seeking government, role of the state, 
and the world-system.  Having separated western scholarship into 
these nine schools, Deng has an easy time pointing to the 
(obvious)  weaknesses  of each.   Landes's Wealth and Poverty, for example, 
is brushed aside in just one short sentence: "When this bulky, narrative 
book is stripped to the kernel, the subject is 'culture' and cultural 
determinisn." More ink is spent on other works, but the discursive 
strategy which Deng employs is still extremely misleading, for it 
creates the illusion that every work on this question is pushing a 
particular brand of determinisn, when the truth is that most scholars 
today accept an overdetermined explanation, meaning not  the mutual 
causation of everything by everything (only  Resnick and Wolf would 
make this erroneous inference) but the overdetermination of one - or 
of  a  tight constellation of primary factors - by  many 
secondary/conjuctural/accidental factors.   

I agree that in the case of  somelike like Jared Diamond we are 
dealing  - explicitly though not implicitly - with a strong 
environmental determinism, but even in his case 
one does not refute him by showing (obviously) that the environment 
is not everything, or by pointing  - as Deng does, to a quick 
similarity  between Europe's and China's geography. We have enough of 
that in Blaut (or in the Monthly Review). Here's Deng: "what is often 
overlooked is that there is an 'Asian Mediterranean' in the China 
seas. In the past, different peoples met, migrated, and traded there. 
Moonsoon winds favored shipping in the Asian Mediterranean and there 
is no reason to view Asia as geographically inferior to the 
Mediterranean on the other side of Euroasia. Therefore, geographic 
difference no longer provides a safe haven for enviromental 
determinisn in studying China." 

Deng cites a paper by Diamond in *Nature*, not the book, but it is 
important to understand that in the book Diamond says that 
"geographic connectedness and only modest internal barriers gave 
China an initial advantage." But he then adds that "China's connectedness 
eventually became a disadvantage, because a decision by one despot 
could and repeatedly did halt innovation. In contrast, E's 
geographic balkanization resulted in dozens or hundreds of 
independent, competing stateless and centers of innovation. If one 
state did not pursue some particular innovation, another did, forcing 
neighboring states to do likewise or else be conquered or left 
economically behind." 

This is a view long  argued by  neo-Weberians, but in their writings 
the  *political/military* dimension of this apparent 
geographic determinism becomes transparent: in Europe we had an 
international political organization known as the *interstate* 
system. Every effort at creating a world empire had failed. Deng 
could have recognized this political aspect right here in his 
analysis of "geography, but he prefers to divide 
and rule, so he approaches this political issue separetely, and 
responds, this time against Mokyr, that "China always faced 
competition from the Steppes and increasingly so after AD 1000: from 
the Tartars, Mongols, and Manchus, to name just a few."  

But this point still misses the net: European inter-state competition 
was between relatively equal state powers, and it was more intense 
and sustained than elsewhere. Also, we need to understand the 
role of *culture* in this context as well (which is implicit in Diamond's 
use of the word "innovation"). As Chirot writes: "There existed 
a European-wide culture in which learned men, traders, pilgrims, 
mercenaries, sailors, and statesmen moved with ease across political 
boundaries...Intolerant dogmatism pushed good minds, capital, and 
skilled men to other states and prevented stagnation. Thus it was 
that German printing techniques, Italian banking methods, Dutch 
cartography, Portuguese maritime experience, and the explosion of 
learning, art, and science spread throughout Europe to help those who 
knew how to use them". 

I would insist that the Mediterranean is unique geographically in the way 
that it connects to the rest of the world, and in the way that it  
acted as the busiest cultural/ethnic intersection in world history. 
Leave that and the other schools which Deng criticises for later.       

Reply via email to