[PEN-L:4765] new mercantalism

1995-04-19 Thread jones/bhandari

Reproduced below is  an absoutely  brilliant analysis of "the ratio of
dynamic to stagnant sectors" in an individual nation.  The analysis comes
from Tilla Siegel who I believe is now a Prof (or perhaps Chair) of
Sociology at the Goethe University at Frankfurt. I am hoping it will
provoke discussion.  

In its own fetishistic terms, bourgeois economics  is now groping towards
an analysis of this ratio.  This ratio is perhaps the basis of today's
mercantalism, as was once the fetish of gold.

 A chair of many influential "global competitiveness" committees, Harvard
Business Prof Michael Porter has basically equated that concept with this
ratio--as can be seen from any of his very tedious contributions to the
Harvard Business Review.  In other words, he pays careful attention to the
actual sectorial composition of economies, not the aggregates of
Keynesianism.  This sort of attention is sometimes seen as legacy of
Schumpeterian economics, as emphasized by noted American business historian
Thomas McGraw. As always, the economists  must now catch up with the
business profs if they want to have any relation to reality!

The labor secretary Robert Reich himself is groping at this idea in his
chapter on the movement from "high volume to high value" in his Work of
Nations.  He is explicitly concerned, from a natl. pt. of view, with the
expulsion of certain sectors and the monopolization of others. 

On the other hand, Siegel is able to analyze  the reproduction of total
capital, not (as with narrow bourgeois minds) just the "growth" an
individual nation based on its specific ratio of dynamic to stagnant
sectors.  To me this illuminates the whole/part relationship in Marx better
than can any purely philosophical treatment. 


"The existence of dynamic and stagnant sectors in capitalism does not
contradict the tendency toward an equalization of profit rates.  this is
not just because the term 'tendency'already implies continually changing
inequalities between profit rates.  dyanic sectors do not grow faster just
because their profit rates, and so rates of accumulation, are above
average, but also because these profit rates attract capitals from other
sectors.  So long as the additional influx of capital does change the
relations between supply and demand in such a way that the profit rates
fall below average, they will remain dyanmic sectors.  And stagnant sectors
do not grow more slowly or shrink just because their rates of profit are
below average, but also because capitals leave these sectors for others
with higher profit rates. In general, the existence of dynamic and stagnant
sectors in capitalism is an expression of the capital movements that create
the tendency toward an average rate of profit.

"With respect to the position of the individual nation in the world market
the ratio of dynamic to stagnant sectors in its economy is very important. 
Even if we assume that all nations have the same wage level and that all
nations produce at the highest levels of productivity, a ntion that has
specialized in dynamic sectors will have a higher growth rate than one that
has specialized in stagnant sectors. Through the imperialistic expansion of
capital the international distribution of these sectors has created a
partition of the capitalist world market into nations with primarily
dynamic sectors (in the center) and nations with primarily stagnant sectors
(in the periphery).

"But how did this specialization come about?  It would be wrong to take the
effect for the cause and to argue that it came about because it was
favorable for the dominant capitalist nations.  One cannot say that the
process toward this form of specializtion was consciously created in the
sense that the nations of the center transferred staganatn sectors into the
periphery by way of state action or by concerned capitalist action.  This
process was set in motion mainly by the fact that *acquired* advantages in
productivity, i.e., advantages resulting from technological progress, have
played an increasingly important role in international trade.  meanwhile,
the nations of the center have been and are monopolizing the development of
technology while their capital have destroyed and are destryoing the
possibility of this development in the periphery.  

"On the one hand, the increase of productivity in a sphere of production
creates the possibility of extra profits.  On the other hand, this increase
makes possible the capture of markets in other nations where the level of
productivity is lower, and somakes possible an increase in demand and thus
the reaping of extra profits over a longer span of time.  This sphere of
production becomes a dynamic one (because of a higher rate of accumulation
and the influx of new capitals) and acquires more weight in the nation
concerned wthan other spheres where the relation between falling cost
prices and expanding demand is not as favorable.

"What was left for the nations of ther periphery were those sectors 

[PEN-L:4764] RE: New work on discrimination in credit/housing

1995-04-19 Thread DYMSKI

Thanks, Patrick, for that provocative reflection on banking and race.

I've been thinking a lot about the connections you were musing over, so
let me spice the brew before everyone has coffee on Wednesday.  BTW, thanks
to those who responded privately, and I repeat my interest in hearing
from anyone doing new stuff on race/discrimination/banking/housing.

Patrick makes several diverse points.  I'll crunch through some, and
undoubtedly leave others uncrunched.  Blame the late hour.  First, the
point that much radical policy analysis is reactive, not active.  In the
case of housing/banking, reactive means looking for discrimination per se,
hoping to score Fed points; but leaving other connections untouched, or
too little touched.  

I don't agree that the studies have shown discrimination per se; I don't
think any have, except for the "paired-testing" types (minority and white
person with identical characteristics try to get a loan, get a job, ...).
The studies most often replicated have shown that areas with many minority
residents -- usually African American population percentage, for most 
studies -- have lower loan flows per eligible housing unit.  This "area"
race effect is different than showing "individual" race effects aimed
at specific minority applicants.  

The area race effects show, in Anne Shlay's term, the lack of a "fair
share" of credit in those areas -- no more and no less than that.  These
are the studies that have indeed proliferated around the country.  The
very volume of these studies is, in a way, impressive -- because lots of
activist groups could replicate something done somewhere else, and borrow
ideas on how to interpret it.  But here's where things have tilted in a
way that Patrick doesn't like.  Conservative critics responded, "How
do you know it's not lack of demand for housing loans in minority areas?"

In response, HMDA data on individual applicants were produced thanks to
a compromise worked out by the Southern Finance Project and others during
the FIRREA negotations.  This richer data allowed richer tests on whether
in fact there were still fewer loans to minorities once you took applica-
tions into account.  The answer was, yes; but the conservative rejoinder
was again, "How do you know it isn't bad credit history ...? (etc.)?"

In efect, there's always an excluded variable problem to contend with.
Even the infamous revised Boston study didn't quell the pens of the
conservative scribes at the WSJ.  The revised Beantown tried to put
everything and the kitchen sink into the structural equation; but still
there was a flaw -- "What about default rates?"  It would take us too
far afield to follow this strange debate further here.

The point is that a good part of the empirics has definitely involved 
a dialogue with "conservative" economists; and this has been fought out
on terrain these foes understand ... and the empirics have (surprise)
proven to be inconclusive.

I would vote for continuing that dialogue/duel, but also as Patrick 
suggests, for mounting new campaigns on new fronts.  Here, I'll just
throw out a few things, since I've gone on too long.

Area race effects can be the legacy of structural discrimination, not
just of racist bankers.  And structural discrimination can be an amalgam
of labor-market inequity, class dynamics, unequal wealth, etc.  I have a
paper coming out later this year in the Rev. of Black Pol. Economy, which
shows how labor-market and credit-market discrimination can interact very
perversely.  I think that the class and race dynamics are interpenetrating;
so I see efforts that are class-based as being complementary with "race"
based efforts.

I agree completely with the need to look at spatial dimensions.  More and
more I think this is a key.  The racial, of course, is spatial.  This is
just where we need to add in, say, Robert Bullard and Melvin Oliver, to
spice William J. Wilson.  The racial is also gendered, as is the class-
based.  The post-moderns here would say, no problem, find a specific
instance and pull it apart.  I've don precisely this with my own co-work
-- with John Veitch -- on LA.  The class/gender/racial separations that
are going on, the polarizing processes, interweave, and leave us more
and more with very different kinds of space. I don't think I agree with
Lash and Urry that it's "ungovernable" -- but it's definitely polarized,
and I think polarized in ways richer than can be got at with just one
dimension alone.

I also like the idea of combining ideas about financial fragility and
speculation with ideas about localized credit rationing.  Here too there's
a lot to be said -- but another time ?

And as to literature.  The old radical stuff from the 1970's has a lot to
say today.  Some is a bit functionalist for my taste; but still lots of
insights that should be thrown back into circulation.  I'd also note 
that I've been learning a lot from the geographers and sociologists.  There's
some interesting work on "financial 

[PEN-L:4766] Re: Worker (fwd)

1995-04-19 Thread Carl H.A. Dassbach

Regarding Carl Dassbach's definition:
 What is a telecommunications operator in a big room filled
with dividers and other telecommunications operators working the
night shift for a big catalog company?
 A physical product was part of the definition.  What is the  
physical product?
 -- Mary Schweitzer

Answer - a worker.  I never said anything about a physical product which, in
my mind,  suggests a distinction between productive and non-productive
labor.  All labor is productive (for owners) insofar as it generates more
value then is returned to the laborer, i.e. needed to reproduce that labor
power.  It is immaterial what form this labor takes - e.g. assembly line
work or service labor.  The problem is that most labor processes today are
socialized - as a result, surplus value is really the global outcome of the
collective and socialized labor process and the contribution of individual
workers can not be preciserly specified.  So-called unproductive
activtities, sales, supervision are in fact integral to the process of
producing surplus value as a collective socialized activity.  Let's not
reproduce Senior "Last Hour." 
-
Carl H.A. Dassbach   E-mail:   [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Dept. of Social SciencesPhone:   (906)487-2115
Michigan Technological University  Fax:   (906)487-2468
Houghton,  MI   49931USA



[PEN-L:4767] Re: Boyer Reference

1995-04-19 Thread Carlos Salas, Facultad de Economia, UNAM

Dear Michael:
For the second time in the last three months, I've stopped receiving 
messages from PEN-L. I don't know what is happening.
Could you please help?
Thank you
Cheers
Carlos Salas



[PEN-L:4768] RE: New work on discrimination in

1995-04-19 Thread Marshall Feldman

Gary,

Thanks for the posting.  Can you give us the specific references?  I've
tried to highlight the ones needed.

I don't agree that the studies have shown discrimination per se; I don't
think any have, except for the "paired-testing" types (minority and white
person with identical characteristics try to get a loan, get a job, ...).

Can you cite a recent published study via which we can bore into the lit?

The studies most often replicated have shown that areas with many minority
residents -- usually African American population percentage, for most
studies -- have lower loan flows per eligible housing unit.  This "area"
race effect is different than showing "individual" race effects aimed
at specific minority applicants.

Again, please give at least on cite as a port of entry.


The area race effects show, in Anne Shlay's term, the lack of a "fair
^^
 ref?

very volume of these studies is, in a way, impressive -- because lots of
  ^^

Is there a review or academic summary?

In response, HMDA data on individual applicants were produced thanks to
a compromise worked out by the Southern Finance Project and others during
the FIRREA negotations.  This richer data allowed richer tests on whether
in fact there were still fewer loans to minorities once you took applica-
tions into account.  The answer was, yes; but the conservative rejoinder

Have these studies been published anywhere?

conservative scribes at the WSJ.  The revised Beantown tried to put
   
   ref?

Area race effects can be the legacy of structural discrimination, not
just of racist bankers.  And structural discrimination can be an amalgam
of labor-market inequity, class dynamics, unequal wealth, etc.  I have a
paper coming out later this year in the Rev. of Black Pol. Economy, which
 ^^
  do you know which issue?
I agree completely with the need to look at spatial dimensions.  More and
more I think this is a key.  The racial, of course, is spatial.  This is
just where we need to add in, say, Robert Bullard and Melvin Oliver, to
spice William J. Wilson.  The racial is also gendered, as is the class-

Again, people might want refs. to Bullard, Oliver, and Wilson.

-- with John Veitch -- on LA.  The class/gender/racial separations that

published where?

Lash and Urry that it's "ungovernable" -- but it's definitely polarized,
 ^
  cite?

And as to literature.  The old radical stuff from the 1970's has a lot to
^
 anything in particular?

that I've been learning a lot from the geographers and sociologists.  There's

which ones?  Where?

a second look.  For those interested in such trends, a new "Los Angeles"
school is arising -- with Ed Soja, Mike Davis, Allen Scott, Jennifer
Wolch, Michael Dear at the center -- in response to the older "Chicago
model".  Hey, we're just jealous about MJ coming back.  Why not Magic?

Some cites here would help too.  BTW, the "Los Angeles" school is not so
new (these folks have been plugging along since at least the mid-1970's)
and not so LA (see the intro to Mike Storper and Dick Walker's
_Capitalist Imperative_).  As far as I'm concerned, Manuel Castells nailed
the Chicago model from France in 1972 (_The Urban Question_).

Thanks again.  I'm familiar with some of the lit. here, but it would be
nice to know exactly what you're referring to and to fill in the gaps in
my knowledge.

Marsh Feldman   Phone: 401/792-5953
Community Planning, 204 Rodman Hall   FAX: 401/792-4395
The University of Rhode Island   Internet: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Kingston, RI 02881-0815

"Marginality confers legitimacy on one's contrariness."



[PEN-L:4769] RE: New work on discrimination in credit/housing

1995-04-19 Thread SCHWEITZ

More comments on the problem:
 To the extent there IS racism behind the imbalance in loans, it is
not due to explicit policies on the part of the banks, but rather to
the lingering internalized racism of the guys in the trenches, the
loan officers who actually sit down and talk with prospective borrowers.
It's there, but it's hard to pin down in hard numbers.
 Second, bankers have devised a number of rules of thumb for
distinguishing between a good credit risk and a bad credit risk. 
these rules of thumb have served them well to the extent that they
identify good credit risks.  But it leaves plenty of room open for
people who are ALSO good credit risks to fall into the automatic
category of a bad credit risk.  A simple example is the longstanding
rule against lending to a woman heading up a household with children.
Made sense.  They've had to get used to that, because it can be
obvious discrimination.  But still, a woman heading up a household
with children is not going to fit well the standard profile of a
good credit risk.   
 There are householders who don't make a lot of money, and have
a lot of bills, but would turn out to be steady and able to make
their mortgage payments.  But the bankers do not have any good
methods for telling WHICH ONES THEY ARE.  In other words, what has
to happen is that NEW rules of thumb have to be created that are
(as the saying goes) idiot-proof -- any idiot could follow the
instructions and figure out whether or not this person was a good
credit risk.  You have to find a way of distinguishing AMOLNG women
who head households, to pick out who is going to be reliable and
who is not.  
 This is where minority-owned/operated and female-owned/operated
institutions come in.  They are more likely (not always, just MORE)
to be able to come up with new rules of thumb that would work WITHIN
certain groups that don't fit the older profiles.  
 The advantage to redefining the rules in the end is great:  more
and more households of all races and ethnic backgrounds are what is
called "nontraditional".  So figuring out who the good credit risks
are WITHIN "nontradtional" groupings is a worthwhile innovation.
 But.  It is a risky innovation.  So there has to be public support
for those willing to take those risks.  
 A flat-out rule such as the community reinvestment act does not
necessarily do anyone any good -- in some cases, it may discourage
location within the community, in other cases institutions may work harder
to find traditional recipients among the nontraditional majority.  What
-- sorry -- IT may be easy to enforce a flat-out rule, but what do we
learn from it?  
 What is needed is some way to reward innovation in this direction.
A learning process that then can be shared.  
 As for the spatial aspects:  as long as new peripheral development
is rewarded with windfall gains in value and redevelopment is
penalized; as long as slumloards can hold on to deteriorating property
for decades waiting for the ground beneath to appreciate; the
cheap housing will be in the old railroad-hub interior of the city,
and that is where the poor will be, and that is where the jobs are not.
 -- Mary Schweitzer



[PEN-L:4771] Re: min wage

1995-04-19 Thread GSKILLMAN

Heather writes:

 Dear pen-llers, 
   Could any of you min wage experts please suggest to me the *best* most recent
 article on the social and economic effects of a minimum wage?
 Thanks in advance!Heather  

Best with respect to what concerns?  Possible candidates are:

1)Card and Krueger's new book from Princeton University Press;

2) Mishel and Bernstein's discussion in THE STATE OF WORKING AMERICA 
1994-1995;

3) The excellent but somewhat old survey by Charles Brown, Curtis 
Gilroy, and Andrew Kohen, published in the June 1982 JOURNAL OF 
ECONOMIC LITERATURE.

Of the three I guess I'd pick Card and Krueger's book, but you wanted 
an article, so perhaps start with the conclusion section of the 
Brown/Gilroy/Kohen survey.

The problem here is that no one source is both recent, utterly 
comprehensive in theoretical and empirical analyses, and relative 
short (i.e. an article). 

Gil Skillman








[PEN-L:4772] Re: min wage

1995-04-19 Thread Doug Henwood

At 11:39 AM 4/19/95, HEATHER GROB wrote:

Dear pen-llers,
  Could any of you min wage experts please suggest to me the *best* most recent
article on the social and economic effects of a minimum wage?
Thanks in advance!Heather

If the Card  Krueger book is too much for you, check out two recent
publications from your neighbors at the Economic Policy Institute -
"Raising the Floor," a longish paper published a few months (?) ago, and
"Who Benefits from a Higher Minimum Wage?," a nice short briefing paper.

Doug

--

Doug Henwood
[[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
Left Business Observer
250 W 85 St
New York NY 10024-3217
USA
+1-212-874-4020 voice
+1-212-874-3137 fax




[PEN-L:4773] WSJ: Revised NAFTA job prediction,Apr.17 (fwd)

1995-04-19 Thread D Shniad

 Date: Tue, 18 Apr 1995 14:53:23 -0700 (PDT)
 From: Dale Wiehoff [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 To: Recipients of conference [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Subject: Revised NAFTA job prediction
 
 From: dwiehoff (Dale Wiehoff)
 
 From: The Wall Street Journal, April 17, 1995
 By:   Bob David
 Title: The Outlook: Free Trade Is Headed For More Hot Debate:
 
 "The Mexican meltdown demolished the Bush and Clinton administrations'
 formula to sell Nafta: free-trade pacts=exports=jobs. With the peso
 devaluation, the U.S. trade surplus with Mexico will disappear and with the
 claim that Nafta will generate jobs, says Gary Hufbauer, a trade economist
 whose predicition that Nafta would create 130,000 additional jobs in five
 years was parroted by the White House.
 'The best figure for the jobs effect of Nafta is approximately zero,' he
 says now. 'The lesson for me is to stay away from job forecasting.'"
 
 For more on what Hufbauer and the Economic Policy Institute (EPI) should
 stay away from, please see the review of his book, NAFTA: AN ASSESSMENT, by
 Kai Mander, available at the IATP gopher
 site:gopher.igc.apc.org:70/11/trade/iatp in the Trade Library conference,
 topic #139.
 
 
 Some excerpts:
 
 "In spite of their own research findings to the contrary, Hufbauer and
 Schott nevertheless hold up the ideological argument of  free trade as
 proof of long-term benefits.  They claim, "Investment by US firms in
 Mexico is a 'good event' rather than a  'bad event' for the United
 States"  because "foreign investment by US firms creates US  jobs,
 both in the short run, by boosting US exports of capital goods, and in
 the long run, by establishing channels for the export of US
 intermediate components, replacement parts, and associated goods
 and services" (19).
 
 The authors hope to quell concern about US companies moving to
 Mexico, but again their argument is inconsistent.  "The fact that some
 US plants close, just as some Mexican plants close, should be read as
 evidence that the market system is working, not that it is failing.
 From the standpoint of the US economy as a whole, what counts is
 how many net jobs are created by NAFTA" (14).  Ten pages later, in
 arguing the US will benefit from greater competition and a larger
 continent-wide market created by NAFTA,  they claim that increased
 efficiency and higher output will earn approximately $15 billion a
 year between Mexico and the US.  "Over the long-term, this figure --
 not jobs won or lost -- is the true measure of the economic gain from
 the NAFTA agreement," the authors contend (24).
 
 ...Hufbauer and Schott's specific plans are not realistic.  Each seems to
 be based on an amazingly profound faith in the governments and
 corporations of the US, Canada and Mexico to act in an ethical fashion.
 They recommend that the US-Mexico Binational Commission not have
 the "power to levy fines or award money damages against particular
 firms or industries," but instead should act as "a roving spotlight."  If
 businesses do not conduct themselves properly of their own accord,
 the  authors contend, "The glare of publicity should be sufficient to
 promote compliance" in most cases. (30)  While a great glare of
 publicity does have its influence, a commission report would be an
 unlikely source to stir up such a public outcry."
 
 
 Dale Wiehoff
 Communications Director
 Institute for Agriculture and Trade Policy (IATP)
 1313 5th St.,SE, Suite 303
 Minneapolis, MN 55414-1546 USA
 Tel: (612) 379-5980 Fax: (612) 379-5982
 Email: [EMAIL PROTECTED]