[EM] PR methods and Quotas

2011-07-24 Thread Andy Jennings
Like Jameson and Toby, I have spent some time thinking about how to make a
median-based PR system.

The system I came up with is similar to Jameson's, but simpler, and uses the
Hare quota!

Say there are 100 voters and you're going to elect ten representatives.
 Each representative should represent 10 people, so why not choose the first
one by choosing the candidate who makes 10 people the happiest?  (The one
whose tenth highest grade is the highest.)  Then, take the 10 voters who
helped elect this candidate and eliminate their ballots.  (There might be
more than ten and you'd have to choose ten or use fractional voters.  I have
ideas for that, but lets gloss over that issue for now.)  You can even tell
those 10 voters who their representative is.

Electing the next seat should be the same way.  Choose someone who is the
best representative for 10 people.  Repeat.

The only problem is when you get down to the last representative.  If you
follow this pattern, the last candidate is the one whose LOWEST grade among
the remaining ballots is the highest, which is rather unorthodox.  You could
change the rules and just use the median on the last seat, but using the
highest minimum grade does have a certain attraction to it.  You're going to
force those last ten voters to have some representative.  It makes some
sense to choose the one who maximizes the happiness of the least happy
voter.  (Though ties at a grade of 0 may be common.)

But this system doesn't reduce to median voting.  Which got me thinking...
 Is there anything that special about the 50th percentile in the
single-winner case anyways?  I can imagine lots of single-winner situations
where it's more egalitarian to choose a lower percentile.  In a small and
friendly group, even choosing the winner with the highest minimum grade is a
good social choice method.  It's like giving each person veto power and
still hoping you can find something everyone can live with.  This is the
method we tend to use (informally) when I'm in a group choosing where to go
to lunch together.

Thoughts?

Andy

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] PR-SODA? Try 2 (and 3)

2011-07-24 Thread Andy Jennings
On Thu, Jul 21, 2011 at 9:45 AM, Jameson Quinn jameson.qu...@gmail.comwrote:

 So, here's the simpler procedure:

 While there are more uneliminated candidates than empty seats:

 Divide each ballot by the number of uneliminated candidates it approves
 If there are any candidates with more than a Droop quota:

 Elect the one with the highest score (previously unique ballots)
 Discard a Droop quota of randomly-chosen ballots which approve the elected
 candidate, starting with the ones delegated to that candidate
 Assign that candidates pre-declared approvals on any undiscarded delegated
 ballots for that candidate

 Otherwise:

 Eliminate the candidate with the lowest score
 Assign that candidates pre-declared approvals on any delegated ballots for
 that candidate

 Elect all remaining candidates to fill the seats.



Okay, I really love how simple this is.  From the description, it sounds
like it would be explainable and would work well.  I wonder how it does in
simulations and if we can find any problematic scenarios.

Questions:
- Is there a bullet vote but don't delegate option like normal SODA?

- Would it work just as well with the Hare quota?

- Without the delegation, is it the same as any other
PR-with-approval-ballots method in existence?

Suggestions:
- When a candidate is elected and you need to discard ballots, you could
specify a more detailed preference order:
1. Ballots which delegated to that candidate
2. Ballots which bullet voted that candidate and didn't delegate
3. Ballots which approved two candidates
4. Ballots which approved three candidates
5. Ballots which approved four candidates
6. And so on.
This eliminates ballots first which approve fewer candidates.  You may still
have to select randomly within these tiers, but it gives an incentive for
people to approve more candidates, which helps the method work better.
 Right?


- Andy

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] PR methods and Quotas

2011-07-24 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

Andy Jennings wrote:
Like Jameson and Toby, I have spent some time thinking about how to make 
a median-based PR system.


The system I came up with is similar to Jameson's, but simpler, and uses 
the Hare quota!


How about clustering logic? Say you have an electorate of n voters, and 
you want k seats. The method would be combinatorial: you'd check a 
prospective slate. Say the slate is {ABC...}. Then that means you make a 
group of n/k voters and assign A to this gorup, another group of n/k 
other voters and assign B to that group, and so on.
The score of each slate is equal to the sum of the median scores for 
each assigned candidate, when considering only the voters in the 
assigned candidate's group. That is, A's median score when considering 
the voters of the first group, plus B's median score when considering 
the voters of the second group, and so on. The voters are moved into 
groups so that this sum is maximized.


Actually determining where to move each voter to optimize this might be 
quite hard, though. But if you could make it work, then that would seem 
to do what you wanted: it gives one candidate to represent the first 
n/k, one candidate to represent the next n/k, etc, and picks the council 
that makes these people most happy.


Say there are 100 voters and you're going to elect ten representatives. 
 Each representative should represent 10 people, so why not choose the 
first one by choosing the candidate who makes 10 people the happiest? 
 (The one whose tenth highest grade is the highest.)  Then, take the 10 
voters who helped elect this candidate and eliminate their ballots. 
 (There might be more than ten and you'd have to choose ten or use 
fractional voters.  I have ideas for that, but lets gloss over that 
issue for now.)  You can even tell those 10 voters who their 
representative is.


I imagine you could eliminate the voters directly, though that would 
have some path dependence problems (which was why I suggested the 
above). Say you make use of highest tenth grade. Then you know which 
voters voted the candidate in question that high. Eliminate these. Find 
the highest tenth with those voters elminated, among uneliminated 
candidates. Again, you know the 10 voters who voted the next winner at 
that level or higher. Eliminate *them*. And so on down.


Is that what you're suggesting? Then the last candidate is only the one 
with the best worst votes in the sense that there are only ten voters left.


How about using the midpoint? That is, you find the 5th voter down, not 
the 10th. Then when you're down to the last 10 voters, the 5th voter 
down is the median. Doing so would seem to reduce it to median ratings 
in the single-winner case, since 100/1 = 100, so you'd pick the 
midpoint, i.e. at the 50th voter, which is the median.


Electing the next seat should be the same way.  Choose someone who is 
the best representative for 10 people.  Repeat.


The only problem is when you get down to the last representative.  If 
you follow this pattern, the last candidate is the one whose LOWEST 
grade among the remaining ballots is the highest, which is rather 
unorthodox.  You could change the rules and just use the median on the 
last seat, but using the highest minimum grade does have a certain 
attraction to it.  You're going to force those last ten voters to have 
some representative.  It makes some sense to choose the one who 
maximizes the happiness of the least happy voter.  (Though ties at a 
grade of 0 may be common.)


But this system doesn't reduce to median voting.  Which got me 
thinking...  Is there anything that special about the 50th percentile in 
the single-winner case anyways?  I can imagine lots of single-winner 
situations where it's more egalitarian to choose a lower percentile.  In 
a small and friendly group, even choosing the winner with the highest 
minimum grade is a good social choice method.  It's like giving each 
person veto power and still hoping you can find something everyone can 
live with.  This is the method we tend to use (informally) when I'm in a 
group choosing where to go to lunch together.


I think the median is used because it's robust. If you assume unlimited 
ratings, the maximum and minimum could be altered by a single voter 
(whoever's at the min or max), as could the mean (by any outlier). 
However, the median is robust to distorted values - quite a number of 
voters would have to change their votes to alter the median.


In one way, then, the median is a way of robustly estimating a property 
related to the shape of the function given by the voters' ratings, even 
in the presence of noise (or strategy). To keep this reasoning for 
multiwinner, one should find out what properties one want to know about 
for multiwinner elections, then find a way of robustly estimating these.



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Single Contest

2011-07-24 Thread Andy Jennings
On Sat, Jul 23, 2011 at 11:28 AM, fsimm...@pcc.edu wrote:

 If one of the finalists is chosen by a method that satisfies the majority
 criterion, then you can skip step
 one, and the method becomes smoother.

 Here are some possibilities for the method that satisfies the majority
 criterion:  DSC, Bucklin, and the
 following range ballot based method:

 Elect the candidate X with the greatest value of p such that more than p/2
 percent of the ballots rate X at
 least p percent of the maxRange value.


Forest,

Can you clarify your definition of the majority criterion?  I don't think
this method satisfies it.

As a general example, suppose there are two candidates, A and B.  The voting
range is 0-100 and there are 5 voters:
1 voter: A=10 B=30
1 voter: A=30 B=50
1 voter: A=50 B=70
1 voter: A=70 B=90
1 voter: A=90 B=10

B is strictly preferred to A by 4 out of 5 voters, but these two candidates
have the exact same set of votes.  Any method which forgets which voter gave
which vote must consider them exactly tied.  This includes score (range)
voting, majority judgement, the chiastic median, and any of the other
generalized medians.  Thus, with only some minor perturbation, A can defeat
B in any of these methods.

In the chiastic median (or the majority judgement), both candidates have
societal grades of 50, but if you change A=50 to A=51 for the third voter,
A's societal grade becomes 51 and A defeats B, despite strong majority
opposition.

In the p/2 system, 40% of the voters gave grades of 70 or above and 20% of
the voters gave grades strictly above 70, so both candidates get a societal
grade of 70.  But if you change A=70 to A=71 for the fourth voter, A's
societal grade becomes 71 and A defeats B, again despite a strong majority
opposition.

I think any method which forgets which voter gave which vote will never
satisfy the majority criterion.

- Andy

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Weighted voting systems for proportional representation

2011-07-24 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

Kathy Dopp wrote:

The system you describe *is* still precinct summable in the sense of
reporting the sums for each possible slate of candidates for each
precinct or polling location - this is at least a whole lot fewer sums
than the number of possible ballot choice permutations including
partially filled out ballots that IRV/STV would require to be reported
and sampled to be precinct summable (reporting all individual ballots'
choices would be less to report in most cases).

To be summable, this system would require reporting (N choose S) sums
where N is the number of total candidates in the contest and S is the
number of seats being elected.  This is a lot of sums - but could, I
imagine, be mathematically sampled and audited to limit the risk of
certifying the wrong slate much more easily than IRV methods could be
- but I'm not certain about that until I have the time to think about
it more (not any time soon).


Ah, yes. This leads me back to an older thought that perhaps the 
criterion of summability should be refined for multiwinner methods by 
turning it into two criteria. These criteria would be:


- Weak summability: If the number of seats is fixed, one can find the 
winner of the method according to precinct sums, where the amount of 
data required for these sums grows as a polynomial with respect to the 
number of candidates, and as a polylogarithmic function with respect to 
the number of voters.


- Strong summability: Same as weak, but without the number of seats 
being fixed or known in advance.


To my knowledge, Schulze STV is weakly summable, as is this method, 
because if you fix S, N choose S is bounded by a polynomial.


When people here talk about summability for multiwinner methods, they 
usually mean strong summability, though. This is like SNTV or party 
list. If you have the Plurality counts for SNTV, it doesn't matter how 
many seats you want, you can just read off the n first Plurality 
winners. Similarly, for party list, you can just run the Sainte-Laguë 
method n times for n seats with the same input data.


Do you think weak summability is sufficient to audit multiwinner methods?


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] PR methods and Quotas

2011-07-24 Thread Andy Jennings
Kristofer Munsterhjelm wrote:

 Andy Jennings wrote:

 Like Jameson and Toby, I have spent some time thinking about how to make a
 median-based PR system.

 The system I came up with is similar to Jameson's, but simpler, and uses
 the Hare quota!


 How about clustering logic? Say you have an electorate of n voters, and you
 want k seats. The method would be combinatorial: you'd check a prospective
 slate. Say the slate is {ABC...}. Then that means you make a group of n/k
 voters and assign A to this gorup, another group of n/k other voters and
 assign B to that group, and so on.
 The score of each slate is equal to the sum of the median scores for each
 assigned candidate, when considering only the voters in the assigned
 candidate's group. That is, A's median score when considering the voters of
 the first group, plus B's median score when considering the voters of the
 second group, and so on. The voters are moved into groups so that this sum
 is maximized.


The median is not what you want for clustering like this, because it
basically ignores the scores of half the voters assigned to each candidate.
 That is, if I'm assigning 11 voters to each candidate, I can assign 6
voters who love that candidate and 5 voters who hate the candidate and still
have a very high median.


 Say there are 100 voters and you're going to elect ten representatives.
  Each representative should represent 10 people, so why not choose the first
 one by choosing the candidate who makes 10 people the happiest?  (The one
 whose tenth highest grade is the highest.)  Then, take the 10 voters who
 helped elect this candidate and eliminate their ballots.  (There might be
 more than ten and you'd have to choose ten or use fractional voters.  I have
 ideas for that, but lets gloss over that issue for now.)  You can even tell
 those 10 voters who their representative is.


 I imagine you could eliminate the voters directly, though that would have
 some path dependence problems (which was why I suggested the above). Say you
 make use of highest tenth grade. Then you know which voters voted the
 candidate in question that high. Eliminate these. Find the highest tenth
 with those voters elminated, among uneliminated candidates. Again, you know
 the 10 voters who voted the next winner at that level or higher. Eliminate
 *them*. And so on down.

 Is that what you're suggesting?


Yes, this is what I'm suggesting.


 Then the last candidate is only the one with the best worst votes in the
 sense that there are only ten voters left.

 How about using the midpoint? That is, you find the 5th voter down, not the
 10th. Then when you're down to the last 10 voters, the 5th voter down is the
 median. Doing so would seem to reduce it to median ratings in the
 single-winner case, since 100/1 = 100, so you'd pick the midpoint, i.e. at
 the 50th voter, which is the median.


True, but in filling the first seat, I don't think we should take a
candidate loved by 5 and hated by 95 as the first choice to represent
one-tenth of the population.



 But this system doesn't reduce to median voting.  Which got me thinking...
  Is there anything that special about the 50th percentile in the
 single-winner case anyways?  I can imagine lots of single-winner situations
 where it's more egalitarian to choose a lower percentile.  In a small and
 friendly group, even choosing the winner with the highest minimum grade is a
 good social choice method.  It's like giving each person veto power and
 still hoping you can find something everyone can live with.  This is the
 method we tend to use (informally) when I'm in a group choosing where to go
 to lunch together.


 I think the median is used because it's robust. If you assume unlimited
 ratings, the maximum and minimum could be altered by a single voter
 (whoever's at the min or max), as could the mean (by any outlier). However,
 the median is robust to distorted values - quite a number of voters would
 have to change their votes to alter the median.


With any finite number of voters, the median is still the score of one
voter, who can change the median by changing his vote.  But you are right
that if the scores follow a normal distribution, then he probably can't
change the median very much before he crosses another voter's score and is
not the median vote anymore.   But that's not true for a bimodal
distribution.

- Andy

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] PR methods and Quotas

2011-07-24 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

Andy Jennings wrote:

Kristofer Munsterhjelm wrote:

Andy Jennings wrote:

Like Jameson and Toby, I have spent some time thinking about how
to make a median-based PR system.

The system I came up with is similar to Jameson's, but simpler,
and uses the Hare quota!


How about clustering logic? Say you have an electorate of n voters,
and you want k seats. The method would be combinatorial: you'd check
a prospective slate. Say the slate is {ABC...}. Then that means you
make a group of n/k voters and assign A to this gorup, another group
of n/k other voters and assign B to that group, and so on.
The score of each slate is equal to the sum of the median scores for
each assigned candidate, when considering only the voters in the
assigned candidate's group. That is, A's median score when
considering the voters of the first group, plus B's median score
when considering the voters of the second group, and so on. The
voters are moved into groups so that this sum is maximized.


The median is not what you want for clustering like this, because it 
basically ignores the scores of half the voters assigned to each 
candidate.  That is, if I'm assigning 11 voters to each candidate, I can 
assign 6 voters who love that candidate and 5 voters who hate the 
candidate and still have a very high median.


Well, yes, but the same thing holds for median ratings in general. If 
you want to find someone who represents the whole population, median 
ratings can pick someone who is loved by 51% and hated by 49%, rather 
than someone that 80% think are okay (and I think Warren have made 
arguments to the effect that this makes Range better than median).


The question then is: what makes that logic okay when you're electing a 
single representative for the whole population, but not okay when you're 
electing one of ten representatives for 10% of the population? Is it the 
fluid nature of the clustering - that the optimizer could try to 
artificially inflate the scores by packing hate A voters into the A-group?



Then the last candidate is only the one with the best worst votes in
the sense that there are only ten voters left.

How about using the midpoint? That is, you find the 5th voter down,
not the 10th. Then when you're down to the last 10 voters, the 5th
voter down is the median. Doing so would seem to reduce it to median
ratings in the single-winner case, since 100/1 = 100, so you'd pick
the midpoint, i.e. at the 50th voter, which is the median.


True, but in filling the first seat, I don't think we should take a 
candidate loved by 5 and hated by 95 as the first choice to represent 
one-tenth of the population.


I guess you could be more gentle by placing the point at 50% (1/2) for 
one winner, 1/3 for two, 1/4 for three ... 1/11 for ten. That would be 
more Droop-like and less Hare-like. But then you can't simply eliminate 
those who contributed to the voting, I think.


With any finite number of voters, the median is still the score of one 
voter, who can change the median by changing his vote.  But you are 
right that if the scores follow a normal distribution, then he probably 
can't change the median very much before he crosses another voter's 
score and is not the median vote anymore.   But that's not true for a 
bimodal distribution.


He can't alter the median to an arbitrary extent, however. An outlier at 
the mean can do so by setting his score arbitrarily high (or low), and 
the max or min voter can do so, but to a limited extent, by raising his 
score (if he's max) or lowering his score (if he's min). If the median 
voter alters his score by too much, he's no longer the median voter. 
That may change the median result by some amount (unless the new median 
voter expresses the same score as the old one used to), but it's limited.


Ah, there is a term for this reasoning. 
https://secure.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/en/wiki/Breakdown_point#Breakdown_point


I haven't investigated it in detail though :-)


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] How to make a summable version of STV

2011-07-24 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

fsimm...@pcc.edu wrote:

Kristopfer.

Look at it this way, the process of amalgamating the factions is a
low pass filter that gets rid of some fo the noise.  So why not
consider the resulting ballots as the true ballots, and the
associated weights tell how many of them there are of each kinsd.
STV can be done with these new true ballots, Droop quotas and all.


Sure, but these reformulated criteria are less useful than the ordinary 
criteria. For instance, the Droop proportionality criterion means that 
voters don't have to coordinate the ordering of their preferred set 
(except regarding vote management). In the case of an absolutely 
preferred candidate like X, if your low-pass filter is in place, the 
voters now have to remember to not rank X top, which weakens the 
guarantee given by the DPC.



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Automated Approval methods (was Single Contest)

2011-07-24 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

Kevin Venzke wrote:


I also tried implementing the most obvious (I suppose) method: Take the
ratings and conduct simulated approval polling, either for some
determined or semi-random number of iterations, or until someone wins
twice in a row. This doesn't test as well as I thought it would though.


What Approval strategy do you use?


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] PR methods and Quotas

2011-07-24 Thread Andy Jennings
Kristofer Munsterhjelm wrote:

 Andy Jennings wrote:

 Kristofer Munsterhjelm wrote:

Andy Jennings wrote:

Like Jameson and Toby, I have spent some time thinking about how
to make a median-based PR system.

The system I came up with is similar to Jameson's, but simpler,
and uses the Hare quota!


How about clustering logic? Say you have an electorate of n voters,
and you want k seats. The method would be combinatorial: you'd check
a prospective slate. Say the slate is {ABC...}. Then that means you
make a group of n/k voters and assign A to this gorup, another group
of n/k other voters and assign B to that group, and so on.
The score of each slate is equal to the sum of the median scores for
each assigned candidate, when considering only the voters in the
assigned candidate's group. That is, A's median score when
considering the voters of the first group, plus B's median score
when considering the voters of the second group, and so on. The
voters are moved into groups so that this sum is maximized.


 The median is not what you want for clustering like this, because it
 basically ignores the scores of half the voters assigned to each candidate.
  That is, if I'm assigning 11 voters to each candidate, I can assign 6
 voters who love that candidate and 5 voters who hate the candidate and still
 have a very high median.


 Well, yes, but the same thing holds for median ratings in general. If you
 want to find someone who represents the whole population, median ratings can
 pick someone who is loved by 51% and hated by 49%, rather than someone that
 80% think are okay (and I think Warren have made arguments to the effect
 that this makes Range better than median).


Exactly.  This is why I'm questioning the median even for single-winner
elections.  Maybe you're right and we should be using the 20th percentile,
which would give us the candidate that some 80% of the population liked
best.  I tried to point out some arguments that highest minimum might be a
good method even in some single-winner environments.  It does give everyone
veto power.  But that's okay if everyone is committed to finding a solution
that's acceptable to everyone.  (In a public method, obviously, you'd have
to have some tie-breaker, like electing the candidate vetoed by the fewest
voters.)


 The question then is: what makes that logic okay when you're electing a
 single representative for the whole population, but not okay when you're
 electing one of ten representatives for 10% of the population? Is it the
 fluid nature of the clustering - that the optimizer could try to
 artificially inflate the scores by packing hate A voters into the A-group?


Yes, the fluid nature makes it much worse.  Say there are 110 voters and
we're choosing 10 winners.  Here's the voter profile:
50 people love A and noone else
6 people love B and noone else
6 people love C and noone else
...
6 people love K and noone else

If A were a political party, it would be entitled to at least 4 out of the
ten seats.  As a candidate, you would expect A to get a seat.  But we can
cluster the voters into:
6 voters who love B and 5 voters who love A
6 voters who love C and 5 voters who love A
...
6 voters who love K and 5 voters who love A

And then we elect B,C,..., and K, each with a perfect median in their
cluster.

Clustering with the median in each cluster is way too under-determined.

   Then the last candidate is only the one with the best worst votes in
the sense that there are only ten voters left.

How about using the midpoint? That is, you find the 5th voter down,
not the 10th. Then when you're down to the last 10 voters, the 5th
voter down is the median. Doing so would seem to reduce it to median
ratings in the single-winner case, since 100/1 = 100, so you'd pick
the midpoint, i.e. at the 50th voter, which is the median.


 True, but in filling the first seat, I don't think we should take a
 candidate loved by 5 and hated by 95 as the first choice to represent
 one-tenth of the population.


 I guess you could be more gentle by placing the point at 50% (1/2) for one
 winner, 1/3 for two, 1/4 for three ... 1/11 for ten. That would be more
 Droop-like and less Hare-like. But then you can't simply eliminate those who
 contributed to the voting, I think.


Yes, it is much more Droop-like.  It seems arbitrary, though, to leave one
eleventh of the voters completely unrepresented.  (With STV, Droop is
natural, but with cardinal inputs, I see no justification for it.)


  With any finite number of voters, the median is still the score of one
 voter, who can change the median by changing his vote.  But you are right
 that if the scores follow a normal distribution, then he probably can't
 change the median very much before he crosses another voter's score and is
 not the median vote anymore.   But that's not true for a bimodal
 distribution.


 He can't alter the 

Re: [EM] Weighted voting systems for proportional representation

2011-07-24 Thread Juho Laatu
One approach to summability and auditing is to say that the target is to allow 
the district to count the votes and later check that at the top level their 
votes (or the votes of all districts) were counted correctly, AND to allow the 
top level to check that the districts will report their results correctly (they 
may e.g. want the districts to tell their final results before they hear what 
the results of the other districts were). In addition to these also the general 
public and independent auditors will benefit of having the results in a format 
that allows them to recount and check the results and that allows them to audit 
all the districts (and subdistricts, and top level) independently one by one. 
The key point is thus to provide transparency and easy and local checks in all 
directions.

If this is what we want, then an interesting new feature is the new information 
society and its technical capabilities. That makes almost all methods 
summable in the above mentioned sense. Let's say we use STV. With current 
technology it is not a big problem to require all poll stations to record all 
their ballots in some digital format. And it is easy to check, if needed, that 
the physical ballots actually correspond to the reported results. It is also 
easy to check at the top level that the results are correct since the digital 
space taken by few million STV ballots is not that big, and the time that 
computers take to check the results is not that big.

One may thus say that current digital storage, transport and computation 
capabilities can make almost any method summable in the discussed way.

But there are still some problems left. One could say that the summability 
criterion also includes a requirement of being able to sum up the votes so that 
the summed up votes will hide details of the individual votes. This may be 
needed to provide privacy and to avoid unwanted phenomena like coercion and 
vote selling. In this sense the above mentioned treatment of the STV votes may 
not be sufficient. The number of candidates may be high enough and the length 
of the ballots high enough to allow identification of individual ballots. If we 
want to guarantee also privacy some additional tricks are needed in this case.

My point was anyway that it isa also possible to divide this summability / 
auditing / privacy requirement in two parts so that it will consist of the 1) 
easy verifiability and 2) privacy parts. New information technology may 
redefine the rules to some extent. Verification is easier, but on the other 
hand privacy may be more problematic since it is now easier to share all the 
information (partially intentionally to guarantee better verifiability). The 
tricky part is actually the privacy part. We may nowadays have e.g. interest to 
break the individual ballots in smaller and more numerous parts instead of 
trying to sum them up in smaller space.

Juho



On 24.7.2011, at 11.53, Kristofer Munsterhjelm wrote:

 Kathy Dopp wrote:
 The system you describe *is* still precinct summable in the sense of
 reporting the sums for each possible slate of candidates for each
 precinct or polling location - this is at least a whole lot fewer sums
 than the number of possible ballot choice permutations including
 partially filled out ballots that IRV/STV would require to be reported
 and sampled to be precinct summable (reporting all individual ballots'
 choices would be less to report in most cases).
 To be summable, this system would require reporting (N choose S) sums
 where N is the number of total candidates in the contest and S is the
 number of seats being elected.  This is a lot of sums - but could, I
 imagine, be mathematically sampled and audited to limit the risk of
 certifying the wrong slate much more easily than IRV methods could be
 - but I'm not certain about that until I have the time to think about
 it more (not any time soon).
 
 Ah, yes. This leads me back to an older thought that perhaps the criterion of 
 summability should be refined for multiwinner methods by turning it into two 
 criteria. These criteria would be:
 
 - Weak summability: If the number of seats is fixed, one can find the winner 
 of the method according to precinct sums, where the amount of data required 
 for these sums grows as a polynomial with respect to the number of 
 candidates, and as a polylogarithmic function with respect to the number of 
 voters.
 
 - Strong summability: Same as weak, but without the number of seats being 
 fixed or known in advance.
 
 To my knowledge, Schulze STV is weakly summable, as is this method, because 
 if you fix S, N choose S is bounded by a polynomial.
 
 When people here talk about summability for multiwinner methods, they usually 
 mean strong summability, though. This is like SNTV or party list. If you have 
 the Plurality counts for SNTV, it doesn't matter how many seats you want, you 
 can just read off the n first Plurality winners. Similarly, for party list, 
 you 

Re: [EM] PR for USA or UK

2011-07-24 Thread Jameson Quinn
2011/7/23 Andy Jennings electi...@jenningsstory.com

 On Sat, Jul 23, 2011 at 7:45 AM, Jameson Quinn jameson.qu...@gmail.comwrote:

 And so I'd like to suggest that we should be looking for a PR system which
 satisfies the following criteria:

 c1. Truly proportional (of course). I would be willing to support a
 not-truly-proportional system, but I'm not everyone. Egregious compromises
 on this issue will simply reduce the activist base, to no benefit.
 c2. Includes a geographical aspect. People are attached to the local
 representation feature of FPTP, whether that's rational or not.
 c3. No closed list. A party should not be able to completely shield any
 member from the voters. In general, voter power is preferable to party
 power, insofar as it's compatible with the next criterion.
 c4. Simple ballots. A reasonably-thorough voter should not have to mark
 more than, say, 5 candidates or options, and an average ballot should not
 list more than 20 candidates or options. Those are extreme limits; simpler
 is better, all the way down to around 7 options (of which only around half
 will be salient and/or viable).
 c5. Ideally, the smoothest transition possible. If existing single-winner
 districts can be used unchanged, all the better.
 c6. Insofar as it's compatible with the criteria above, greater freedom in
 voting is better. For instance, if ballots are printed with only in-district
 candidates, a system which allows out-of-district write-ins is better than
 one which doesn't, all other things being equal.


 I'm interested both in systems which satisfy 2 and those that don't.  If we
 could identify a good, truly proportional, at-large system, then a state
 with a bicameral legislature (like Arizona) could leave one house as
 geographical and change one to be at-large proportional.


I agree that if you were designing a democracy from scratch,
non-geographical systems deserve attention. My purpose here is to support a
system or systems that have some chance of passage in the US or UK. In my
experience, that means that activists should unify behind a system which
represents a minimal change. Whatever reform you propose will have
opposition, both from people who are honestly and naturally skeptical of
anything new, and from whichever major party currently benefits from the
distortions of the current system. It's better to push a smaller reform
which gives such people fewer arguments to use against you, than a
more-complete one which can never pass. That's why I included criteria 2 and
5, and I stand behind them.

This same argument applies to Kathy Dopp's suggestion that states like AZ
could have their bicameral legislatures function using one PR body and one
geographical body. It's a great idea, and I'd happily and enthusiastically
support it; but it's a more-radical reform, so I think something which meets
my criteria would be more attainable. At least, I'd like to settle on
something which meets my criteria, so that if I'm right, we still have a
chance.



 My proposal for SODA-PR satisfies and surpasses all 5 criteria. Other
 systems which do reasonably well:
 -I've seen a proposal for single-member districts and open party lists.
 This is similar to my SODA-PR system, except that it requires that all
 candidates in a party approve the same party set. As such, it is strictly
 worse on criterion 3, without being notably better on any of the other
 criteria. It is more conventional, though.
 -Multimember districts, with some system inside each district.
 -Mixed member systems.


 We should add Fair Majority Voting, by Balinski.  (
 http://mathaware.org/mam/08/EliminateGerrymandering.pdf)  Here's the
 summary:  Parties run one candidate in each district and voters vote for one
 candidate in the race in their district.  The votes are totaled nationwide
 by party and an apportionment method is used to decide how many seats each
 party deserves.  Each party is assigned a multiplier and the winner in
 each district is the one whose (vote total times party multiplier) is
 highest.  The multipliers can be chosen so that the final total seats won by
 each party matches the number of seats assigned by the apportionment
 method.


 It definitely satisfies your criteria 1,2,4, and 5.  I'd say it mostly
 satisfies 3.  Don't know how to evaluate 6.  The main thing I don't like
 about it is that it conflates voting for a candidate with voting for his
 party.  What if I like the candidate but not the party, or vice versa?  But
 since so many things in the legislature happen on a party basis, I've
 decided that this is not as bad as it first seems.

 FMV is equivalent to the single-member districts and open party lists
system I was talking about, although I remember seeing it under some
different name (some two-letter acronym with a U, I seem to recall). In
the end, FMV can be considered a limited special case of SODA-PR. Thus,
using the more-general terminology of SODA-PR to discuss them both, the
differences are:


Re: [EM] Weighted voting systems for proportional representation

2011-07-24 Thread Jameson Quinn
I agree with Juho's argument that all methods are summable these days.
However, I'd suggest a few vaguely-defined related criteria. The general one
is auditable - is it possible to gain confidence that the result is
correct through some process besides a full recount? This breaks down into
human-auditable (can you gain confidence through some simple arithmetic
process which doesn't require a computer? Such a process can involve
summary-statistics.); and sampling-auditable (can you gain an arbitrary
degree of confidence in the result by recounting a random sample of the
votes? Are the sample sizes required reasonable?).

STV does pretty poorly on these criteria. Since a tie at any stage can have
extreme effects on later stages; and electing A,B,C is likely to lead to
different results later on than electing C,B,A; the system is unstable.
The number of possible ties at all stages is order N³, the cube of the
number of candidates. And the voters divide into N camps at each stage.
Thus, in general, if there are fewer than about N⁴ voters, you can expect to
come arbitrarily close to a tie at some stage, which would mean that you
have to recount all the votes to be confident of the result.

Party list systems do the best on all these criteria, because they are
traditionally summable.

Things like Schulze-STV, AT-TV, and SODA-PR fall somewhere in the middle. If
summary statistics of votes are published, there are some easy sanity
checks which would catch the clumsier frauds in the counting process. And a
sampled recount would be enough to confirm the validity of these summary
statistics. Some forms of fraud would still take a full recount to detect;
but in general, such frauds would be logistically difficult.

I'm doing a lot of hand-waving in that last paragraph, though. The fact is,
to really be fully auditable in both senses, you need a system which is
summable in the traditional, low-order-polynomial-of-candidates, sense.

JQ

2011/7/24 Juho Laatu juho4...@yahoo.co.uk

 One approach to summability and auditing is to say that the target is to
 allow the district to count the votes and later check that at the top level
 their votes (or the votes of all districts) were counted correctly, AND to
 allow the top level to check that the districts will report their results
 correctly (they may e.g. want the districts to tell their final results
 before they hear what the results of the other districts were). In addition
 to these also the general public and independent auditors will benefit of
 having the results in a format that allows them to recount and check the
 results and that allows them to audit all the districts (and subdistricts,
 and top level) independently one by one. The key point is thus to provide
 transparency and easy and local checks in all directions.

 If this is what we want, then an interesting new feature is the new
 information society and its technical capabilities. That makes almost all
 methods summable in the above mentioned sense. Let's say we use STV. With
 current technology it is not a big problem to require all poll stations to
 record all their ballots in some digital format. And it is easy to check, if
 needed, that the physical ballots actually correspond to the reported
 results. It is also easy to check at the top level that the results are
 correct since the digital space taken by few million STV ballots is not that
 big, and the time that computers take to check the results is not that big.

 One may thus say that current digital storage, transport and computation
 capabilities can make almost any method summable in the discussed way.

 But there are still some problems left. One could say that the summability
 criterion also includes a requirement of being able to sum up the votes so
 that the summed up votes will hide details of the individual votes. This may
 be needed to provide privacy and to avoid unwanted phenomena like coercion
 and vote selling. In this sense the above mentioned treatment of the STV
 votes may not be sufficient. The number of candidates may be high enough and
 the length of the ballots high enough to allow identification of individual
 ballots. If we want to guarantee also privacy some additional tricks are
 needed in this case.

 My point was anyway that it isa also possible to divide this summability /
 auditing / privacy requirement in two parts so that it will consist of the
 1) easy verifiability and 2) privacy parts. New information technology may
 redefine the rules to some extent. Verification is easier, but on the other
 hand privacy may be more problematic since it is now easier to share all the
 information (partially intentionally to guarantee better verifiability). The
 tricky part is actually the privacy part. We may nowadays have e.g. interest
 to break the individual ballots in smaller and more numerous parts instead
 of trying to sum them up in smaller space.

 Juho



 On 24.7.2011, at 11.53, Kristofer Munsterhjelm wrote:

  Kathy 

Re: [EM] PR methods and Quotas

2011-07-24 Thread Jameson Quinn
2011/7/24 Andy Jennings electi...@jenningsstory.com

 Like Jameson and Toby, I have spent some time thinking about how to make a
 median-based PR system.

 The system I came up with is similar to Jameson's, but simpler, and uses
 the Hare quota!

 Say there are 100 voters and you're going to elect ten representatives.
  Each representative should represent 10 people, so why not choose the first
 one by choosing the candidate who makes 10 people the happiest?  (The one
 whose tenth highest grade is the highest.)  Then, take the 10 voters who
 helped elect this candidate and eliminate their ballots.  (There might be
 more than ten and you'd have to choose ten or use fractional voters.  I have
 ideas for that, but lets gloss over that issue for now.)  You can even tell
 those 10 voters who their representative is.


Glossing-over noted. I'd like to hear your ideas, but I agree that they
should not be part of the basic definition of the system.

Also, this hard elimination is where your method differs from AT-TV. Your
method certainly has a stronger free-riding incentive than AT-TV. It is
radically simpler, though, so perhaps AT-TV is adding too much complication
in an attempt to minimize the (fundamentally inevitable) free-rider
incentive.


 Electing the next seat should be the same way.  Choose someone who is the
 best representative for 10 people.  Repeat.

 The only problem is when you get down to the last representative.  If you
 follow this pattern, the last candidate is the one whose LOWEST grade among
 the remaining ballots is the highest, which is rather unorthodox.  You could
 change the rules and just use the median on the last seat, but using the
 highest minimum grade does have a certain attraction to it.  You're going to
 force those last ten voters to have some representative.  It makes some
 sense to choose the one who maximizes the happiness of the least happy
 voter.  (Though ties at a grade of 0 may be common.)


If you use the Droop quota instead of the Hare, ties at 0 will be less
likely. In general, I think that with the Hare quota, ties at 0 wouldn't
just be common, they'd be universal; and they'd still be common with the
Droop quota. In either case, the obvious solution (and the one which AT-TV
uses) is to elect the candidate with the fewest 0 votes.


 But this system doesn't reduce to median voting.


Right, it doesn't. But it does if you use the Droop quota.


   Which got me thinking...  Is there anything that special about the 50th
 percentile in the single-winner case anyways?  I can imagine lots of
 single-winner situations where it's more egalitarian to choose a lower
 percentile.  In a small and friendly group, even choosing the winner with
 the highest minimum grade is a good social choice method.  It's like giving
 each person veto power and still hoping you can find something everyone can
 live with.  This is the method we tend to use (informally) when I'm in a
 group choosing where to go to lunch together.


The Droop quota reduces to the median. The Hare quota reduces to the highest
minimum grade. You could also use any number in between. (I note that
modified Saint-Lague is, I think, actually used in some places, and
amounts to a similar compromise idea.)

The higher the quota (up to Hare), the smaller a group of strategic voters
can be and still determine the result (if everyone else is honest). I'd
argue that this makes pure Hare a poor solution. I am open to compromises.
2/(2N+1), the quota half way between Droop and Hare (I bet it already has a
name, but I don't know it), reduces to the ~33rd percentile in the
single-winner case. From what I've seen of supermajority requirements in
contentious high-stakes contexts (California tax hikes, US senate
filibusters), 2/3 is the highest reasonable supermajority requirement, and
may already be too high. But, as you say, a higher requirement may make
sense for smaller, friendlier decision-making.

In sum: I like your method. It is certainly similar to, but simpler than,
AT-TV. I prefer it with the Droop quota. What do you call it? (It would be
good if you had terms for both the Droop and Hare versions).

JQ

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Single Contest

2011-07-24 Thread Jameson Quinn
The ranked majority criterion is: if one candidate is top-ranked by a
majority of voters, that candidate must win.

To me, the natural extension of that to rated systems is: if only one
candidate is top-rated by any majority of voters, that candidate must win.

You are suggesting that we use the ranked majority criterion for rated
systems. If we do so, you are right that broad classes of rated systems
(including range, median, and chiastic) can never pass.

But if we use my definition of the criterion, then median systems pass,
trivially.

JQ

2011/7/24 Andy Jennings electi...@jenningsstory.com

 On Sat, Jul 23, 2011 at 11:28 AM, fsimm...@pcc.edu wrote:

 If one of the finalists is chosen by a method that satisfies the majority
 criterion, then you can skip step
 one, and the method becomes smoother.

 Here are some possibilities for the method that satisfies the majority
 criterion:  DSC, Bucklin, and the
 following range ballot based method:

 Elect the candidate X with the greatest value of p such that more than p/2
 percent of the ballots rate X at
 least p percent of the maxRange value.


 Forest,

 Can you clarify your definition of the majority criterion?  I don't think
 this method satisfies it.

 As a general example, suppose there are two candidates, A and B.  The
 voting range is 0-100 and there are 5 voters:
 1 voter: A=10 B=30
 1 voter: A=30 B=50
 1 voter: A=50 B=70
 1 voter: A=70 B=90
 1 voter: A=90 B=10

 B is strictly preferred to A by 4 out of 5 voters, but these two candidates
 have the exact same set of votes.  Any method which forgets which voter gave
 which vote must consider them exactly tied.  This includes score (range)
 voting, majority judgement, the chiastic median, and any of the other
 generalized medians.  Thus, with only some minor perturbation, A can defeat
 B in any of these methods.

 In the chiastic median (or the majority judgement), both candidates have
 societal grades of 50, but if you change A=50 to A=51 for the third voter,
 A's societal grade becomes 51 and A defeats B, despite strong majority
 opposition.

 In the p/2 system, 40% of the voters gave grades of 70 or above and 20% of
 the voters gave grades strictly above 70, so both candidates get a societal
 grade of 70.  But if you change A=70 to A=71 for the fourth voter, A's
 societal grade becomes 71 and A defeats B, again despite a strong majority
 opposition.

 I think any method which forgets which voter gave which vote will never
 satisfy the majority criterion.

 - Andy

 
 Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] PR-SODA? Try 2 (and 3)

2011-07-24 Thread Jameson Quinn
2011/7/24 Andy Jennings electi...@jenningsstory.com

 On Thu, Jul 21, 2011 at 9:45 AM, Jameson Quinn jameson.qu...@gmail.comwrote:

 So, here's the simpler procedure:

 While there are more uneliminated candidates than empty seats:

 Divide each ballot by the number of uneliminated candidates it approves
 If there are any candidates with more than a Droop quota:

 Elect the one with the highest score (previously unique ballots)
 Discard a Droop quota of randomly-chosen ballots which approve the elected
 candidate, starting with the ones delegated to that candidate
 Assign that candidates pre-declared approvals on any undiscarded delegated
 ballots for that candidate

 Otherwise:

 Eliminate the candidate with the lowest score
 Assign that candidates pre-declared approvals on any delegated ballots for
 that candidate

 Elect all remaining candidates to fill the seats.



 Okay, I really love how simple this is.  From the description, it sounds
 like it would be explainable and would work well.  I wonder how it does in
 simulations and if we can find any problematic scenarios.

 Questions:
 - Is there a bullet vote but don't delegate option like normal SODA?


Yes, but it's pretty useless. In general, your vote will be more likely to
be decisive in some context, the closer to half of the candidates you
approve. Voting for just one candidate is pretty unlikely to have any effect
on results.



 - Would it work just as well with the Hare quota?


Yes, but see my other message about your median-based system. For
contentious elections, I prefer the Droop quota. With the Hare quota, the
last candidate elected is likely to have about half the support of all the
rest. And in the single-winner case it amounts to a supermajority
requirement; and these don't have an illustrious history in my view.

(I suppose that you could have an explicit tiebreaker representative, with
only half a vote. But that amounts to same voting power as everyone else,
unless an odd number of people abstain, which is just silly.)


 - Without the delegation, is it the same as any other
 PR-with-approval-ballots method in existence?


I expect that non-delegated votes will be rarer than in plain SODA, for the
reasons I mentioned above relating to bullet votes. So it's not too
important. But without delegation, this method reduces to the same
approval-based method as two-rating-level AT-TV. This system is to me an
obvious case - it's the simplest form of sequential representative approval
voting - and so I would not be surprised to learn that someone has already
named it, but if so, I'm not aware of that. I guess I'd call it SRAV if it
needs a name, see previous sentence.



 Suggestions:
 - When a candidate is elected and you need to discard ballots, you could
 specify a more detailed preference order:
 1. Ballots which delegated to that candidate
 2. Ballots which bullet voted that candidate and didn't delegate
 3. Ballots which approved two candidates
 4. Ballots which approved three candidates
 5. Ballots which approved four candidates
 6. And so on.
 This eliminates ballots first which approve fewer candidates.  You may
 still have to select randomly within these tiers, but it gives an incentive
 for people to approve more candidates, which helps the method work better.
  Right?


Well, up to a point. The problem would be if people approved a no-hope
candidate, just to puff up the number of approvals on their ballot. This is
a form of Woodall free riding, and it could lead to DH3-type pathologies
in the worst case. I'd rather not go there.

JQ

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


[EM] SODA page updated with SODA-PR

2011-07-24 Thread Jameson Quinn
Just to alert those who may be interested, I've added SODA-PR to the SODA
page on 
electowikihttp://wiki.electorama.com/wiki/Simple_Optionally-Delegated_Approval#SODA-PR_.28proportional_representation_version_of_SODA.29
.

It includes some minor adjustments since the last time I expounded it here:

Simplifying the ballot by including same-district candidates in a larger
font, nearby-district candidates in a smaller font, and far-away candidates
as write-ins only, is now part of the system by default.
Random discards are repeated until the next candidate to be elected is the
same twice in a row. That is intended as a compromise between the
mathematical simplicity of ballot discarding and the deterministic nature of
fractional reweighting. In most cases, it will not affect the result.
Intercandidate can be conditional on being mutual, but not conditional on
anything else. That should allow a reasonable, but not excessive, level of
party discipline.

It also notes the circumstances when this will give the same results as
plurality, to argue that existing plurality winners will find this to be a
relatively-good PR system.

JQ

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] PR for USA or UK

2011-07-24 Thread Toby Pereira
I've replied to Jameson and Kevin in the same post here, so hopefully it's come 
out alright!



From: Jameson Quinn jameson.qu...@gmail.com
To: Toby Pereira tdp2...@yahoo.co.uk
Cc: EM election-methods@lists.electorama.com
Sent: Sun, 24 July, 2011 2:50:12
Subject: Re: [EM] PR for USA or UK

I agree that PRV would give better results, with sophisticated voters, than 
most 
forms of PR. However, it does fail my criterion 4 (simple ballots) and do 
worse 
than SODA-PR on criteria 5(smooth transition) and even arguably 1(true 
proportionality - because separate districts spoil the proportionality). If 
you 
don't think these criteria are reasonable, you should give that argument. 



I started out with a list of criteria because I think that's the right place 
to 
start when you're looking for a practical system.

JQ
 
I don't necessarily think sophisticated voters are required in order to ensure 
reasonable PR under PRV. I think as long as you don't get some candidates who 
have much better strategic voters than others, it should do OK.
 
I would argue that my system doesn't fail on simple ballots. It's not all or 
nothing. Yes, there are simpler ballots, but if I was rating simplicity of 
ballots approval style, I'd approve range ballots! But seriously, scores out of 
6 is quite simple, and it could be made quite clear that you only need to rate 
candidates that you have any positive feeling towards. Blanks would count as 
zero. Some may argue for an average score to be given to blanks, but I think 
that would actually encourage people to fill out a load of zeros anyway. 
SODA-PR 
is probably simpler, but I think the delegable/non-delegable thing would be a 
bit confusing for voters and so wouldn't be simple in their minds. I know that 
it's arguably better to have the one vote and let your favourite candidate 
delegate (given that they probably have similar views to you) than dilute with 
several approvals, but why not just let candidates have their own delegation 
list - i.e. STV - and do away with the approval aspect completely (since you 
don't approve of voters actually voting approval style under your system 
yourself)?
 
Smooth transition - yes, PRV a bigger step from FPTP in some ways than SODA-PR 
(giving candidates a score is further from a single X than approval-style 
votes), but the idea of giving your vote to the candidates to delegate is a 
pretty big paradigm shift in itself, and arguably causes it to fail on this 
criterion. Still, if we ever were to have PR in the UK, it would probably be 
STV 
anyway (don't know about in the US), which I would argue is no more or less 
smooth a transition than PRV from the starting point of FPTP. So for smooth 
transition, I don't think PRV fails, because I think it ties with the realistic 
(UK) frontrunner.
 
Separate constituencies do spoil proportionality to an extent, yes. There would 
only be a certain number of seats available in each. If it was six, then a 
party 
with constant 10% support across the county would struggle to get anything. 
What's the alternative? We could have bigger constituencies, but that means 
bigger ballots, or party lists, but I don't like them. I'm not sure I get your 
district/co-district thing though. In any case, I think this is a problem of 
how 
we sort out districts/constituencies, rather than anything against PRV per se.
 
Also, I don't get the whole thing about write-ins. Maybe it's a UK/US divide 
thing, but surely if you want to be elected then you stand for election. 
Therefore your name would be on the ballot.
 
 



From: Kevin Venzke step...@yahoo.fr
To: election-meth...@electorama.com
Sent: Sun, 24 July, 2011 5:38:18
Subject: Re: [EM] PR for USA or UK

Hi Toby,
 
Hello.

I really don't know what dishonest results means. Judging by your
example below it apparently requires comparing two different methods.
So, I can make any method give dishonest results just by inventing
a different method that requires dishonesty from everyone. Now every 
other method in the world is cheating.
 
I suppose what I mean is that by transferrig your vote for you, STV ends up 
producing the same result (in my simple case) as PRV with strategic voting, and 
to me it's an ugly result.

It's not a bad description that strategy-resistant systems do the
strategy for you. This has important results:

1. The voters do not need to do the strategy
2. So the playing field is leveled
3. So votes should have correct effect in proportion to the number,
meaning the outcome is more accurate. That is, it reflects better the
overall preferences of the electorate.
 
Strategy-resistant systems do have certain advantages as you say, but in the 
single-winner case it would end up reducing range to a Condorcet method, which 
arguably isn't as good, and ends up pushing out a better-liked candidate for 
one that strictly more people prefer. And this is what I like about range - 
it's 
not 

Re: [EM] Automated Approval methods (was Single Contest)

2011-07-24 Thread Kevin Venzke
Hi Kristofer,

--- En date de : Dim 24.7.11, Kristofer Munsterhjelm km_el...@lavabit.com a 
écrit :
  I also tried implementing the most obvious (I suppose)
 method: Take the
  ratings and conduct simulated approval polling, either
 for some
  determined or semi-random number of iterations, or
 until someone wins
  twice in a row. This doesn't test as well as I thought
 it would though.
 
 What Approval strategy do you use?

I always use better than expectation when it is allowed to assume the
voters know the method is approval. (Which is just to say that the main
sim, when during pure Approval, can't use better than expectation.)

I put a tiny amount of average utility of all candidates into the
expectation just to try to avoid the situation where your favorite won
all the polls so therefore you don't approve him.

Kevin Venzke


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] PR for USA or UK

2011-07-24 Thread Juho Laatu
On 23.7.2011, at 17.45, Jameson Quinn wrote:

 We had a discussion about the best practical single-winner proposal, which, 
 while it certainly wasn't as conclusive as I'd hoped, seemed productive to 
 me. I think we should have a similar discussion about PR.
 
 Obviously, the situations in the UK and in the USA are very different in this 
 regard. The UK is, as far as I know, the origin of the PR movement (in the 
 1860s and 1870s, liberals gained seats disproportionately as the franchise 
 was extended, and Conservatives looked for a fairer system to recoup their 
 losses). And it's part of Europe, where people have experience with PR. But 
 both the UK and the US currently elect their principal representative bodies 
 by district-based FPTP/plurality.
 
 And so I'd like to suggest that we should be looking for a PR system which 
 satisfies the following criteria:
 
 1. Truly proportional (of course). I would be willing to support a 
 not-truly-proportional system, but I'm not everyone. Egregious compromises on 
 this issue will simply reduce the activist base, to no benefit.

What is a not-truly-proportional system? That could range from being close to 
proportional (= only few seats difference to full PR) to being close to what 
the system is today in the USA (= gives one or two seats to third parties).

 2. Includes a geographical aspect. People are attached to the local 
 representation feature of FPTP, whether that's rational or not.

That may well make sense also in a PR system. Proportional geographical 
representation is a different and separate target, not necessarily a relic.

 3. No closed list. A party should not be able to completely shield any 
 member from the voters. In general, voter power is preferable to party power, 
 insofar as it's compatible with the next criterion.
 4. Simple ballots. A reasonably-thorough voter should not have to mark more 
 than, say, 5 candidates or options, and an average ballot should not list 
 more than 20 candidates or options. Those are extreme limits; simpler is 
 better, all the way down to around 7 options (of which only around half will 
 be salient and/or viable).

I hope you don't assume that all the candidates must be listed on the ballot. 
One could have also ballots where the voters write the number(s) of their 
favourite candidate. That approach allows high number of candidates.

Let's say that there are 100 seats. In a fully proportional system a party 
with more than 1% support would be entitled to one seat. If you want the voters 
to decide who wins instead of letting the party decide you need several 
candidates to choose from. Let's say that this party has 5 candidates. If other 
parties have similar rights to nominate candidates you could end up having e.g. 
100*5 candidates. That is not an exact formula and I ignored the impact of 
districts, but the point is that if you want to support small parties and 
ability to select from multiple candidates the total number of candidates and 
the total number of candidates per district may grow large. Does number 20 
above limit the number of candidates per district?

 5. Ideally, the smoothest transition possible. If existing single-winner 
 districts can be used unchanged, all the better.

Having both pure single-winner districts (not e.g. MMP) and full PR is possible 
but then you have to accept considerable inaccuracy in electing the most liked 
candidate in each district. I guess what you are looking for is a good balance 
between these incompatible (but positive) requirements. Maybe this is one 
reason why you would accept also less than perfect PR.

 6. Insofar as it's compatible with the criteria above, greater freedom in 
 voting is better. For instance, if ballots are printed with only in-district 
 candidates, a system which allows out-of-district write-ins is better than 
 one which doesn't, all other things being equal.

Is the old American tradition of allowing write-in candidates included in your 
list of requirements?

 
 My proposal for SODA-PR satisfies and surpasses all 5 criteria. Other systems 
 which do reasonably well:
 -I've seen a proposal for single-member districts and open party lists. This 
 is similar to my SODA-PR system, except that it requires that all candidates 
 in a party approve the same party set. As such, it is strictly worse on 
 criterion 3, without being notably better on any of the other criteria. It is 
 more conventional, though.
 -Multimember districts, with some system inside each district.
 -Mixed member systems.

One possible approach (with accurate PR) is to first allocate the seats to 
parties at national level and then allocate those seats to (probably 
multimember) districts (in a geographically proportional way).

One approach that allows high number of candidates and simple ballots is to 
allow voters to rank candidates of one single party in one single region only. 
One may also limit the maximum number of ranked candidates heavily since 

Re: [EM] PR for USA or UK

2011-07-24 Thread Kevin Venzke
Hi Toby,

--- En date de : Dim 24.7.11, Toby Pereira tdp2...@yahoo.co.uk a écrit :
Strategy-resistant systems do have certain advantages as you say, 
but in the single-winner case it would end up reducing range to a 
Condorcet method, which arguably isn't as good, and ends up pushing 
out a better-liked candidate for one that strictly more people 
prefer. And this is what I like about range - it's not just about 
which candidates you prefer to which other ones, but by how much. 

I think the Range method itself is pretty incapable of this, but you
could do it either with rated ballots or with a rank ballot that has
truncation incentive.

And as long as strategy isn't performed better by voters of some candidates 
than others, the fact that there would still be some 
honest voters would mean that the advantages of range would still 
remain to an extent, meaning that overall better-liked candidates 
stand a better chance, and it therefore reflects better the overall
preferences of the electorate!

That paragraph makes sense if you're comparing Range to Approval, but 
not Range to anything else. If large numbers of voters use strategy in
Range (and I'm pretty sure they would be encouraged to; personally I
wouldn't need any encouraging) this will destroy so much information 
that the only way Range will win out is if the rank methods you compare
it to contain even more destructive incentives than Range has.

[begin quote]
On my website I give an example where party A has 68% of the support 
and party B 32%. There are two seats and so each party fields two 

 Of course party A voters could 
coordinate themselves and split into two factions of 34% to take both 
seats, but this would be very hard for them to achieve. STV (Droop 
quota anyway) would transfer the votes above the quota accordingly 
so that party A would win both seats, and give what I would regard 
as the less fair result.

Ok, but it's not obvious that it is less fair. You are according a
privilege to the weaker party just because it is a different party.

I'm not according them a privilege because they are a different party, but 
because I would see it as logical and fair that 75% is a reasonable cut-off. If 
a system made the cut-off at 80%, I'd argue that it was unfair in favour of the 
smaller party.

[end quote]

Can you explain your position without saying party? Because if you 
didn't see the parties, and only saw voters, it would be indefensible 
to give a seat to the 32%. There would be nothing special about that 
group.

Kevin Venzke


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] PR for USA or UK

2011-07-24 Thread Jameson Quinn
2011/7/24 Juho Laatu juho4...@yahoo.co.uk

 On 23.7.2011, at 17.45, Jameson Quinn wrote:

  We had a discussion about the best practical single-winner proposal,
 which, while it certainly wasn't as conclusive as I'd hoped, seemed
 productive to me. I think we should have a similar discussion about PR.
 
  Obviously, the situations in the UK and in the USA are very different in
 this regard. The UK is, as far as I know, the origin of the PR movement (in
 the 1860s and 1870s, liberals gained seats disproportionately as the
 franchise was extended, and Conservatives looked for a fairer system to
 recoup their losses). And it's part of Europe, where people have experience
 with PR. But both the UK and the US currently elect their principal
 representative bodies by district-based FPTP/plurality.
 
  And so I'd like to suggest that we should be looking for a PR system
 which satisfies the following criteria:
 
  1. Truly proportional (of course). I would be willing to support a
 not-truly-proportional system, but I'm not everyone. Egregious compromises
 on this issue will simply reduce the activist base, to no benefit.

 What is a not-truly-proportional system? That could range from being close
 to proportional (= only few seats difference to full PR) to being close to
 what the system is today in the USA (= gives one or two seats to third
 parties).


I was thinking of things like limited vote as somewhat-proportional systems.
These would be an improvement, but the activist base for these half-measure
reforms is I think always smaller than that of true PR.



  2. Includes a geographical aspect. People are attached to the local
 representation feature of FPTP, whether that's rational or not.

 That may well make sense also in a PR system. Proportional geographical
 representation is a different and separate target, not necessarily a relic.


Note that SODA-PR is not perfect here. It would tend to elect about one
candidate per district, but there would be a possibility that some districts
would get 2 and some would get 0.



  3. No closed list. A party should not be able to completely shield any
 member from the voters. In general, voter power is preferable to party
 power, insofar as it's compatible with the next criterion.
  4. Simple ballots. A reasonably-thorough voter should not have to mark
 more than, say, 5 candidates or options, and an average ballot should not
 list more than 20 candidates or options. Those are extreme limits; simpler
 is better, all the way down to around 7 options (of which only around half
 will be salient and/or viable).

 I hope you don't assume that all the candidates must be listed on the
 ballot. One could have also ballots where the voters write the number(s) of
 their favourite candidate. That approach allows high number of candidates.

 Let's say that there are 100 seats. In a fully proportional system a
 party with more than 1% support would be entitled to one seat. If you want
 the voters to decide who wins instead of letting the party decide you need
 several candidates to choose from. Let's say that this party has 5
 candidates. If other parties have similar rights to nominate candidates you
 could end up having e.g. 100*5 candidates. That is not an exact formula and
 I ignored the impact of districts, but the point is that if you want to
 support small parties and ability to select from multiple candidates the
 total number of candidates and the total number of candidates per district
 may grow large. Does number 20 above limit the number of candidates per
 district?


I understand that large numbers like this are possible; that's the reason
for this criterion. A system (like SODA-PR) which allows legal, useful votes
for the full candidate set, but which only explicitly lists some
 (district-based) subset on any given ballot, would pass this criterion in
my view.



  5. Ideally, the smoothest transition possible. If existing single-winner
 districts can be used unchanged, all the better.

 Having both pure single-winner districts (not e.g. MMP) and full PR is
 possible but then you have to accept considerable inaccuracy in electing the
 most liked candidate in each district. I guess what you are looking for is a
 good balance between these incompatible (but positive) requirements. Maybe
 this is one reason why you would accept also less than perfect PR.


I said I'd personally accept it, but it's not what I'm looking for in this
thread. But yes, it's a balancing act here.


   6. Insofar as it's compatible with the criteria above, greater freedom
 in voting is better. For instance, if ballots are printed with only
 in-district candidates, a system which allows out-of-district write-ins is
 better than one which doesn't, all other things being equal.

 Is the old American tradition of allowing write-in candidates included in
 your list of requirements?


No. In this case the write-in capability is a way to list fewer candidates
than the full allowed set, as a way to 

Re: [EM] PR for USA or UK

2011-07-24 Thread Toby Pereira






From: Kevin Venzke step...@yahoo.fr
To: election-meth...@electorama.com
Sent: Sun, 24 July, 2011 20:34:33
Subject: Re: [EM] PR for USA or UK


Hello again.

--- En date de : Dim 24.7.11, Toby Pereira tdp2...@yahoo.co.uk a écrit :
Strategy-resistant systems do have certain advantages as you say, 
but in the single-winner case it would end up reducing range to a 
Condorcet method, which arguably isn't as good, and ends up pushing 
out a better-liked candidate for one that strictly more people 
prefer. And this is what I like about range - it's not just about 
which candidates you prefer to which other ones, but by how much. 

I think the Range method itself is pretty incapable of this, but you
could do it either with rated ballots or with a rank ballot that has
truncation incentive.

Is a range ballot not a rated ballot?


And as long as strategy isn't performed better by voters of some candidates 
than others, the fact that there would still be some 

honest voters would mean that the advantages of range would still 
remain to an extent, meaning that overall better-liked candidates 
stand a better chance, and it therefore reflects better the overall
preferences of the electorate!

That paragraph makes sense if you're comparing Range to Approval, but 
not Range to anything else. If large numbers of voters use strategy in
Range (and I'm pretty sure they would be encouraged to; personally I
wouldn't need any encouraging) this will destroy so much information 
that the only way Range will win out is if the rank methods you compare
it to contain even more destructive incentives than Range has.

With a single-winner election, the full strategy option is to vote approval 
style, but I'm not sure if this is as clear for PR. You say you wouldn't need 
any encouraging to vote strategically - I wouldn't either to be honest - but 
what is the optimal strategy? In any case, if range does turn out to be 
problematic, proportional approval voting would be my next choice. I don't like 
ranked ballots because you don't know how much the voter actually likes each 
candidate or whether they like them at all.

Can you explain your position without saying party? Because if you 
didn't see the parties, and only saw voters, it would be indefensible 
to give a seat to the 32%. There would be nothing special about that 
group.

Candidates A and B are both fairly similar and 68% of voters vote for both of 
these approval-style and no-one else. Candidates C and D are also similar to 
each other and 32% of voters vote for both of these approval style and no-one 
else. That's the example set out without parties. And it's the same as before - 
if 50% of the voters voted for A and B it would be exactly the right 
proportion (without rounding due to a specific number of seats) for one of A or 
B to be elected, and if 100% voted for them, it would eb exactly the right 
proportion for both seats. 75% is halfway.
Hi Toby,
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] PR for USA or UK

2011-07-24 Thread Toby Pereira






From: Jameson Quinn jameson.qu...@gmail.com
To: Toby Pereira tdp2...@yahoo.co.uk
Cc: EM election-methods@lists.electorama.com
Sent: Sun, 24 July, 2011 19:45:06
Subject: Re: [EM] PR for USA or UK



I don't necessarily think sophisticated voters are required in order to ensure 
reasonable PR under PRV. I think as long as you don't get some candidates who 
have much better strategic voters than others, it should do OK.

You should read some of Schulze's papers about the history of free riding. It 
seems clear from those examples that there are examples of parties with better 
or worse free-riding vote-management capabilities. So I would worry about 
this 
distorting results.

OK, I might look into it. But you could probably legislate against blatant 
suggestions to vote in a specific way from certain parties. It would still exit 
unofficially with discussions online and elsewhere but anyone would have 
access to the information. I'm sure Warren's got an answer too. ;)
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


[EM] Another approach to geographical proportionality and single-winner districts (was: PR for USA or UK)

2011-07-24 Thread Juho Laatu
One feature of single-winner district based political systems is that voters 
will have a clearly named own representative that is as local as possible. In 
a PR context with multiple parties one could redefine this idea so that people 
should have a known representative that represents them in the assembly. A 
two-party / single-winner district system has the problem that often the local 
representative is from the wrong party. The requirement could be modified so 
that the idea is to have a local representative of one's *own* party. With that 
approach we will lose some of the locality, but on the other hand we may get 
more natural local representatives.

This kind of methods could work for example so that first the number of seats 
that each party gets will be determined at national level (to provide perfect 
proportionality between parties). The country is divided in small voting areas. 
We know the number of votes from each voting area to each party and the 
location of each voting area. (Votes are summed up in voting areas instead of 
using individual votes directly in order to guarantee voter privacy.) Also 
candidates have a location. That location could be approximate and it could be 
used only to indicate that the intention of the candidate is to represent 
certain region. Voters will then vote for the candidates. The system could 
allow only bullet votes or one could user ranked or rated ballots too.

Then we need an algorithm that takes the votes to some party and their 
geographical distribution, and the geographical distribution of the votes to 
different candidates of the party into account. The whole country will be 
divided in (party specific) regions, and one candidate (of this party) will be 
elected in each region. Now all supporters of this party will have a single 
own representative of their own party. The size of the regions should reflect 
the density (or sparseness) of votes from that region. The size of each 
district would be about the same in terms of votes received from that region. 
One could allow also disjoint regions, but if one wants the regions not to be 
too fragmented, one could add some parameter that favours compact regions. One 
should form such a set of regions and set of representatives in them that the 
overall happiness of the voters (of this party) is maximized (= local 
representatives having local support etc.).

One could develop also systems with no party structure (with ranked or rated 
ballots). In such systems each geographical spot could have exactly one 
representative. Or alternatively one could agree some (small) number of 
representatives that each spot should have (= layers). That would allow every 
voter to have a local representative from their own wing at least. Also in 
this approach different layers could have different regions, and the size of 
the regions could reflect the popularity distribution of that candidate. 
(Actually the layers need not be separate layers. It is enough if each 
representative has a region, and each geographical spot is included in the 
agreed number of regions.

The end result so far is thus a mixture of strict political and geographical 
proportionality requirements, leading to electing a fixed number of 
representatives for each geographic spot. But of course one could still give up 
the idea of keeping the number of representatives per spot constant :-). One 
could instead optimize the number of representatives per spot so that it 
reflects the uniformity of opinion in each location. If some place has only 
small number of different opinions it could have only a small number of very 
local representatives, while another place (with similar population density) 
could have numerous but less local representatives. I guess we will keep the 
requirement of all representatives having in their regions about equal number 
of supporters to represent.

One problem of systems without clear district structure and geographic 
proportionality is that candidates from the capital region and other major 
cities and television tend to become overrepresented. The discussed system 
above had no clear fixed district borders (although it could have) and it may 
allow voters to vote also distant candidates, but it may still maintain 
regional representation quite well (also without limiting the area where each 
candidate can collect votes) since individual candidates are more likely to be 
elected if they get their votes from a region size geographical area.

I wrote this mail as a response to the PR for USA or UK mail stream, and 
particularly to the question how to offer good political proportionality, 
geographic proportionality and local representation at the same time. This 
model is however not a very concrete and practical proposal for the needs of 
that mail stream. If one looks for a practical implementations of this 
approach, maybe the party based approach with one party representative for each 
spot is closest to being a 

Re: [EM] Single Contest

2011-07-24 Thread Andy Jennings
Jameson Quinn wrote:

 The ranked majority criterion is: if one candidate is top-ranked by a
 majority of voters, that candidate must win.

 To me, the natural extension of that to rated systems is: if only one
 candidate is top-rated by any majority of voters, that candidate must win.


That must be the definition Forest is using.  Thanks.  Any strategic
median which assigns the MaxGrade if at least 50% of the electorate rated
the candidate at MaxGrade will indeed pass this criterion.



 You are suggesting that we use the ranked majority criterion for rated
 systems. If we do so, you are right that broad classes of rated systems
 (including range, median, and chiastic) can never pass.

 But if we use my definition of the criterion, then median systems pass,
 trivially.


You are probably aware the median systems pass a stronger criterion:  If for
some grade X, only one candidate is rated at X or above by any majority of
voters, then that candidate must win.

In other words, it doesn't just have to be top-rated, it can be any grade.

- Andy

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] PR for USA or UK

2011-07-24 Thread Kevin Venzke
Hi Toby,

--- En date de : Dim 24.7.11, Toby Pereira tdp2...@yahoo.co.uk a écrit :
[begin quote]
Strategy-resistant systems do have certain advantages as you say, 
but in the single-winner case it would end up reducing range to a 
Condorcet method, which arguably isn't as good, and ends up pushing 
out a better-liked candidate for one that strictly more people 
prefer. And this is what I like about range - it's not just about 
which candidates you prefer to which other ones, but by how much. 

I think the Range method itself is pretty incapable of this, but you
could do it either with rated ballots or with a rank ballot that has
truncation incentive.
 
Is a range ballot not a rated ballot?
[end quote]

Sorry, I mean, I don't believe it is hopeless to try doing what you
want with a rated ballot. Range does use a rated ballot. Off the top
of my head I don't have any really great method suggestions here,
because it seems to me to be extremely difficult to design a method so
that it maximizes utility. If the method is strategy-proof, it will
tend to elect the sincere Condorcet winner. If it's not strategy-proof,
you can't fully trust the information you collect. Something in-between
seems to be needed, but I would bet nobody will feel very happy with 
whatever is invented.

[begin quote]
And as long as strategy isn't performed better by voters of some candidates 
than others, the fact that there would still be some 
honest voters would mean that the advantages of range would still 
remain to an extent, meaning that overall better-liked candidates 
stand a better chance, and it therefore reflects better the overall
preferences of the electorate!

That paragraph makes sense if you're comparing Range to Approval, but 
not Range to anything else. If large numbers of voters use strategy in
Range (and I'm pretty sure they would be encouraged to; personally I
wouldn't need any encouraging) this will destroy so much information 
that the only way Range will win out is if the rank methods you compare
it to contain even more destructive incentives than Range has.
 
With a single-winner election, the full strategy option is to vote approval 
style, but I'm not sure if this is as clear for PR.

[end quote]

No, I have no comment on any PR versions. I wouldn't assume any 
similarity.

You say you wouldn't need any encouraging to vote strategically -
I wouldn't either to be honest - but what is the optimal strategy?

I have heard and tend to agree with approve everyone better than what
you expect on average the outcome to be. If there are two frontrunners
with perceived-to-be equal odds of winning, that would mean approving
every candidate better than the average of the two.

Experimentally there usually are two frontrunners that emerge from
pre-election polling.

In my own simulations, the ideal strategy is determined by the voters
within the specific situation they find themselves in. So it's not
easy to describe what strategy they are choosing, but it must be 
something close.

In any case, if range does turn out to be problematic, proportional
approval voting would be my next choice. I don't like ranked ballots
because you don't know how much the voter actually likes each 
candidate or whether they like them at all.

Generally I have liked rank methods where voters are not thought to be
supposed to rank candidates they don't really like. This may start to
turn it into Approval, but with some ranking information retained.

Can you explain your position without saying party? Because if you 
didn't see the parties, and only saw voters, it would be indefensible 
to give a seat to the 32%. There would be nothing special about that 
group.

Candidates A and B are both fairly similar and 68% of voters vote 
for both of these approval-style and no-one else. Candidates C and 
D are also similar to each other and 32% of voters vote for both 
of these approval style and no-one else. That's the example set out 
without parties.

Ok. It sounds like you want to represent more types of voters. The
68% cannot have both seats because they're the same type. If they were
different types then it would be OK.

Kevin Venzke


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] PR for USA or UK

2011-07-24 Thread Andy Jennings
Jameson Quinn wrote:

 2011/7/23 Andy Jennings electi...@jenningsstory.com

 On Sat, Jul 23, 2011 at 7:45 AM, Jameson Quinn 
 jameson.qu...@gmail.comwrote:

 And so I'd like to suggest that we should be looking for a PR system
 which satisfies the following criteria:

 c1. Truly proportional (of course). I would be willing to support a
 not-truly-proportional system, but I'm not everyone. Egregious compromises
 on this issue will simply reduce the activist base, to no benefit.
 c2. Includes a geographical aspect. People are attached to the local
 representation feature of FPTP, whether that's rational or not.
 c3. No closed list. A party should not be able to completely shield any
 member from the voters. In general, voter power is preferable to party
 power, insofar as it's compatible with the next criterion.
 c4. Simple ballots. A reasonably-thorough voter should not have to mark
 more than, say, 5 candidates or options, and an average ballot should not
 list more than 20 candidates or options. Those are extreme limits; simpler
 is better, all the way down to around 7 options (of which only around half
 will be salient and/or viable).
 c5. Ideally, the smoothest transition possible. If existing single-winner
 districts can be used unchanged, all the better.
 c6. Insofar as it's compatible with the criteria above, greater freedom
 in voting is better. For instance, if ballots are printed with only
 in-district candidates, a system which allows out-of-district write-ins is
 better than one which doesn't, all other things being equal.


 I'm interested both in systems which satisfy 2 and those that don't.  If
 we could identify a good, truly proportional, at-large system, then a state
 with a bicameral legislature (like Arizona) could leave one house as
 geographical and change one to be at-large proportional.


 I agree that if you were designing a democracy from scratch,
 non-geographical systems deserve attention. My purpose here is to support a
 system or systems that have some chance of passage in the US or UK. In my
 experience, that means that activists should unify behind a system which
 represents a minimal change. Whatever reform you propose will have
 opposition, both from people who are honestly and naturally skeptical of
 anything new, and from whichever major party currently benefits from the
 distortions of the current system. It's better to push a smaller reform
 which gives such people fewer arguments to use against you, than a
 more-complete one which can never pass. That's why I included criteria 2 and
 5, and I stand behind them.

 This same argument applies to Kathy Dopp's suggestion that states like AZ
 could have their bicameral legislatures function using one PR body and one
 geographical body. It's a great idea, and I'd happily and enthusiastically
 support it; but it's a more-radical reform, so I think something which meets
 my criteria would be more attainable. At least, I'd like to settle on
 something which meets my criteria, so that if I'm right, we still have a
 chance.


Agree on both counts, but I live in AZ so the bicameral option doesn't seem
so radical.  :)





 My proposal for SODA-PR satisfies and surpasses all 5 criteria. Other
 systems which do reasonably well:
 -I've seen a proposal for single-member districts and open party lists.
 This is similar to my SODA-PR system, except that it requires that all
 candidates in a party approve the same party set. As such, it is strictly
 worse on criterion 3, without being notably better on any of the other
 criteria. It is more conventional, though.
 -Multimember districts, with some system inside each district.
 -Mixed member systems.


 We should add Fair Majority Voting, by Balinski.  (
 http://mathaware.org/mam/08/EliminateGerrymandering.pdf)  Here's the
 summary:  Parties run one candidate in each district and voters vote for one
 candidate in the race in their district.  The votes are totaled nationwide
 by party and an apportionment method is used to decide how many seats each
 party deserves.  Each party is assigned a multiplier and the winner in
 each district is the one whose (vote total times party multiplier) is
 highest.  The multipliers can be chosen so that the final total seats won by
 each party matches the number of seats assigned by the apportionment
 method.


 It definitely satisfies your criteria 1,2,4, and 5.  I'd say it mostly
 satisfies 3.  Don't know how to evaluate 6.  The main thing I don't like
 about it is that it conflates voting for a candidate with voting for his
 party.  What if I like the candidate but not the party, or vice versa?  But
 since so many things in the legislature happen on a party basis, I've
 decided that this is not as bad as it first seems.

 FMV is equivalent to the single-member districts and open party lists
 system I was talking about, although I remember seeing it under some
 different name (some two-letter acronym with a U, I seem to recall). In
 the end, FMV can be 

Re: [EM] Automated Approval methods (was Single Contest)

2011-07-24 Thread fsimmons

This kind of approach has been experimented with for a long time by Rob 
LeGrand, and there doesn't 
seem to be any good way to make it monotone.

Here's a very conservative and simple approach that may have some value in some 
context, if not this 
one:

For each rating ballot b approve the top N candidates where N is the (rounded) 
sum of the ballot b 
ratings of all of the candidates divided by the maxRange value  

Let S be the sum over candidates X of the ballot ratings b(X) .

Then N is S divided by maxRange, rounded to the nearest whole number (or 
rounded to even when 
exactly halfway between floor and ceiling of S/maxRange).

The N highest rated candidates on ballot b are approved.

If these approvals are used to elect an approval winner, the method is montone 
and as clone free as 
possible for automated approval.  (It can split clone sets at the approval 
boundary on a ballot).

Here is a possible heuristic for the method:

If the ballot b ratings are normalized (by dividing by maxRange) and taken to 
represent probabilities, so 
that b(X) is the probability that candiadte X would correctly represent the 
ballot b voter on a random 
question, then the sum S is the expected number of candidates that would agree 
with this voter on a 
random question.

So why not approve the top S voters, since they are the most likely to be the 
ones that would agree with 
the voter?

Note that this is a zero information strategy, and for all I know, it could 
well be zero-info-optimal by some 
criterion or other.  The usual zero info strategy is to assume that all of the 
candidates are equally likely 
to win, and to approve above expectation on that basis, but the insertion of 
lots of clones can radically 
change those probabilities.

This kind of reminds me of the rule that Kristofer suggested for how many 
winners there should be in a 
PR election when that number hasn't been decided ahead of time.

 Date: Sun, 24 Jul 2011 20:01:48 +0100 (BST)
 From: Kevin Venzke 
 Hi Kristofer,
 
 --- En date de?: Dim 24.7.11, Kristofer Munsterhjelm 
 a ?crit?:
   I also tried implementing the most obvious (I suppose)
  method: Take the
   ratings and conduct simulated approval polling, either
  for some
   determined or semi-random number of iterations, or
  until someone wins
   twice in a row. This doesn't test as well as I thought
  it would though.
  
  What Approval strategy do you use?
 
 I always use better than expectation when it is allowed to 
 assume the
 voters know the method is approval. (Which is just to say that 
 the main
 sim, when during pure Approval, can't use better than expectation.)
 
 I put a tiny amount of average utility of all candidates into the
 expectation just to try to avoid the situation where your 
 favorite won
 all the polls so therefore you don't approve him.
 
 Kevin Venzke

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [COVoterChoice] RB gives an equal chance of winning to not just all parties, but all combinations of programs,

2011-07-24 Thread Dave Ketchum

I assume this is from Colorado, and have no idea who else has seen it.

I see it as worth considering the thinking, although I AM NOT signing  
on as backing any of it.


On Jul 23, 2011, at 11:32 PM, Dave Ketchum wrote:

Knowing of IRV and Condorcet methods of counting ballots, the first  
paragraph below makes me wonder how valid the the author's claims  
may be.  The very last few lines help.

. STV - not used here - THANKS
. Condorcet - also not used here - think more whether this is  
better.


On Jul 23, 2011, at 3:59 PM, preferentiality wrote:


Ranked Ballot (voters ranking candidates in order of preference) will
give us (PRACTICABLE!) Instant TRUE Democracy for ALL the World, 
even put an end to all war forever.

Because it gives an equal chance of winning to not just all parties,
but all combinations of programs, “RB” is the only thing that’s truly
both just  free.  Because it always elects the candidate most  
exactly

in the middle of all voting, RB is top-dead-center counter extremist,
 thus more anti-terrorist than all the many recent retrenchments
combined  thus will even disallow the tendency of (virtually two-
party) parliamentary systems to give the top to the biggest gang on
the block, sometimes with violently extremist results.


Worth reading more - I am not buying the author's claims of  
achieving perfection.  There are many topics for which more than two  
possible choices seem worth debating possible value.


Dave Ketchum


RB is the sole unchangeable plank  bylaw of a Ranked Ballot Party,
the only practicable third party.)  We imagine running on the single
issue of RB, promising a citizens’ advisory board based on Organized
Communications, “OC”, small randomly assigned discussion groups
electing reps to higher  higher randomly assigned levels, by means  
of

RB, ‘til one small group, most exactly in the middle of all voting,
remains at the top, to guide us in the rest, which group by its  
merest

invitation to speak  inevitably names the perfect compromise  next
winner  That’s the instant part.  You do the same, from the most  
local

on up.
By the power of its example alone, RB will give us practicable  
instant

worldwide true democracy.  Virtually no democracy has ever been
attacked by another.  In a world of only democracies, there would no
longer be need of the counter-productive wastefulness of armies, war
or the preparation for war.  RB will bring us that  all else: a real
solution to terror, a perfect marriage of Freedom  Justice,  
Tradition

 Modernity, Palestinian  Jew, Free Market  Communalism, all the
fairness, payback  make-up one could wish for, clean back to the  
Cro-

Magnons, ecologically sustainable politics, what’s best for all
workers, instant global women’s liberation, world-wide luxury, a
rationalization of the drug wars, human unity, the Freedom of Justice
 the Justice of Freedom, perhaps the only possible solution to the
world’s only real problem, the Israeli/Palestinian conflict (once  
they
both are made to have to adopt RB), even integrity. RB is to the  
horse

 buggy two-party system as shopping in the Mall of America is to
shopping in Soviet Russia.  The majority of the problems we face are
due to the heavy-footedness of the two party system.  RB lessens the
power of the extremes, whether authoritarian, economic or sectarian,
except through what they can gain by persuasion, which is only what’s
just.  While it would be equally useful for all else, RB’s real power
is perhaps most clearly shown in the case of Iraq.  Unless its
Parliament comes to select the Prime Minister by means of RB, it may
not hold  the country, region  world will be in danger of going to
war over some ancient grudge, oil well, multi-ethnic city, or
sabotaged pipeline.  While the new constitution does call for the
selection of the President by a 2/3 vote in the first round (even if
only by the parliament  not the people) (who may then decide who  
will

form the new government)  then by a run-off between the top two vote
getters in the second round, if that fails to move all three tribes  
to

nominate centrists, then the resulting handful of old men in a back
room will fall far short of RB’s ultimate retail politics.  RB would
be equally useful for all electoral systems (parliamentary or
presidential, the parliaments choosing their PMs by RB from among
their members, lest they produce another Hitler or other extreme)
coops, collective leaderships, tribal groupings, religious
confessions, political parties, associations or, even cabals.   
Whoever

gets there first wins.  For leaders to best represent their country,
or district, whether chosen at large or by a representative body,  
they

must be the perfect compromise, most exactly in the middle, as is
given by RB.  Yet because it gives minorities a real say in which
member of the plurality/majority gets chosen, RB is the only thing
that will lead Iraqis, or anyone else, to support any plan more than
inadequate 

Re: [EM] Weighted voting systems for proportional representation

2011-07-24 Thread Kathy Dopp
On Sun, Jul 24, 2011 at 4:53 AM, Kristofer Munsterhjelm
km_el...@lavabit.com wrote:


 Ah, yes. This leads me back to an older thought that perhaps the criterion
 of summability should be refined for multiwinner methods by turning it into
 two criteria. These criteria would be:

 - Weak summability: If the number of seats is fixed, one can find the winner
 of the method according to precinct sums, where the amount of data required
 for these sums grows as a polynomial with respect to the number of
 candidates, and as a polylogarithmic function with respect to the number of
 voters.

 - Strong summability: Same as weak, but without the number of seats being
 fixed or known in advance.

 To my knowledge, Schulze STV is weakly summable, as is this method, because
 if you fix S, N choose S is bounded by a polynomial.

 When people here talk about summability for multiwinner methods, they
 usually mean strong summability, though. This is like SNTV or party list. If
 you have the Plurality counts for SNTV, it doesn't matter how many seats you
 want, you can just read off the n first Plurality winners. Similarly, for
 party list, you can just run the Sainte-Laguë method n times for n seats
 with the same input data.

 Do you think weak summability is sufficient to audit multiwinner methods?



Your definitions do not differentiate between the enormous difference
between the difficulty of summing STV vs. the far more summable voting
method you were proposing!  That is an enormous difference -
regardless of whether the number of seats is known in advance or not.
I was only considering contests where the # of seats are known in my
remarks.  Thus, I do not think that your definitions are sufficient
for evaluating methods.


-- 

Kathy Dopp
http://electionmathematics.org
Town of Colonie, NY 12304
One of the best ways to keep any conversation civil is to support the
discussion with true facts.

Fundamentals of Verifiable Elections
http://kathydopp.com/wordpress/?p=174

View some of my research on my SSRN Author page:
http://ssrn.com/author=1451051

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [COVoterChoice] RB gives an equal chance of winning to not just all parties, but all combinations of programs,

2011-07-24 Thread Kevin Venzke
Hi,

--- En date de : Dim 24.7.11, Dave Ketchum da...@clarityconnect.com a écrit :
 De: Dave Ketchum da...@clarityconnect.com
 Objet: Re: [EM] [COVoterChoice] RB gives an equal chance of winning to not 
 just all parties, but all combinations of programs,
 À: electionscience Foundation electionscie...@googlegroups.com
 Cc: preferentiality preferential...@gmail.com, EM 
 election-methods@lists.electorama.com
 Date: Dimanche 24 juillet 2011, 19h42
 I assume this is from Colorado, and
 have no idea who else has seen it.
 
 I see it as worth considering the thinking, although I AM
 NOT signing on as backing any of it.

I have trouble finding any description in the post. I wonder if RB is 
intended to mean Random Ballot (RB) as the message subject would
almost make sense in that case.

Kevin Venzke


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Automated Approval methods (was Single Contest)

2011-07-24 Thread Kevin Venzke
Hi Forest,

--- En date de : Dim 24.7.11, fsimm...@pcc.edu fsimm...@pcc.edu a écrit :
 This kind of approach has been experimented with for a long
 time by Rob LeGrand, and there doesn't 
 seem to be any good way to make it monotone.

Yes, but if it were strategy-free somehow, I think it would be worth it.
Real life isn't monotone. I don't imagine that all the prettier Yee
diagrams would really look like that if voters were using information
and strategy!

No time to say more...

Kevin Venzke


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] PR for USA or UK

2011-07-24 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jul 24, 2011, at 5:01 PM, Toby Pereira wrote:




From: Kevin Venzke step...@yahoo.fr

...

I think the Range method itself is pretty incapable of this, but you
could do it either with rated ballots or with a rank ballot that has
truncation incentive.

Is a range ballot not a rated ballot?


well, i don't know precisely what is meant by a rated ballot, but  
Range or Score Voting is not the same as the *ranked* ballot nor  
really a subset of it.  i guess any score ballot can default to a  
ranked ballot, where the candidate ranks are listed in the same order  
as the candidate scores.  but Range or Score requires more information  
than the ranked ballot.


and i don't think voters would be entirely consistent between the two  
types of ballots.  it might be that a voter thinks that both  
Candidates B and C are scum (compared to A) and would score B and C at  
0 with A at 10 whereas, since the ranked ballot, if the voter thinks  
that B, while scum, is preferable to C and they might rank B higher  
than C, which doesn't hurt A at all.  whereas with score, bumping B up  
from 0 to 1 (or anything non-zero) to express the voters preference of  
B to C will numerically hurt this voters preference of A to B.


i have to admit, i don't like Score voting (i still don't see any of  
the single-winner alternatives beating Condorcet, for the most part).   
i think, while requiring more precise information from the voter than  
with the ranked ballot (how much more do you prefer A over C than do  
you prefer A over B?), i think it can lead a voter to act, to vote in  
a less expressive way than with the ranked ballot.  and i think that  
if voters (especially those that hate IRV and the ranked ballot) will  
use their Score ballot like a traditional ballot, except for the  
scaling.  that voter will give the single candidate of their choice a  
10 and all other candidates a 0.  that becomes like a First-Past-The- 
Post election.


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info