Re: Estimating the surplus\Doug's question\Fred's comments

2003-12-14 Thread Fred B. Moseley
Paul, thanks for your comments.  My responses below.


On Fri, 12 Dec 2003, Paul wrote:

 Fred,
 Very glad you could make it - you were missed!  I want to think more about
 your post but have one small and one larger reflection.

 1.  I think we can all agree on the big focus of profit rates, as Paul
 put it - that the rate of profit is the most important variable in
 analyzing capitalism.  And I agree with Paul that this emphasis on profit
 and the rate of profit is what distinguishes classical-Marxian theories
 from neo-classical theories.

 In addition to Doug's main point ('show me the benefit of all this'), Doug
 does make me wonder whether my description of the Classical/Marxian
 approach should have been more specific (although the change might prove
 more narrow-minded). As you know well, historically, the Classical
 tradition focused on profits/profit rate but broke this down into the
 changes that emerge from the labor\capital shares AND the changes that
 emerge from what I was calling the 'capital side' (with lots of differences
 and inconsistencies among Classical authors).  Of course, since Sraffa
 there has been an intelligent and articulate revival of interest in
 Classical presentations of the first issue (wage/profit frontiers, etc)
 WITHOUT the capital side.  The discussion with Doug illustrates a point:
 without the 'capital side' just how useful is such a presentation?  Doug
 gave good examples of how similar arguments could be made sticking to a
 Keyensian\Kaleckian tradition that is more accessible to most.  (Of course
 Doug is also skeptical of the value of this approach even with the capital
 side, but that is a different discussion.)

I agree that the capital side (i.e. the composition of capital) is an
important determinant of the rate of profit.  (I prefer to discuss this in
terms of Marx's concept of the composition of capital, rather than the
mainstream concept of the productivity of capital which I think is
misleading.)  The increase in the composition of capital in the early
postwar period was an important cause of the decline of the rate of profit
in that period, and the decrease in the composition of capital in recent
decades has been the main cause of the partial recovery of the rate of
profit.  So clearly, theory and analysis of the rate of profit should
include the composition of capital.

I also agree that this is an important distinguishing feature of Marx's
theory, in contrast to Ricardo's theory and Sraffa's theory and all other
economic theories, which if they consider the rate of profit at all,
generally consider only the share of profit and ignore the composition of
capital.


 ...
 6.  I have suggested another explanation of these important trends, one
 based on Marx's distinction between productive labor and unproductive
 labor - that an important cause of the declines in the share and the rate
 of profit was a very significant increase in the ratio of unproductive
 labor to productive labor.  I am not sure that this is the correct
 explanation of these trends, but I think it may be, and I think that it
 worthwhile to at least consider what Marx's theory implies about the
 causes of these trends and the likely prospects for the future.
 
 And one important advantage that this theory has over the profit squeeze
 explanation is that it provides a consistent explanation of why the share
 and rate of profit have only partially recovered in recent decades, in
 spite of the loss of workers' power and stagnant real wages - because the
 ratio of unproductive to productive labor has continued to increase.
 
 This theory also provides an important prediction about the future - that
 if the ratio of unproductive to productive labor continues to increase (as
 I expect), then the recovery of the share and rate of profit will continue
 to be slow and partial, thus leading to more wage cuts, speed-up,
 etc.  According to this theory, the US economy is definitely NOT at the
 beginning of another long-wave period of growth and prosperity, similar
 to the early postwar period (with steady real wage increases).  The only
 partial recovery of the share and rate of profit makes such a return to
 more prosperous conditions very unlikely.

 You have made me think about what is the nature of a long wave
 upturn.  Here are some quick thoughts and concerns.

 1.  a. Of course these are waves, not cycles (as in Kondratieff,
 investment-accelerator, etc).  It is not even as if a simple mechanism such
 as the falling of the price of capital in a downturn will, in
 itself,  produce an upturn.

  b. The up and the down of these waves are not symmetrical. While
 there are forces common and inherent in the accumulation process to
 downturns (tendencies to a rising OCC, etc), the upturns require
 exceptional events that are not inherently produced by the downturn
 process.  Mostly these require some combination of major technological
 change AND socio-political 

Re: Estimating the surplus\Doug's question

2003-12-14 Thread Fred B. Moseley
Hi Jim, thanks for your good questions.  A few responses below.


On Fri, 12 Dec 2003, Devine, James wrote:

 Hi, Fred.

 you write:
  6.  I have suggested another explanation of these important
  trends, one
  based on Marx's distinction between productive labor and unproductive
  labor - that an important cause of the declines in the share
  and the rate
  of profit was a very significant increase in the ratio of unproductive
  labor to productive labor.  I am not sure that this is the correct
  explanation of these trends, but I think it may be, and I
  think that it
  worthwhile to at least consider what Marx's theory implies about the
  causes of these trends and the likely prospects for the future.
 
  And one important advantage that this theory has over the
  profit squeeze
  explanation is that it provides a consistent explanation of
  why the share
  and rate of profit have only partially recovered in recent decades, in
  spite of the loss of workers' power and stagnant real wages -
  because the
  ratio of unproductive to productive labor has continued to increase.

 A big question: _why_ does the ratio of unproductive to productive
 labor increase over time? if this ratio is squeezing profits, it seems
 that profit-seeking capitalists would make an effort to lower it. or is
 there some sort of technological or social imperative that pushes
 capitalists to increase the ratio anyway? or is it a matter of it being
 good for capitalists as individuals to raise the ratio even though it's
 bad for capital as a whole?

This is indeed a big and important question, and I think the answer is a
combination of the types of things that you have suggested.  I discuss
this question at some length in Chapter 5 of my 1992 book (The Falling
Rate of Profit in the Postwar US Economy).  It is complicated because the
category of unproductive labor is a mixed bag of different kinds of labor
(circulation labor and supervisory labor and subgroups of each), and the
increase of each of these different kinds of unproductive labor may be due
to different causes.

The main conclusion that I came to in this chapter is that the main cause
of the increase of circulation labor (roughly two-thirds of the total) is
that during this period the productivity of productive labor increased
faster than the productivity of sales labor, thereby requiring a relative
increase of the latter in order to sell the more rapidly increasing output
of the former.  The classic example is the auto industry.  The quantity of
autos produced per productive worker increases much more rapidly than the
quantity of autos sold by salesperson (which remains a largely
labor-intensive, person-to-person activity).

An interesting corollary of this explanation is that the computer
revolution has been one way to increase the productivity of unproductive
labor, and therefore slow down the increase in the number of unproductive
workers.  Indeed, much of the computer revolution has been aimed at
reducing unproductive labor (sales, accounting, debt-credit,
etc.).  Therefore, Marx's theory suggests that the rapid development of
computer technology in recent decades has been due in part to the
systematic imperative to reduce unproductive labor in order to restore the
rate of profit.


 alternatively, it could be that the geographical unit of analysis is
 wrong. What if the US-based operations of capital are specializing in
 what Marxists term unproductive labor, while exporting the
 productive jobs to other countries? In that case, we should be
 calculating the world-wide rate of profit, no?


Yes, I think the increasing geographical specialization of recent decades
(productive labor in the rest of the world, unproductive labor in the
US) is part of the explanation of the relative increase of unproductive
labor in the US.


  This theory also provides an important prediction about the
  future - that
  if the ratio of unproductive to productive labor continues to
  increase (as
  I expect), then the recovery of the share and rate of profit
  will continue
  to be slow and partial, thus leading to more wage cuts, speed-up,
  etc.  According to this theory, the US economy is definitely
  NOT at the
  beginning of another long-wave period of growth and
  prosperity, similar
  to the early postwar period (with steady real wage
  increases).  The only
  partial recovery of the share and rate of profit makes such a
  return to
  more prosperous conditions very unlikely.

 why can't the ratio of unproductive to productive spending change
 quickly in the future? didn't something like that happen in the 1990s,
 lowering the ratio?

 One indicator of what happened can be seen in Michael Reich's 1998
 article Are U.S. Corporations Top-Heavy? Managerial Ratios in Advanced
 Capitalist Countries (in the REVIEW OF RADICAL POLITICAL ECONOMICS,
 vol. 30, no. 3, 33-45). Reich's data on p. 37 show a rise in the
 management ratio until 1982 or so -- fitting with David Gordon's fat
 and 

Re: Estimating the surplus\Doug's question

2003-12-14 Thread Fred B. Moseley
On Fri, 12 Dec 2003, paul phillips wrote:

 Devine, James wrote:

 Hi, Fred.
 
 you write:
 
 
 spite of the loss of workers' power and stagnant real wages -
 because the
 ratio of unproductive to productive labor has continued to increase.
 
 
 
 A big question: _why_ does the ratio of unproductive to productive labor increase 
 over time? if this ratio is squeezing profits, it seems that profit-seeking 
 capitalists would make an effort to lower it. or is there some sort of 
 technological or social imperative that pushes capitalists to increase the ratio 
 anyway? or is it a matter of it being good for capitalists as individuals to raise 
 the ratio even though it's bad for capital as a whole?
 
 why the ratio rises is important. For example, if we posit that demand-side 
 stagnation has been the rule of late, that would push up the ratio (for a few 
 years, at least) in that unproductive labor is typically overhead labor, while 
 productive labor is laid off. However, this explanation doesn't fit the waves of 
 downsizing (thinning out of management, etc.) that hit US business during the 
 1990s. (see below)
 
 
 
 Jim,

 I tried to offer one suggestion in my post a few days ago.  In the
 1970s, corporations attempted to restore the profit level through price
 increases (leading to a price-wage spiral) which was cut off by the
 recession of the 1980s.  Since that time, we have been in a period of
 demand constraint.  As a result, increasing productivity has been met by
 downsizing and wage restraint resulting in stagnant wages which leads,
 as you point out, to an underconsumption undertow.  Major corporations
 respond to this demand constraint by increasing  promotion, marketing
 and advertising thereby increasing the ratio of unproductive to
 productive labour.  But given globalisation and Asian competition, firms
 can't raise prices to match the increased cost of unproductive labour.
  They respond by trying to cut managers, etc.  In the 1990s, they were
 aided by technological change in white collar work (i.e.
 computerization) which reduced the relative demand for/employment of
 unproductive labour. (My figures for Canada indicate a significant
 decline in the employment of certain types of secretarial and clerical
 labour in the early 1990s.)
 But  given the deflationary effect of global competition using low-wage
 3rd world labour, 1st world corporations are unable to raise prices to
 restore (realized) profitability.  Thus, the profit recovery in the
 1990s was only partial in the light of continuing need to increase
 unproductive selling/marketing expenditures despite the rise in
 productive worker productivity.  To the extent that the growth in
 non-productive worker productivity is on a declining projectory,   there
 is little to give hope for a new long-term, profit-based expansion based
 on technological change, at least in North America and Europe where the
 ratio of productive to unproductive labour is already so low.

 I think my read on this is similar to Fred's.  If not, I would be glad
 to hear, and if so, why?


Paul, yes, I think our readings are very similar.  Would you please send
me any articles that you have written on this subject (or the
references)?  I look forward to further discussion.

Comradely,
Fred


Re: Estimating the surplus\Doug's question\Fred's comments

2003-12-14 Thread Fred B. Moseley
On Fri, 12 Dec 2003, Mike Ballard wrote:

 I'm obviously not an economist.

 Just a wondering Wobbly,


Mike, what a great description!
I wish there were more wondering Wobblies!

Comradely, Fred


Re: Estimating the surplus\Doug's question

2003-12-14 Thread Fred B. Moseley
On Fri, 12 Dec 2003, Devine, James wrote:

 Paul,. your story makes sense (though I'd add a lot). My question is
 for Fred, though. The classical Marxian story stresses the role of the
 organic composition rising due to some societal or technological
 imperative. For Fred, the rise of the ratio of productive to
 unproductive labor costs has replaced -- or now complements -- that's
 story. I wanted to know his logic.


Jim, I argue that the increase of unproductive labor complements the
increase of the composition of capital.  The rate of profit varies
inversely with both of these, and varies positively with the rate of
surplus-value.

The simple algebra of this Marxian theory of the conventional rate of
profit is as follows (as I am sure you know):


RP = P / K

   = S - U / C + Ku

   = [ S/V - U/V ] / [ C/V + Ku/V ]


Comradely,
Fred


Re: Estimating the surplus\Doug's question\Fred's comments

2003-12-14 Thread Fred B. Moseley
On Sat, 13 Dec 2003, Doug Henwood wrote:

 Fred Mosley wrote:

 6.  I have suggested another explanation of these important trends, one
 based on Marx's distinction between productive labor and unproductive
 labor - that an important cause of the declines in the share and the rate
 of profit was a very significant increase in the ratio of unproductive
 labor to productive labor.  I am not sure that this is the correct
 explanation of these trends, but I think it may be, and I think that it
 worthwhile to at least consider what Marx's theory implies about the
 causes of these trends and the likely prospects for the future.
 
 And one important advantage that this theory has over the profit squeeze
 explanation is that it provides a consistent explanation of why the share
 and rate of profit have only partially recovered in recent decades, in
 spite of the loss of workers' power and stagnant real wages - because the
 ratio of unproductive to productive labor has continued to increase.
 
 This theory also provides an important prediction about the future - that
 if the ratio of unproductive to productive labor continues to increase (as
 I expect), then the recovery of the share and rate of profit will continue
 to be slow and partial, thus leading to more wage cuts, speed-up,
 etc.  According to this theory, the US economy is definitely NOT at the
 beginning of another long-wave period of growth and prosperity, similar
 to the early postwar period (with steady real wage increases).  The only
 partial recovery of the share and rate of profit makes such a return to
 more prosperous conditions very unlikely.

 Why should a national economy be the unit of analysis? Why can't U.S.
 capitalists and a significant portion of the U.S. population propser
 by appropriating the SV produced by, say, Chinese workers? Wal-Mart
 is a profit machine - is it productive or unproductive?


Hi Doug, you are right that the appropriate unit of analysis is the world
economy, and that surplus-value produced by e.g. Chinese workers is
appropriated by US capitalists.  But since this surplus-value is
appropriated by US capitalists, it is mostly included in the estimates of
profits in the US NIPAs.

But this international aspect does mean that the estimates of the ratio of
unproductive labor to productive labor in the US are overestimated.

Comradely,
Fred


Re: Estimating the surplus\Doug's question

2003-12-14 Thread Fred B. Moseley
On Sat, 13 Dec 2003, Doug Henwood wrote:

 Fred B. Moseley wrote:

 5.  The most popular radical-Marxian explanation of these profit rate
 trends has been the reserve army profit squeeze theory - that low
 unemployment rates in the late 1960s and early 1970s increased workers
 power, and enable them to gain substantial wage increases and to squeeze
 profits.  This theory then explains the increase in the rate of profit on
 the higher rates of unemployment and the loss of workers' power in recent
 decades.  This seems to be Doug's explanation of these trends.
 
 However, this profit squeeze theory does not provide a very good
 explanation of the only-partial recovery of the rate of profit, and
 especially the share of profit, in recent decades.  One would think that,
 if greater worker power leading to wage increases in the 1960s and 70s
 caused the profit share to decline, then surely the last three decades of
 wage-cuts, speed-up on the job, and the general attack on workers and
 unions should have fully restored the profit share by now.

 Why fully restored? The 1950s and 1960s were a Golden Age with few if
 any historical precedents that followed the worst depression in
 history. The corporate sector had net losses in 1932 and 1933,
 something it's never come close to replicating since. But the
 corporate profit share of GDP rose from the low of 5.2% in 1982 to
 8.7% in 1997, a 67% increase. Sure it's below the 10-11% levels of
 the mid-1960s, but it's a major recovery. And though I haven't gotten
 a chance to analyze the latest benchmark revision of the NIPAs, they
 show a very substantial rise in profits in 2001 and 2002 - an amazing
 performance in a recession and weak recovery.

You are comparing a cyclical low (1982) with a cyclical high (1997).
And do your estimates include interest?

The estimates of the (profit + interest) share show cyclical ups and
downs, but very little overall increase since the 1970s.



 The 1982-97 and 2001-2002 profit recoveries happened despite an
 increase in what you call unproductive labor. Why?

In part because of the cyclical effects of higher capacity utilization
rates, but also over the long-term because of a very significant
increase in the rate of surplus-value, the ratio of the surplus-value
produced by productive workers to the wages of productive workers (S/V in
the following equation for the Marxian determination of the conventional
rate of profit, included in a prior post):


RP = P / K

   = S - U / C + Ku

   = [ S/V - U/V ] / [ C/V + Ku/V ]



Comradely,
Fred


Re: Estimating the surplus\Doug's question

2003-12-14 Thread Fred B. Moseley
On Sun, 14 Dec 2003, Doug Henwood wrote:

 Fred B. Moseley wrote:

 You are comparing a cyclical low (1982) with a cyclical high (1997).
 And do your estimates include interest?

 1997 was four years before the cyclical high, actually. But the 1982
 low was in many ways - political as well as economic - a point of
 structural reversal. Mexico's debt crisis marked the onset of
 neoliberal restructuring of the world; the stock market took off at
 almost the same minute as the Mexican quasi-default; and the Reagan
 boom was about to begin. That was about a lot more than a business
 cycle - it was about a whole new regime of accumulation.


And my point is that this new regime of accumulation - whose main purpose
was to restore the rate of profit - has been only partially successful.

1997 was the peak for the share and rate of profit, as you must know,
after which they declined sharply, so that the share of profit in 2001
was almost as low as in 1982.

Doug, do you think that profit has been restored to such an extent
that the US economy is entering a new long-wave period of growth
and relative prosperity, with signficant increases in average real wages?

Comradely,
Fred


Re: Estimating the surplus\Doug's question

2003-12-11 Thread Fred B. Moseley
I have been trying to find the time to join this interesting discussion on
the rate of profit in the US economy.  My classes finally ended
yesterday.  A few comments:


1.  I think we can all agree on the big focus of profit rates, as Paul
put it - that the rate of profit is the most important variable in
analyzing capitalism.  And I agree with Paul that this emphasis on profit
and the rate of profit is what distinguishes classical-Marxian theories
from neo-classical theories.

2.  And I think we are talking about the same rate of profit and the same
share of profit - as measured by the NIPAs.  I (and most others) include
interest so profit means total income to capital.

3.  This conventional rate of profit declined about 50% in the early
postwar period, and has regained only about half of that decline since the
1970s.  The profit share declined less (about 30%), but has hardly
increased at all in recent decades.

4.  Where we mainly disagree (as Paul has pointed out) is about the CAUSES
of these important trends - the causes of the decline, and the causes of
the incomplete recovery.

5.  The most popular radical-Marxian explanation of these profit rate
trends has been the reserve army profit squeeze theory - that low
unemployment rates in the late 1960s and early 1970s increased workers
power, and enable them to gain substantial wage increases and to squeeze
profits.  This theory then explains the increase in the rate of profit on
the higher rates of unemployment and the loss of workers' power in recent
decades.  This seems to be Doug's explanation of these trends.

However, this profit squeeze theory does not provide a very good
explanation of the only-partial recovery of the rate of profit, and
especially the share of profit, in recent decades.  One would think that,
if greater worker power leading to wage increases in the 1960s and 70s
caused the profit share to decline, then surely the last three decades of
wage-cuts, speed-up on the job, and the general attack on workers and
unions should have fully restored the profit share by now.  The average
real wage in the US economy has not increased since the early 1970s and
has even declined some.  Meanwhile productivity has continued to
increase.  And yet the profit share has hardly increased at all.  This
seems hard to explain by the wage push profit squeeze theory

6.  I have suggested another explanation of these important trends, one
based on Marx's distinction between productive labor and unproductive
labor - that an important cause of the declines in the share and the rate
of profit was a very significant increase in the ratio of unproductive
labor to productive labor.  I am not sure that this is the correct
explanation of these trends, but I think it may be, and I think that it
worthwhile to at least consider what Marx's theory implies about the
causes of these trends and the likely prospects for the future.

And one important advantage that this theory has over the profit squeeze
explanation is that it provides a consistent explanation of why the share
and rate of profit have only partially recovered in recent decades, in
spite of the loss of workers' power and stagnant real wages - because the
ratio of unproductive to productive labor has continued to increase.

This theory also provides an important prediction about the future - that
if the ratio of unproductive to productive labor continues to increase (as
I expect), then the recovery of the share and rate of profit will continue
to be slow and partial, thus leading to more wage cuts, speed-up,
etc.  According to this theory, the US economy is definitely NOT at the
beginning of another long-wave period of growth and prosperity, similar
to the early postwar period (with steady real wage increases).  The only
partial recovery of the share and rate of profit makes such a return to
more prosperous conditions very unlikely.

This theory may be wrong, but it seems to me that it should at least be
considered, and its economic and political implications pondered.


I look forward to further discussion, as time permits.

Comradely,
Fred


Re: Estimating the surplus - Turkey (Cem Somel)

2003-12-04 Thread Fred B. Moseley
On Thu, 4 Dec 2003, Doug Henwood wrote:

 g kohler wrote:
 
 Concerning the Somel - Parmaksiz (based on ShaikhTonak) difference of
 estimates about Turkey - don’t know. But regarding estimates of SV USA,
 Moseley’s book compares his estimates with those of other authors. All of
 these authors measured the same theoretical concept (SV). But the estimates
 diverged considerably. One of the reasons was that other authors stayed
 closer to the statistical categories of the GDP accounting system, whereas
 Moseley re-cast the data into authentic Marxian categories.
 
 And the intellectual/political payoff for this authenticity is?
 
 Doug


A different understanding of the causes of the decline of the rate of
profit in the postwar US economy, and of the reasons for its only partial
recovery, in spite of two decades of wage cuts, speed-up, etc.



Re: Rates of profit: a recent article

2003-11-24 Thread Fred B. Moseley
This is a response to Paul's post of ten days ago (Nov. 13) on recent
trends of the rate of profit in the US economy (see below).  Paul, thanks
for your post and sorry for my delay in responding.  It is a busy time of
the semester, and I had to find some time to take a look at Wolff's paper.


In a 1997 paper in the RRPE (The Rate of Profit and the Future of
Capitalism), I updated my estimates of the rate of profit and its Marxian
determinants through 1994.  According to these estimates, the rate of
profit had recovered less than half of its prior decline, and thus
remained approximately 30% below its early postwar peak.  (This paper is
available on my website: www.mtholyoke.edu/~fmoseley.)

Wolff's estimates end in 1997, which was a cyclical peak, and thus
exaggerate the increase.  The rate of profit declined sharply between 1997
and 2001-02 (as we have discussed on pen-l).  There has been some rebound
this year, but my guess is that the rate of profit today is no higher than
it was in 1994, and is probably somewhat lower.  There are probably some
further differences between Wolff's estimates and my estimates, but I
would have to study them more carefully.  Comparison is difficult because
Wolff's estimates are not annual, but only for 5 years between 1947 and
1997 (1947, 1957, 1966, 1979, and 1997), because his estimates are based
on input-output tables, which do not exist for every year.

So I would say that the US economy is still not out of the woods so far
as the rate of profit is concerned.  Therefore, in terms of the strategic
importance of our assessment of the medium-term direction of the US
economy that you mention, I think workers will continue to face strong
persistent attempts to restore the rate of profit - by wage cuts, pension
cuts, speed-up, moving to low-wage areas around the world, etc..  In other
words, the attacks on the living and working standards of US workers in
recent decades is not over and will continue.  I think that is the nature
of the challenge that we face.

According to Marx's theory, one of the main reasons for the prior decline
of the rate of profit was a very significant increase in the ratio of
unproductive labor to productive labor (in addition to an increase in the
composition of capital).  Furthermore, according to Marx's theory, the
main reason why the rate of profit has only partially recovered is that
the ratio of unproductive to productive labor has continued to increase
since the 1970s, and thus partially offset the very large increase in the
rate of surplus-value and a small decline in the composition of capital.

I would be happy to try to answer any further questions, if you wish.

Fred




On Thu, 13 Nov 2003, Paul wrote:

 Date: Thu, 13 Nov 2003 13:50:21 -0500
 From: Paul [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Reply-To: PEN-L list [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Subject: Rates of profit: a recent article

 A useful article on U.S. profit rates, from a marxian perspective, has been
 published recently by Ed Wolff (What's behind the rise in profitability in
 the US in the 1980's and 1990's? in the July issue of the Cambridge
 Journal of Economics vol 27; write me off list for those needing an e-version).

 1)  To my knowledge, this is only the second (!) published article that
 provides a marxian perspective on the 'big picture' of the US
 economy\profit rates since the 1950's AND assesses the last 10-20 years in
 that context.  In January, we briefly discussed this issue and I drew
 attention to the other article by Dumenil and Levy in the RRPE.  There is
 also the (unpublished?) useful pamphlet by Jim Devine (
 http://bellarmine.lmu.edu/~jdevine/talks/newOhio.htm ) and very good
 earlier work by Shaikh and Tonak, Mosely, and a very few others.  In fact,
 many of the key authors, on this key subject, subscribe to Pen-l.  Jim
 Devine is thanked as an ASSA commentator to the paper (comments
 Jim?).  Anyone aware of any other recent articles?

 2)  Three points struck me about the Wolff article:

 - Using somewhat different methods than D  L, the Wolff article confirms
 the view of early '80s to '97 as a period of rising rate of profit - weak
 and perhaps atypical of other periods but still rising.  Wolff is cautious
 not to draw large conclusions (as were D  L), but his breakdown of the
 factors that contributed to the profit rise are long term and 'structural'
 in nature. It seems to me that a context of rising profits (unless you
 believe it is over) will have strategic importance to our assessments of
 the medium term directions of the US economy - and the types of challenges
 we will face.

 - Wolff also concurs with D  L that one major cause of the profit rise was
 a shift in shares away from labor and to profit. [Fred Mosely may have some
 comments about this.]  Both articles attribute labor's loss to real wage
 gains lagging behind productivity gains. Wolff points out that consumer
 good prices rose faster than the GDI inflator; without this effect 

Re: Weapons hunters watch films

2003-06-16 Thread Fred B. Moseley
Hi Barkley,

Your question about mass graves is a very good one.
I hope someone has some more information.

Fred


On Mon, 16 Jun 2003, Barkley Rosser wrote:

 Date: Mon, 16 Jun 2003 15:02:05 -0400
 From: Barkley Rosser [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Reply-To: PEN-L list [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Subject: Re: Weapons hunters watch films

  Actually rather than comment on this issue directly,
 now that it is becoming increasingly clear to anyone
 paying attention (and here in the US Fox TV is trying
 very hard to focus peoples' attention on important
 stuff like the Laci Peterson murder), that both the WMD
 and al Qaeda-link arguments for the war in Iraq were
 completely bogus.  So, the arguments that are being
 handed out to keep the wolves at bay are liberation
 of Iraqis (replay tapes of that small group hitting Saddam's
 statue with their shoes), torture chambers (yes, those
 were bad, they were also not news), and mass graves.
   I am wondering about these latter.  It is my impression
 that the overwhelming majority of these are linked to the
 putting down of armed uprisings, especially in the immediate
 aftermath of the first Gulf war, rather than being dumping
 grounds for political prisoners coming out of the torture
 chambers.  These are very different kettles of fish, needless
 to say, as the US has its own mass graves of the first sort,
 in such places as Gettysburg, to mention a well known one.
   Is there anybody on the list who has more information
 regarding what is what on this matter?  Mass graves has
 increasingly become the new two word answer being used
 by war proponents to silence anyone daring to criticize it.
 Barkley Rosser
 - Original Message -
 From: Chris Burford [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Sent: Monday, June 16, 2003 2:12 AM
 Subject: Re: [PEN-L] Weapons hunters watch films


  At 2003-06-16 00:01 +0100, I wrote:
  On page 2 of Sunday Times, London
  
  Weapons hunters watch films as trail goes cold.
  
  by Christina Lamb, Baghdad.
 
 
  It looks as if some of it is an off the record leak by the senior UK
  representative in Iraq, to defuse little by little the growing problem
 for
  the UK  (less so for the USA) if no WMD are found, and to explain the
  difficulties for the poor Brits in having to work with these Americans
 (who
  can't even fix the air-conditioning).
 
  On re-reading, I think Alastair Campbell's name at the beginning suggests
  the sequence. Campbell deliberately gave a low key background briefing in
  London. We do not know whether it was specifically to a Sunday Times
  reporter, or thrown away as an aside in a briefing to the press in
 general.
  Either way, the Sunday Times got their reporter in Baghdad to follow it up
  with a few direct interviews with the UK representative in Iraq, and with
  Brits in a weapons inspections team in an overheated bombed out palace,
  whose location had been kindly mad eavailable to the ST reporter.
 
  The London desk of the ST then checks for an official statement from the
  Pentagon and from the Prime Ministers official spokesperson, which ends
 the
  story off with a repetition of the official line.
 
  But Campbell is ever so discretely managing the news against Rumsfeld,
 just
  as Rumsfeld is callously ignoring the public embarrassment of the UK
  government. Campbell probably has Blair's consent in managing the
 explosive
  issues of the non-existent WMD in this way. The fingerprints are hardly
  detectable.
 
  Chris Burford
 
 
  PS I would be grateful if people do not cut and paste this article outside
  this list. It is not available on the ST website except through a specific
  search, presumably as part of the ST trying to build up e-business. It
  cannot be copied from the website and it includes a typo by me. My
  fingerprints are therefore also detectable. (Perhaps we should invite
  Campbell onto this list and have a discussion about 'processology'.)
 
 
  Of course it is all free advertising, so since the Sunday Times is
 probably
  the best of the Murdoch empire, I will add the URL
 
  www.timesonline.co.uk/section/0,,2086,00.html
 



Re: Falsifiability and the law of value

2003-06-13 Thread Fred B. Moseley
I argue that Marx's LTV is mainly a macro theory of profit, not a micro
theory of prices.  From this perspective, the main empirical test of
Marx's LTV is the explanatory power of its theory of profit.

I have written a paper on this topic, Marx's Theory: True of False?  A
Marxian Response to Blaug's Appraisal, in Moseley (ed.) *Heterodox
Economic Theories: True or False?* (1995, Elgar).  The Blaug in the title
is Mark Blaug (of *Economic Theory in Retrospect*, etc.).

I argue that Marx's theory of profit has considerable explanatory
power.  It explains inherent technological change, and inherent conflicts
between capitalists and workers over the length of the working day and
over the intensity of labor.  It also explains the increasing composition
of capital, the falling rate of profit, periodic crises, etc.

In striking contrast, the orthodox theories of profit (or interest) -
marginal productivity of capital, time preference, etc. - have little or
no explanatory power.  I argue that there is no contest here.  Marx's
theory wins hands down!  Marx's theory of profit provides a much more
substantial theory of capitalism's important dynamics than do the orthodox
theories of profit.

In Blaug's comment on my paper (in the volume referred to above), Blaug
even concedes this point:

The point is made as soon as it is said.[!]  Neoclassical economics is
essentially a static theory of resource allocation, and as such it does
not make predictions about the dynamic evolution of the capitalist
system.  (p. 135)

Blaug goes on to say that Marx's attempt to develop a theory of the
long-run dynamics of capitalism is TOO AMBITIOUS and suggests that we
should LOWER OUR SIGHTS THEORETICALLY speaking and ... settle for LOOSELY
STRUCTURED HISTORIES of the evolution of the capitalist system, PREDICTING
LITTLE because we CAN EXPLAIN SO LITTLE.   (emphasis added)

This statement is astonishing, coming from such a staunch Popperian, who
his whole life has emphasized definite predictions as the hallmark of
scientific theory.  This abandonment of the attempt to develop a general
theory of the long-run dynamics of capitalism is a clear admission of the
failure of neoclassical economics.

Therefore, if we want to continue to develop a general theory of the
dynamic evolution of capitalism, Marx's theory would seem to be the best
alternative, and indeed the only alternative.


Comradely,
Fred


Re: Rates of Profit: Recent Estimates\Japan

2003-01-16 Thread Fred B. Moseley

Hi Paul,

Thanks again for your comments.  A couple of responses below.



On Wed, 15 Jan 2003, Paul_A wrote:

 Fred,
 
 This has been very useful.  Thanks for the stimulating posts.  The point 
 about debt and financial fragility really must be kept as a prime issue.
 
 You asked for reactions about Japan and nationalizing the bank debt.  I 
 understand that by new proposal you mean it is a new alternative to the 
 U.S. pushed proposal of a classic bankruptcy\deflation with assets being 
 sold off cheaply (and bought by you-know-who).  I also understand you are 
 not asking about the political morality of the proposal, just how would it 
 work out from the macro economic perspective of nation states and capitals.

Right, I am mainly interested in a general theoretical analysis of the
extent to which government policies could avoid, or minimize, the
necessity of bankruptcies in order to reduce debt burdens.  In order to be
more effective, I imagine that the government bail-outs would also have to
include  writing off some of the debt of borrowers, not just taking over
the bad loans of the banks.  But this would of course cost the government
even more.  And even if debt burdens are reduced, these
bankruptcy-avoidance policies still do nothing to raise the rate of
profit.


 Doesn't the analogy to Latin America remind you of just how 
 outrageous it was in the early '80s that their massive debt, largely 
 private or non-sovereign, was nationalized without even a bargaining 
 process or concessions?  What cowardly and selfish leadership; how 
 disingenuous of the Bretton Woods institutions to help push this along.


Are you sure about this?  I thought that most of this earlier Latin
American debt was governent debt from the beginning.  Please explain
further.  What were the main private sectors whose debt was taken over by
the government?


Thanks again.

Comradely,
Fred




Re: Rates of Profit: Recent Estimates

2003-01-15 Thread Fred B. Moseley

On Tue, 14 Jan 2003, Chris Burford wrote:

 On this model, the only important condition for the US economy
 to resume expansion without a period of substantial bankruptcies,
 would be if it receives an inflow of exchange value from the rest
 of the world.

 Perhaps in ways that are invisible to conventional economics?


Hi Chris,

I don't know exactly what you mean by an inflow of exchange-value from
the rest of the world.  Would you please explain further?  

If you mean an inflow of foreign *capital*, then that of course has
already happened on a massive, unprecedented scale in the 1980s and 90s,
which is one of the main things that has propped up the US economy, in
spite of the drastic decline in the rate of profit.  However, this inflow
of foreign capital also has its limits, which we seem to be
approaching.  If this inflow slows down significantly in the years ahead
(which seems likely), then this cushion for the US economy will be
gone.  And if the inflow ever turns into an outflow, then the US economy
would be in deep trouble.

Comradely,
Fred




Re: Rates of Profit: Recent Estimates

2003-01-15 Thread Fred B. Moseley

Hi Paul A.,

Thanks again very much for your very interesting comments.  A few
responses below.


On Tue, 14 Jan 2003, Paul_A wrote:

 Hi Fred,
 
 Thanks to you for your post and, more to the point, your hard work and 
 serious contributions to precisely this question over a number of years.
 
 Yes, D  L are very measured on this point.  In fact they explicitly limit 
 themselves to just presenting the stylized facts.  Still, since seeing D  
 L's numbers I am asking myself 'what-if' -type questions.  [FWIW, my own 
 view is just a shift to a neutral policy stance (to borrow the Fed's 
 language). But I think we can usefully brainstorm.]
 
 My own sense of 'received wisdom' was certainly what you point out - that a 
 sustainable long upswing required considerably more domestic pain 
 (including bankruptcies) than the '77-mid 80s experience and that sooner or 
 later we would face such a scenario in the U.S..  But below are some of the 
 speculations (underline speculations) that I think we need to face (I am 
 not advocating these points; just trying to bring them out for purposes of 
 discussion):
 
 1)  Can we be vastly underestimating the importance of the 
 international dimension?  Certainly the third world HAS been seeing 1930's 
 style bankruptcies and depression since '82.  Eastern Europe goes far 
 beyond that (although the impact of the big industrial collapse on U.S. 
 profits would be somewhat different, at least in the first few years).

Yes, this is a good point.  Especially in Asia in recent years, where
bankrupt companies have been sold off to foreign companies at bargain
rates.  


 
  Also, doesn't the scrapping of the old style U.S. industrial base 
 and moving it overseas partially mimic a bankruptcy process?  One does get 
 the scrapping of physical capital (but admittedly not the write off of 
 fictitious financial capital that comes with bankruptcy or debt 
 restructurings).  Maybe some of the financial write off comes with the 
 stock market dip (I wonder how much of DL's core sector used the stock 
 bubble to unwind their debt position; this could then be functional 
 equivalent to a debt write off).

Actually the relationship was the opposite: corporations borrowed huge
amounts of money to purchase their own stock!  Thereby increasing the
price of its stock to the benefit of the top executives.  In the late
1990s, something like half (!) of all the money borrowed by corporations
was used for this purpose.  Now the bubble has burst, but the debt still
has to be serviced and repaid.  


  It makes me want to dust off the debates of the classical imperial 
 era on the role of foreign investment and trade on home profit levels.
 
 2)  Maybe upswings in today's world require a bit - just a bit - less 
 pain than we previously thought (we generalized too much from the 1930s and 
 its aftermath) to produce an upswing.  I.e. Perhaps the 'pain-to-profit 
 gain' coefficient need not be exactly like the 1930's.  ((Before we try out 
 numbers for the 19th century, let's remember Michael's point about how 
 inexact out numbers are even today.))
 
  I realize this is a slippery slope and one  should proceed with 
 great caution, but it is not a surrender to hydraulic Keynsianism to say 
 some (just some) of the previous pain WAS unnecessary (even for their own 
 long term interests) and the result of misguided government policy pushed 
 on us by greedy narrow-minded interests.  Is, say, Japan really likely to 
 get that much more of an upswing by accepting that much more pain or are 
 there boundary effects to the benefits of pain (such as Jim's points about 
 an undertow or the 'overshooting'/domino effect that widespread bankruptcy 
 produces)?
 
  There might also be boundaries on the profit level highs.  Unless 
 someone devastates Europe and Japan again (I shouldn't joke), should we 
 really be expecting any upswing to produce profit levels like the early 
 post-war peaks in core countries?
 
  In short, (just trying this out for discussion) maybe we've had a 
 moderate restructuring\pain process (maybe with more to come) and that this 
 IS what a moderate upswing looks like?  If this is true, and this is as 
 good as it gets, that's no praise for the system.  In today's world, the 
 high's and lows are just more reduced (for those who live in the core 
 countries).

Certainly, you could be right, and this possibility should be seriously
considered.  I think it is very difficult to know how much of an increase
in the rate of profit is necessary to generate another long-run upswing in
the economy.  But the core rate of profit is only about half of its early
postwar peak.  That certainly does not seem like enough of a rebound to
make possible a long-run upswing.  

The other crucial factor (besides the rate of profit) that you hardly
mention is the record levels of debt of all kinds in the US economy -
business debt, household debt, and 

Re: Rates of Profit: Recent Estimates

2003-01-13 Thread Fred B. Moseley
 
Hi Paul,

Thanks for calling our attention to the Dumenil-Levy article and for your
comments and questions.  

I think it misleading to talk in terms of a new long-run upward trend in
the rate of profit.  I think D-L are measured and cautious in what they
have to say about this.  The recovery in the rate of profit since the
early 1980s is very weak and partial.  Excluding the highly capital
intensive industries (Transportation and Public Utilities, and
Mining) (as D-L suggest), the increase in the rate of profit since 1982
has been only about 25% of its prior decline, so that the rate of profit
today is roughly half of its early postwar peaks.  Extending the estimates
to 2002 (which is a more appropiate comparison with 1982), as Jim
D. suggests, would lower these %'s further.  

Plus, I am puzzled by the 25% increase in D-L's estimates of the profit
share for the corporate sector.  Other estimates that I have seen of the
profit share show little or no increase in the profit share since
1982.  For example, the BEA estimates for non-financial corporate
business, in the SCB article that Jim D. cited (thanks, Jim), shows the
profit share (including interest) in 2001 actually LOWER than in 1982
(14.5% compared to 15.8%.  So I don't know how the D-L estimates increase
so much.  Maybe it is the difference between the corporate and
non-financial corporate business sector, but I don't think so. 

In the past (as you no doubt know), strong recoveries of the rate of
profit have been accomplished by the widespread bankruptcies of capitalist
firms, which significantly reduces the capital invested (the denominator
in the rate of profit) without reducing the capacity of the economy to
produce profit.  Such widespread bankruptcies have not yet happened in the
US economy since 1982.  While the absence of widespread bankruptcies has
meant the absence of another great depression, it has also meant the
absence of the main mechanism through which the rate of profit has been
increased in the past.  

So, I continue to think that a long-run upswing in the rate of profit is
not likely without such widespread bankruptcies and devaluation of
capital.  I think Japan is facing the same dilemma in even more
intensified form.

Comradely,
Fred

 




Re: quesion from Michael Yates

2003-01-09 Thread Fred B. Moseley

On Wed, 8 Jan 2003, Michael Perelman wrote:

 Can anyone recommend a good article on the causes of stagflation in the US
 in the 1970s?  Thanks.
 -- 


Hi Michael,

You might want to take a look at my 1992 book *The Falling Rate of Profit
in the Postwar US Economy*, and a more recent 1997 RRPE paper The Rate of
Profit and the Future of Capitalism.  

Comradely,
Fred




Re: PK on accounting reform

2002-05-21 Thread Fred B. Moseley



On Tue, 21 May 2002, Devine, James wrote:

 By the way, a media evaluation web-page voted PK's column the most
 consistently partisan of op-ed regulars. As I told PK, not that there's
 anything wrong with it. 

More partisan that pro-Israeli fire-eater and let's-go-get-Saddam 
William Safire?

Fred




day of reckoning for the dollar?

2002-05-02 Thread Fred B. Moseley



Related to the Business Week article sent to the list last Friday by Jim
D. on the danger of the US deficit on the current account and increasing
foreign debt, below is an article in last Saturday's Financial Times,
which concludes that the day of reckoning for the dollar is close at
hand.  

The article emphasizes that the key problem is that it is not necessary
for foreign investors to sell US assets for the dollar to fall.  All that
is necessary is that foreign investors cease to buy US assets, or buy them
at a slower rate.  And it argues that there are good reasons to believe
that foreign investors may indeed purchase US assets at a slower rate in
the coming months:  US asset markets are no longer outpacing the rest of
the world; the price-earnings ratio on US stocks is almost twice as high
as on European stocks (the print version of the article has an impressive
graph of this differential in price-earnings ratios, which has increased
in recent months); and US bonds have become less attractive.  One could
add that the Enron scandal and the more general accounting crisis in the
US have led many to have doubts about the value of US assets.  

If the day of reckoning is at hand for the dollar, then so it is for the
US economy, which has become increasing dependent on foreign capital in
recent years, and which would suffer negative consequences if this inflow
of foreign capital were to slow down (rising interest rates, slower
investment and growth, higher unemployment, etc.), and especially if it
were to turn into capital outflows.

Fred



Analysts sense day of reckoning for dollar: A fall in capital inflows to
 the US has alarm bells ringing
 
Financial Times; Apr 27, 2002
By CHRISTOPHER SWANN


After a frustrating couple of years, dollar bears in the foreign exchange
market are scenting blood.

With the US economy supposedly leading the world out of recession, one
might have expected the greenback to spring higher. In fact it has fallen
by almost 3 per cent over the past month in trade-weighted terms.

Currency strategists are asking whether this sign of vulnerability
presages the long-awaited fall in the dollar or whether it is yet another
false alarm.

Defenders of the dollar are quick to point out that the recent weakness of
the currency is largely the result of bets by speculative
traders. Speculators have taken these positions several times over the
past few years, only to be forced to withdraw their bets because fund
managers continued to invest heavily in US assets.

This argument would suggest that the recent weakness of the dollar could
be relatively short-lived. But a rising number of analysts are unpersuaded
by this sanguine analysis. This is not just a fire drill for the dollar,
it is a real alarm, says David Bloom, currency strategist at HSBC in
London.

The key problem for the US currency is that investors do not need to sell
US assets for the dollar to fall. All that is necessary is that they fail
to buy.

The bloated US current account deficit, running at about 4 per cent of
gross domestic product, means that the US needs to attract a net inflow of
around Dollars 1.5bn (Pounds 1.04bn) every day in order to stop the dollar
falling.

The latest figures from the US Treasury provide strong indications that
capital inflows are finally drying up. In January the net inflow into US
equities and fixed income was just Dollars 9.5bn. This is weak even
compared with the Dollars 17.8bn the US attracted in September.

Analysts say the US is struggling to attract funds because its asset
markets are no longer outpacing the rest of the world.

Over the past few years, just when one source of inflows for the dollar
ran dry another would take over, said Ray Attrill, director of research
at 4Cast, the economic consultancy. Now it is becoming harder to see how
the US can attract enough funds to prevent the dollar from
falling. Inflows into US corporate bonds, which funded the lion's share
of the current account last year after mergers and acquisitions inflows
dried up, are thought unlikely to be as important in 2002. Economists are
concerned that recovery has been based on companies rebuilding their
stocks after the slowdown and government spending rather than on a pick-up
in investment spending.

This is low-quality economic growth of the kind that does not boost
corporate profits, said Paul Meggyesi, senior economist at Deutsche
Bank. It is looking increasingly like the day of reckoning for the dollar
is close at hand. 

 Copyright: The Financial Times Limited 1995-2002








Re: Devine/Moseley discussion

2002-02-17 Thread Fred B. Moseley


This is a belated response to Jim D.'s post of Feb. 3.  Jim, thanks again
for your thoughtful posts.  I too have found our discussion
stimulating.  I have been thinking about our agreements and disagreements,
and trying to further clarify my own ideas.

Due to limited time, I want to concentrate on the last part of your post
which deals with the key issue of what adjustments are necessary for a
sustainable recovery from the current recession.  This last part of your
post is as follows:


On Sun, 3 Feb 2002, Devine, James wrote:

  The other crucial question is: what is necessary for a sustainable
 recovery from the current recession? I argue that a sustainable recovery
 requires an increase in investment spending, which in turn requires an
 increase in the rate of profit. One of the main ways to increase the rate of
 profit is to cut wages. This conflict between profit and  wages is an
 unavoidable fact of life in capitalism, and it is intensified in
 recessions. 
 
 Cutting wages is the old time religion for capitalists. (To quote Andrew
 Mellon, the Paul O'Neill of the late 1920s and early 1930s, liquidate
 labor, liquidate stocks, liquidate the farmers, liquidate real estate.)  It
 perhaps makes sense within the logic of capitalism - an essentially
 anti-human system - that the only way capitalism can prosper is on the backs
 of the workers. 
 
 But, as I've said in my papers on the origins of the Great Depression of the
 1930s, this logic only works if there's enough aggregate demand to allow the
 realization of the increased profits that result from cutting wages
 (relative to labor productivity). In a serious recession of the sort I think
 may be developing, business investment spending is blocked by extreme excess
 capacity, business debt, and pessimistic expectations. In that situation,
 capitalists are in a double bind: conditions push them to slash wages and
 speed up labor processes, which helps with profit production but (all else
 equal) makes the realization problem worse. This is what I've called the
 underconsumption trap.  (If, in addition, we get into a full-scale
 deflation process involving falling nominal wages, that makes things even
 worse.) 
 
 In this situation, the workers' struggle to prevent wage cuts and the like
 (or to actually raise wages) actually help capitalism, by allowing consumer
 spending to stay stable (or to rise).  Keynesian fiscal policy can work
 here, though of course with the current balance of political power it's
 likely to involve tax cuts for the rich and increased military spending.
 
 You seem to be agreeing with me when you say the following:  However,
 cutting wages will also reduce consumption in the short-run, and thus will
 make the recession worse. This is especially worrisome at the present time,
 because of the unprecedented levels of debt of  all kinds -  business debt
 and household debt and US debt to foreigners. These high levels of debt make
 the economy vulnerable to a more serious downturn. 
 
  Therefore, the current dilemma seems to be: that which is necessary to
 solve the fundamental problem of insufficient profitability (cutting wages)
 will make the current recession worse (by reducing consumer  spending), and,
 because of the high levels of debt, runs the risk of a very bad recession. 
 
 I would agree with this analysis as far as it goes. However, it goes against
 what you said before, i.e., the conflict between profit and  wages is an
 unavoidable fact of life in capitalism. If falling wages cause recessions
 to get worse, as you say, this makes capacity utilization and thus
 profitability worse. Then there is a community of interests (however limited
 to a specific economic situation) of capitalists and workers, no conflict
 between profit and wages. This potential community can be realized by
 organized pressure from workers and even the state. 
 
 However, this is only on the macro level. Individual capitalists will
 continue to sink their own collective boat. To the extent that these
 individual interests are reflected in the state's policies, there's no
 reason to expect the state to do anything but make things worse.
 
 Final note: I noted in another missive that with increases in labor
 productivity (not due to speed-up), it's possible to raise wages and profits
 at the same time. That's true mathematically, but capitalism keeps on
 raising workers' needs. This can easily lead to a situation where real
 wages (as usually measured) rise in absolute terms but fall relative to
 needs. (Cf. Mike Lebowitz's BEYOND CAPITAL, ch. 1.) So the conflict is
 re-established. 
 
 Jim Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED] 
 


You make a distinction here between the MICRO effects and the MACRO
effects of a wage cut.  There is a further distinction between the
SHORT-RUN macro effects and the LONG-RUN macro effects, and I think the
latter distinction is the key to the differences between us.

I agree that, in the short-run, a reduction of wages would 

Re: Re: Re: Re: O Joy -- another sign of recovery

2002-02-14 Thread Fred B. Moseley


On Wed, 13 Feb 2002, Doug Henwood wrote:

 Fred B. Moseley wrote:
 
 The point that is missed by the newspaper headlines and these excerpts is
 that retail sales as a whole, INCLUDING autos, DECLINED by 0.2% in
 January.  Not a huge decline, but a decline.
 
 The AP headline from the NY Times website was Retail Sales Rise Sharply
 in January.  Then the first sentence reads:  A drop in car sales ...
 pushed down sales at the nation's retailers by 0.2 percent in January.
 
 Then it goes on to say:  Excluding volatile automobile sales, overall
 retail sales rose by a solid 1.2 percent in January.
 
 There are two good reasons to strip away car sales - one, is that 
 they're normally volatile, and can provoke meaningless swings in the 
 headline number, and two, the 0% financing incentives last year stole 
 a bunch of early '02 sales. So anyone trying to measure the 
 underlying trend in consumption would want to see what's going on 
 ex-autos.  But good progressive economists are irresistibly drawn to 
 the negative number.
 
 The weight of the evidence is that the U.S. economy is troughing, or 
 did bottom out around December. This could be a false bottom, a pause 
 before another downleg; the recovery could be weak, and might feel 
 little different from recession. But there's not much point in 
 ignoring the evidence.


Doug, I don't think I am ignoring the evidence.  Rather, the evidence is
ambiguous.

Strong auto sales was the main reason for the 0.2% increase in the GDP in
the 4th quarter of 2001, which many economists hail as evidence that the
recession is over.  So now that auto sales are negative, are we supposed
to ignore them and focus only on the rest of consumer spending?

But the fact remains that total retail sales, as a proxy for total
consumer spending, is now decreasing, rather than increasing at an annual
rate of 5.4%, as it did in the 4th quarter.  And thus the most important
source of growth in the US economy right now seems to have been
eliminated.  

My answer to your question in another post about whether increased
consumer spending can be the cure for a recession caused by a decline in
investment spending is NO.  Because the decline of investment spending was
caused by a decline of the share and the rate of profit, and businesses
will continue in the months ahead to try very hard to increase
profitability by cutting costs, especially wage costs.  But such attempts
to cut wage costs will also limit consumer spending in the months ahead.

Fred




Re: Re: O Joy -- another sign of recovery

2002-02-13 Thread Fred B. Moseley


The point that is missed by the newspaper headlines and these excerpts is
that retail sales as a whole, INCLUDING autos, DECLINED by 0.2% in
January.  Not a huge decline, but a decline.

The AP headline from the NY Times website was Retail Sales Rise Sharply
in January.  Then the first sentence reads:  A drop in car sales ...
pushed down sales at the nation's retailers by 0.2 percent in January.

Then it goes on to say:  Excluding volatile automobile sales, overall
retail sales rose by a solid 1.2 percent in January.

Fred



On Wed, 13 Feb 2002, Doug Henwood wrote:

 Date: Wed, 13 Feb 2002 13:09:00 -0500
 From: Doug Henwood [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Reply-To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Subject: [PEN-L:22787] Re: O Joy -- another sign of recovery
 
 Tom Walker wrote:
 
 . . . sales aside from cars
 posted their biggest surge since March
 2000, aided by higher prices at the gas
 pump . . .
 
 I guess I'm just thick. I can't figure out how anyone figures a surge in
 retail sales if the uptick is entirely due to higher gas prices and
 excluding slumping car sales from the total. As Max pointed out, the recent
 surge in 4th quarter GDP was in real terms, after adjusting for price
 deflation. That number included car sales bloated by 0% interest rates.
 
 Lies, damned lies and audited financial statements.
 
 Sorry to disappoint, Tom, but taking out gas station sales as well as 
 autos, retail sales were still up 0.8% month-to-month. Surge is 
 jounrnalistic hyperbole, for sure, but consumption is holding up in 
 the U.S. And with the initial unemployment claims falling and 
 consumer confidence rising, it's looking very much like a trough. It 
 could all fall apart, but it ain't yet.
 
 And the Redbook retail sales survey for the first week of Feb was up 
 4.2% year-on-year, bringing the three-month moving average to +1.9%. 
 Since auto sales are much stronger than anyone expected after the 
 fading of 0% financing, retail is looking pretty strong. Sorry again.
 
 Doug
 
 




Re: Enron's SPV's

2002-02-03 Thread Fred B. Moseley


Steve, thanks again for your helpful clarifications.

It sounds like after the private placement takes place and the SPV pays
off its loan, there is nothing left of the debt of the SPV, and hence of
the debt of the Parent.

Is this the case with Enron?  Do all there 3000 SPV's have little or no
debt left?  So there is little or no hidden debt of Enron?  

Or, are SPV's also used for other operations (like the purchase of stocks
of other companies) that require some continuing debt?  

Thanks again,
Fred


On Sat, 2 Feb 2002, Steve Diamond wrote:

 Yes, I realize I left out a few things.  The debt that the SPV takes on is
 used to front the money for the asset (like speculative broadband futures)
 from the parent.  But the SPV soon pays off this loan by selling its new
 securities in the private placement.  In fact, the loan that the SPV takes
 on might just be an LOC (letter of credit) or very short term since the
 private placement with 3d party investors is done almost simultaneously.  In
 the deals I worked on of this general type while in private practice, the
 SPV was set up at the same time as the placing of the securities, tho I am
 certain there is a wide range of possibilities.
 
 Keep in mind that in most cases the SPV's underlying  equity is controlled
 by the Parent, thus they really set the value of the asset.  In the case of
 Enron, CFO Jeff Fastow was an officer (or general partner) of these types of
 entities.  One can see how this can easily lead to an inflation of the value
 of the asset.  It is this step that creates the fictitious value -
 establishing some notion of the present value of an asset that will only pay
 out over a long time in a very inefficient, even nonexistent, market (what
 IS the market for broadband?  ENE was creating it thus they could decide the
 price!)  It is hard not to conclude that this was an elaborate pump and dump
 scheme (see the terrific film Boiler Room to get a sense of what kinds of
 snakes these people really are).
 
 Also, I understand your interest in the debt, but keep in mind that the bank
 that provides the loan for the SPV is only taking on the risk that the SPV
 will not be able to complete the private placement to the third parties - in
 fact, the loan is really just a guarantee - serving to provide some
 reputation effect to help get the private placement done - in one case, for
 example, a piece of the private placement was sold to the MacArthur
 Foundation, so you have to convince one of their fund managers that this was
 a great deal - the investment banker marketing the deal will, of course,
 point to the loan from, e.g., JP Morgan.  Often the loan would not go
 through unless the private placement was clearly going to succeed.  Once
 started the entire operation - for up to a billion dollars - can be done in
 six weeks.
 
 Steve
 
 Stephen F. Diamond
 School of Law
 Santa Clara University
 [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 
 




Re: Take the Money Enron.

2002-02-02 Thread Fred B. Moseley


Hi Steven,

Thank you very much for your very interesting Take the Money Enron
...  I was especially interested in the following paragraph:

   Unfortunately, hundreds of companies now rely on this explosive
 combination of private placements and off balance sheet entities.  The last
 decade has seen the American economy create a massive amount of new paper
 financial obligations using these structures that cannot possibly be
 supported by the productive base of the economy.  In fact, little attention
 is being paid to what is happening in this real economy, made up of steel
 mills, auto assembly plants, health care services, and our physical
 infrastructure, which turn out the products and services that a society
 truly needs to eventually pay off all of these fictitious claims to society'
 s wealth.


I have a data question for you:  The main source of data on debt of
non-financial corporations (NFCB) is the Fed's Flow of Funds accounts.  
It seems to me that most of the off balance sheet debt created in the
1990s would NOT be counted in the Fed's data for the NFCB sector, since
the borrower in most of these cases is a financial partner of a NF
corporation.  At most, it would be counted in the Financial sector, whose
debt increased roughly twice as fast as the NFCB sector in the 1990s.  Or,
in the most hidden (off-shore) cases, it might not be counted by the Fed
at all.

If this is correct, then the Fed's data underestimates the current debt
obligations of the NFCB  sector.  I wonder how significant this
underestimation might be?

Steven (and others) what do you know about this?  

Thanks very much.

Fred Moseley




Re: Enron SPV's and debt

2002-02-02 Thread Fred B. Moseley


Steve, thanks for your very clear and helpful description of the typical
SPV.  Better than anything I have read yet.

My main question at the moment has to do with step (ii), the money the SPV
borrows.  This debt is off the balance sheet of the Parent, although the
Parent still has contingent liability.  

And I would like to know how much of this off the balance sheet debt is
out there for the NFCB sector as a whole?  (and ultimately of the
Financial sector as well, but right now my main interest is the NFCB
sector)  How widespread is this scheme for the NFCB sector as a
whole?  How much off the balance sheet debt was created by NF corporations
in the 1990s?  Any idea?  Know of anyone who might?


And also a question about steps (iii) and (iv): the SPV buys the asset
from the Parent, right?  Otherwise, the Parent could not book the $100m as
revenue, right?

It seems to me that the main purpose of this scheme is step (iv): to
increase the reported revenue, and hence the reported profit, of the
Parent.  Is this correct?

Thanks again,
Fred








Re: Re: Re: Enron SPV's and debt

2002-02-02 Thread Fred B. Moseley


I wonder if Portnoy has an idea of how much debt of the NFCB sector is
off the books?

Fred


On Sat, 2 Feb 2002, Michael Perelman wrote:

 Date: Sat, 2 Feb 2002 18:10:20 -0800
 From: Michael Perelman [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Reply-To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Subject: [PEN-L:22248] Re: Re: Enron SPV's and debt
 
 Fred, the Portnoy testimony that Steve mentioned is excellent is laying
 out the mechanism.
 
 On Sat, Feb 02, 2002 at 09:04:12PM -0500, Fred B. Moseley wrote:
  
  Steve, thanks for your very clear and helpful description of the typical
  SPV.  Better than anything I have read yet.
  
  My main question at the moment has to do with step (ii), the money the SPV
  borrows.  This debt is off the balance sheet of the Parent, although the
  Parent still has contingent liability.  
  
  And I would like to know how much of this off the balance sheet debt is
  out there for the NFCB sector as a whole?  (and ultimately of the
  Financial sector as well, but right now my main interest is the NFCB
  sector)  How widespread is this scheme for the NFCB sector as a
  whole?  How much off the balance sheet debt was created by NF corporations
  in the 1990s?  Any idea?  Know of anyone who might?
  
  
  And also a question about steps (iii) and (iv): the SPV buys the asset
  from the Parent, right?  Otherwise, the Parent could not book the $100m as
  revenue, right?
  
  It seems to me that the main purpose of this scheme is step (iv): to
  increase the reported revenue, and hence the reported profit, of the
  Parent.  Is this correct?
  
  Thanks again,
  Fred
  
  
  
  
  
 
 -- 
 Michael Perelman
 Economics Department
 California State University
 Chico, CA 95929
 
 Tel. 530-898-5321
 E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 
 




Re: Re: the profit rate recession

2002-01-29 Thread Fred B. Moseley


On Mon, 28 Jan 2002, Doug Henwood wrote:

 Devine, James wrote:
 
 the data that Fred Moseley and I are discussing is from the BEA and is
 available at:
 http://www.bea.doc.gov/bea/ARTICLES/2001/09september/0901ror.pdf or
 http://www.bea.doc.gov/bea/ARTICLES/2001/09september/ror.xls.
 
 These data are not disaggregated by industry.
 
 Ah, but their definition of profits adds interest back in. That's a 
 useful measure for some purposes, but money spent servicing debt 
 isn't available for investment or dividends.


The rate of profit defined gross of interest is a broader measure of the
return to capital for the capitalist class as a whole.  The rate of profit
defined net of interest is also affected by the division of the gross
profit into non-financial profit and interest.

Doug is right that, from the point of view of individual non-financial
capitals, the money they pay in interest cannot be invested BY THEM.  
However, from the point of view of the capitalist class as a whole,
the interest collected by financial capitalists can (and usually will) be
loaned out and invested by someone else in one way or another.  

Doug is also right that the net rate of profit has increased slightly more
than the gross rate of profit since 1982.  This is because lower rates of
interest in the 1990s have reduced interest payments and raised the net
rate of profit relative to the gross rate of profit (i.e. nonfinancial
capital received a larger share of the gross profit).  

However, from 1965 to 1982, the net rate of profit DECLINED MORE than the
gross rate of profit, for the opposite reason (increasing interest rates
and nonfinancial capital received a smaller share of the gross profit).  
So that, for the whole period from 1965 to 2001, the net rate of
profit declined more than the gross rate of profit.  According to my
calculations (from the estimates in the SCB article by Larkin and Morris),
the gross rate of profit in 2000 was 36% below the 1965 peak and the net
rate of profit was 45% below the 1965 peak.  And if reasonable estimates
for 2001 are added, the declines for the whole period are 46% for the
gross rate of profit and 59% for the net rate of profit.  

Thus, by either measure, there was a very significant decline in the rate
of profit from 1965 to 1982, and a much smaller increase since then, so
that the rate of profit today is about 50% below its 1965 peak.  As I have
said, the fundamental problem of insufficient profitability has not yet
been solved.  It has been masked by accounting tricks, including fraud (as
Michael P. suggests), but it has not yet been solved.

Fred




Re: the profit rate recession

2002-01-29 Thread Fred B. Moseley


On Mon, 28 Jan 2002, Charles Brown wrote:

  the profit rate  recession
 by Fred B. Moseley
 28 January 2002 00:20 UTC  
 My conclusion from these estimates, as I have said many times before, is
 that the fundamental problem in the US economy of insufficient
 profitability has not yet been solved and continues to causes recessions
 and stagnation.
 
 
 
 
 CB: Do you think this fundamental problem can be solved through reforms ?  


Charles, thanks for the clarity of your question.

The short answer to your question is no, there is no reform - that I know
of - that will solve the fundamental problem of insufficient
profitability.  According to Marx's theory, what is needed is one or more
of the following:  a devaluation of capital (through bankruptcies,
write-offs, etc.), lower wages, and/or a reduction of unproductive
labor.  Marx emphasized the former.  

So the reform that you seem to be most interested in - higher wages - will
not solve this problem.  Rather, it will make this problem worse.  It
would be nice if Jim's theory of insufficient demand for consumer goods
were true.  Then there would be no inherent conflict of interests in
capitalist economies, and no necessary inverse relation between wages and
profit, as Marx (and Ricardo) emphasized.  It would then always be
possible to achieve higher wages and living standards for workers with
endangering profits.  But, alas, I don't think this theory is true.  The
inverse relation between wages and profits becomes especially clear in
times of recessions, like today.  

Perhaps a reform that will make the bankruptcy process less disruptive of
production and employment would make the restoration of profitability less
painful.  Chapter 11 bankruptcy already does that to some extent.  But the
problem is that in a bankruptcy, someone has to lose a lot of money, and
there will usually be a fight over that, e.g. the bankruptcy of Global
Crossing announced today (the second largest bankruptcy in US history,
second only to Enron).  

Fred




Re: Re: Re: : The rate of profit and recession

2002-01-29 Thread Fred B. Moseley


On Tue, 29 Jan 2002, Doug Henwood wrote:

 Rakesh Bhandari wrote:
 
 The Fed is powerless to change this; fiscal policy can relieve 
 realization problems but the resumption of private investments 
 depends on the restoration of profitability through the devaluation 
 of constant capital and a rising rate of surplus value.
 
 So, translating into demotic English - one of the most aggressive 
 easing streaks in Fed history will have no effect, and there will be 
 no recovery anytime soon? Are you expecting a long stagnation or a 
 deep depression?


I think that it is very unlikely that the Fed's expansionary monetary
policy will be successful in reviving investment spending anytime soon,
because of continuing problems of low profits, high debts, and low
capacity utilization rates.  The US economy is not going to be pulled out
of recession in 2002 by increased investment spending.  

It is possible that consumer spending will continue to be strong, in spite
of a decline in disposable income, and that households will make up the
difference by going even deeper into debt than they already are.  US
households seemed to be determined, come hell or recession, to continue
their recent spending spree, even though their disposable income has
declined (and promises to decline even more), and even though their
continued spending requires rapidly increasing debt.  In this case, there
might be a slow recovery in 2002, but only as the result of households
increasing their already heavy and unprecedented debt burdens.  This does
not seem to be a very strong basis for a sustainable recovery.  

And the fundamental problem of insufficient profitability remains, and
will continue to depress investment and thus the economy in general.  

Fred





Re: the profit rate recession

2002-01-27 Thread Fred B. Moseley


On Fri, 25 Jan 2002, Charles Brown wrote:

  the profit rate  recession
 by Fred B. Moseley
 
 
 -clip-
 The main point of disagreement seems to be - whether or not the decline of
 investment spending that caused the recession was itself caused by the
 decline in the rate of profit since 1997.  I argue yes and you argue
 no.  You argue that business investment decisions are not determined by
 short-run cyclical fluctuations in the rate of profit, but are instead
 determined by the long-run trend in the rate of profit, and also by the
 capacity utilization rate.
 
 
 
 CB: Fred, Hope your child is better.

He is, thank you, but then I got it!  An awful flu eminating from school
and circulating through families.  


 What if the decline in the rate of profit is due to failure to realize
 through sale of commodities, failure to complete fully  the C-M' phase
 of M-C-M' ?


The rate of profit declined from 1997 to 2000, and during this time the US
economy was booming and there was no realization problem.  This decline
in the rate of profit is what caused the decline in investment spending,
which in turn caused the recession.  Since the recession began, there has
been a realization problem, which has further reduced the rate of
profit.  But this further decline in the rate of profit due to
realization problems was an effect of the recession, not a cause.  

Charles, does this make sense to you?

Thanks,
Fred




Re: Re: Re: the profit rate recession

2002-01-27 Thread Fred B. Moseley


On Fri, 25 Jan 2002, Doug Henwood wrote:

 Michael Perelman wrote:
 
 Doesn't fraud also accompany a falling rate of profit?  I have thought about
 this relationship quite a bit, but I have seen relatively little written about
 it.
 
 As profit rates fall, companies resort to more and more risky behavior to
 compensate for the fall into rate of profit.  In the process, they resort to
 first flaky and then fraudulent behavior.
 
 In the US, the profit rate rose from the early 80s until around 1997. 
 Funny accounting also increased over the period - in bull markets, 
 people don't want to hear bad news, and they want profits to grow 
 rapidly forever. The bursting of a speculative bubble brings calls 
 for tighter accounting.


Doug, this may be misleading.  The rate of profit certainly did not
increase continuously from 1980 to 1977, and then decline.  Rather, the
rate of profit fluctuated up and then down in the 1980s, so that the rate
of profit in 1992 (7.0%) was only slightly higher than it was in 1980
(6.2%).  Similar fluctuations (with somewhat larger amplitudes) occurred
in the 1990s, first an increase to 1997 and then a sharp decline to 7.1%
in 2001).  So that the rate of profit today remains only slightly above
what it was in the trough of the early 1980s.  

My conclusion from these estimates, as I have said many times before, is
that the fundamental problem in the US economy of insufficient
profitability has not yet been solved and continues to causes recessions
and stagnation.

Best,
Fred




Re: re: the profit rate recession

2002-01-24 Thread Fred B. Moseley


Hi Jim,

I am sorry for my delay in responding to your last message of Monday,
Jan. 14.  A sick son, an overdue paper deadline, and classes starting next
week have kept me otherwise occupied.  I just have time for a few brief
comments.

We seem to agree on the following points (please correct me if I am
wrong):

1.  The rate of profit declined significantly from the mid-1960s to the
1970s, and this declining profitability was the main cause of the
stagflation of recent decades.  

2.  If the rate of profit is examined from 1980 to 2002 (estimated), then
there is little or no upward trend in the rate of profit over this period
(and even a slight decline in the share of profit).  
The years 1980 and 2002 are appropriate end points for the estimation of
the trend, because they are at the same point in the business cycle - the
bottom of a recession.

You have other arguments, using other end points and other selected years,
that the rate of profit has increased since 1980.  But you acknowledge
that all these different measures show only a small increase, and that the
rate of profit today remains significantly below its earlier postwar
highs.  

3.  The current recession was caused by a sharp decline in investment
spending, beginning in late 1990.  

4.  The current recession could be made worse because of a subsequent
decline in consumer spending.  


The main point of disagreement seems to be - whether or not the decline of
investment spending that caused the recession was itself caused by the
decline in the rate of profit since 1997.  I argue yes and you argue
no.  You argue that business investment decisions are not determined by
short-run cyclical fluctuations in the rate of profit, but are instead
determined by the long-run trend in the rate of profit, and also by the
capacity utilization rate.  

However, it has been widely discussed in the business press that
investment collapsed in 2001 as a result of rapidly deteriorating
profitability.  As we have discussed, the rate of profit turned down in
1997, and has continued to decline ever since, and finally took its toll
on investment spending in late 2000.  This is how business executives
themselves have explained their reductions of investment spending.  

The investment cutback was probably also influenced by the long-run
decline in the rate of profit since the mid-1960s.  But the primary
precipitating factor seems to have been the sharp decline in the rate of
profit since 1997.  

The capacity utilization rate declined as a RESULT of the recession, it is
not a cause of the recession.  In the months ahead, the low capacity
utilization rate will certainly have a negative effect on investment
spending, and thus will make a recovery from the recession more
difficult.  But the low capacity utilization rate did not cause the
initial decline in investment spending which caused the recession.

Jim, I still don't understand what you think caused the decline in
investment spending that caused the recession.  

The other crucial question is: what is necessary for a sustainable
recovery from the current recession?  I argue that a sustainable recovery
requires an increase in investment spending, which in turn requires an
increase in the rate of profit.  One of the main ways to increase the rate
of profit is to cut wages.  This conflict between profit and wages is an
unavoidable fact of life in capitalism, and it is intensified in
recessions.  

However, cutting wages will also reduce consumption in the short-run, and
thus will make the recession worse.  This is especially worrisome at the
present time, because of the unprecedented levels of debt of all kinds -
business debt and household debt and US debt to foreigners.  These high
levels of debt make the economy vulnerable to a more serious downturn.  

Therefore, the current dilemma seems to be: that which is necessary to
solve the fundamental problem of insufficient profitability (cutting
wages) will make the current recession worse (by reducing consumer
spending), and, because of the high levels of debt, runs the risk of a
very bad recession.  


Jim (and others), do you agree or disagree with the above?

Thanks again for the discussion.

Fred





Re: Re: Re: Re: the profit rate recession

2002-01-15 Thread Fred B. Moseley


On Mon, 14 Jan 2002, Doug Henwood wrote:

 Rakesh Bhandari wrote:
 
 yes what the previous collapse in basic memory chips suggests is 
 that constant capital had cheapened so considerably (esp relative to 
 consumer goods as is almost the case, I believe) that the rate of 
 profit on the lower value of this constant capital can now be 
 greater even if the rate of surplus value is not going to vary much 
 one way or another. So the demand for constant capital is picking up 
 (and therewith the prices of memory chips) not because consumption 
 is higher (as a crude and even sophisticated unconsumptionist may 
 think) but because profitability is being restored.
 
 Doug, you know i am an autodidact but isn't this the ABC's of the 
 Marxian theory of the business cycle?
 
 You're too modest with the autodidact label. But I'm not speaking 
 church Marxian - I was speaking vulgate, and bizcycle economics is 
 about as vulgar as it gets. My only point was that if Hyman is right, 
 then consumption won't be collapsing, and the recession is over, or 
 almost over.
 
 And this recession had little to do with consumption - it was mostly 
 profit and investment-led (at least in the U.S.).
 
 Doug


Hi Doug,

I agree completely that the causes of this recession have little to do
with consumption (at least so far), and have mostly to do with falling
profits and investment.  This is the main point I have been arguing in my
discussion with Jim D.

Greenspan emphasized again in a speech last week that weak profits and
investment is a reason for continuing concern about the economy.  

Fred





Re: Re: the profit rate recession

2002-01-15 Thread Fred B. Moseley


On Mon, 14 Jan 2002, Doug Henwood wrote:

 Rakesh Bhandari wrote:
 
 At any rate, the crisis hit Dept I first. Consumption was not a 
 problem. We also know Marx's famous vol II passge in which he 
 criticizes underconsumption. Consumption will now give.
 
 We'll see. Wall Street's favorite economist, Ed Hyman, has a piece 
 out today claiming the U.S. recession probably ended in November 
 (citing, as most recent evidence, a decline in unemployment claims, 
 higher-than-expected chain store sails, a 23% surge in DRAM prices 
 over the last week, and several major positive profits surprises). 
 And, he says, a synchronized global recovery is underway, citing 
 higher Taiwanese exports, UK retail sales, Malaysian industrial 
 production, and Canadian housing starts over only the last few weeks. 
 Finally, in November, his composite leading indicator for the OECD 
 had its biggest monthly increase in 18 years.
 
 For what it's worth, of course
 
 Doug


Doug, are you agreeing with Hyman and this growing consensus?  What about
the recovery of profits and investment?  If the cause of this recession is
mostly falling profits and investment, as  we seem to agree, isn't a
necessary condition for recovery from the recession the recovery of
profits and investment?  How likely is a recovery of profits in the coming
months?  That would seem to be the crucial question.  Does Hyman say
anything about profits?  What does Henwood say?

Thanks,
Fred




Re: the profit rate recession

2002-01-07 Thread Fred B. Moseley


Over, the weekend I read with interest Jim D's explanation of the
millennium crisis (i.e. the current recession) on his website, which was
discussed last week on PENL.  I also read his RRPE 2000 paper on the rise
and fall of stagflation.  I mostly agree with the latter and strongly
disagree with the former.  

Jim, as I understand it, you argue that the main cause of the current
recession was an INCREASE in the rate of profit from 1982 to 1977.  It is
not entirely clear to me how an increase in the rate of profit could cause
a recession, but the argument seems to something like the following: The
increase in the rate of profit was in large part caused by an increase in
the share of profit, which in turn was caused workers' wages increasing
slower than the value added of the output.  However, the slower wage
growth, which caused the share and the rate of profit to increase, also
caused problems of insufficient demand for consumer goods (i.e. problems
of underconsumption), which eventually caused the recession.  

Jim, is this roughly correct?  Please correct or elaborate.

If this is correct, then this theory would seem to suggest that, in the
quarters leading up to the beginning of the recession in 2001, consumer
spending should have been very weak.  However, THE OPPOSITE IS THE
CASE.  As is well-known, US consumers have been on an extended spending
spree in recent years, which has resulted in rapid rates of increase of
consumer spending (consumer spending has increased faster than value
added).  Indeed, consumer spending is STILL INCREASING in the fourth
quarter of the recession, spurred in large part by the zero
interest incentives on automobiles, plus continuing strong credit growth
in general.  It is possible (though I think unlikely) that this will be
the first recession in US history in which consumer spending does not
decline!  Nothing is said these days about weak consumer spending.  Thanks
is always given for strong consumer spending.  

What has collapsed, by striking contrast, has been investment spending,
which has declined about 10% since mid-2000, and is still declining.  
Computer hardware makers, not consumer goods makers, were the
hardest hit by the recession.  In the words of the Cisco CEO, 
investment demand fell off a cliff.

These facts contradict an underconsumption explanation of the current
recession, and suggest instead that this recession was caused by the
collapse of investment spending, not by insufficient consumer spending.  

Jim, am I missing something?


I would argue further that the sharp decline in investment spending since
later 1999 was caused by an even bigger decline in the rate of profit from
1997 to 2000, which in turn was caused mainly by a similar decline in the
share of profit over this period. The decline in the profit share since
1997 has been so strong that it has completely wiped out the previous
increase in the mid-1990s (I will focus on the profit share since the
estimates are easier).  The profit share today is no higher that it was in
the trough of the early 1980s.  Jim's estimates are taken from Larkin and
Morris (2001) and ultimately from the SCB (BEA).  These estimates go
through the year 2000, which shows a small increase over 1982.  However,
if these estimates are updated through the third quarter of 2001, we find
that there has been a further significant decline, so that the profit
share in 2001 will probably turn out to be even lower that it was in the
trough of 1982 (0.15), and will probably set an all-time record low for
the postwar period of 0.14.  (These estimates are for the NFCB sector.)

Therefore, I argue that the current recession has been caused, in
classical Marxian fashion, by a sharp decline in the rate of profit, which
caused investment spending to fall.  

The causal relation between the decline of the rate of profit and the
decline of investment spending in the current recession seems to be widely
understood, including even by the Federal Reserve Board, which in its
terse explanations of its interest rate cuts this year, has repeatedly
emphasized rapidly deteriorating profitability and its negative effect
on investment spending.  

Jim, what is surprising is that in your RRPE (2000) paper, you argue,
along classical Marxian lines, that the cause of stagflation on the 1970s
and 80s was a decline in the rate of profit, and that the cause of the end
of stagflation in the 1990s was an increase in the rate of profit since
1980 (this latter conclusion needs to be reconsidered in light of more
recent data).  I agree completely that the cause of the stagflation of
recent decades was the significant decline in the rate of profit in the
early postwar period (a decline of roughly 50%).   As you know, I have
been making a similar argument for years.  However, you now argue that the
current recession was not caused by the decline in the rate of profit
since 1997, but was instead caused by the increase in the rate of profit
prior to 1997, 

Re: NS update on anthrax source

2001-11-04 Thread Fred B. Moseley


On Sat, 3 Nov 2001, Chris Burford wrote:

 Today's New Scientist (as always, informed, materialist, progressive in 
 political leanings) has an article
 
 The secret is out
 
 The anthrax spores in the letters seem to have undergone the same 
 'weaponisation' technique used to make US bioweapons in the 1960's, a 
 source who cannot be named told New Scientist this week.
 
 This involves treating anthrax cultures with chemicals that make them break 
 into small clumps of spores as they dry, allowing them to stay separate, 
 airborne, - and inhalable.
 
 ...the US 's weaponising recipe is supposed to be a closely guarded secret. 
 If the anthrax has indeed undergone US-style weaponisation, then either the 
 secret is out or the attacks are being made with leftovers from the 
 American weapons programme.
 
 Analyses of the anthrax have focussed on the largest sample available, from 
 the envelope sent to Senator Tom Daschle. These particles are between 1.5 
 and 3 micrometres across, and contain the drying agent silica but no traces 
 of the anticaking agent the Iraqis tried to use without success.
 
 The Soviets did succeed in making dry anthrax, but their milling process 
 reportedly yielded particles with a wider size range.
 
 The spores found in ventilation filters in Washington DC postal offices, 
 and the growing number of cases in postal workers, also support the idea 
 that the anthrax was treated to help it spread through the air. Half of the 
 16 victims so far worked for the US Postal Service.
 
 
 
 [Now what sort of person could be that unnamed source. And why would they 
 want this information discretely public?]


A dove who wants to counteract the attempt by hawks to blame the anthrax
scare on Iraq as a pretext for invading Iraq.  That issue is on the back
burner for now, but I fear it will eventually come back to the front
burner.

Fred




Re: Re: Re: Re: Japanese Liquidity Trap

2001-11-02 Thread Fred B. Moseley


On Tue, 30 Oct 2001, Chris Burford wrote:

 The classic description by Engels of capitalist crises observes in 1877 
 that the world was at that time going through its 6th crisis since 1825.
 
 In this he describes how the markets are glutted (as in present day 
 Japan) but further hard cash disappears, credit vanishes.
 
 I wonder whether we are looking at the same cyclical processes only 
 cushioned rather than cured by the additional Keynesian interventionist 
 attempts by central government at least to avoid a crisis of the 
 circulation of finance capital.
 
 It just can do nothing about restoring the rate of profit. And with the 
 newly coined(?) term 'liquidity trap' we see that even if such measures 
 make the crisis less acute, they may make it worse.


Chris,

I think you are exactly right about this.  This is the answer to your
puzzle of several weeks ago - that Marx predicted high interest rates at
the peak of an expansion, but now we have low interest rates.  The answer,
as you say, is expansionary monetary policy, which was non-existent in
Marx's day, but is widely used today.  Expansionary monetary policy may
make the crisis less acute, not by reviving business investment (that
requires a revival of the rate of profit), but rather by lowering the
interest burden of existing debts.  But expansionary monetary policy
cannot solve the fundamental problem of insufficient profitability (too
low rate of profit).  That requires the liquidation of large amounts of
capital, through bankruptcies, write-offs, etc., as you have emphasized in
other recent posts.  

At least according Marx's theory.  And Marx's theory seems very
much to be supported by what is going on in the world economy today.

Comradely,
Fred




Re: Re: failing firms must be promptly liquidated

2001-11-02 Thread Fred B. Moseley


Chris,

I seem to have deleted by mistake your #19226 on 31 Oct. about the comment
by Prof. Kakagi on p. 12 of last week's English Language Nikkei Weekly
(how did you find this?!) that failing firms must be promptly
liquidated.  

I agree that the latest proposals of the Japanese Bankers Assoc. is mild
medicine.  Tough words, little action.  This is what Japanese government
officials have been doing for the last 4 or 5 years, ever since the
gravity of the Japanese banks' bad loans problem became apparent.  They
just can't seem to bring themselves to liquidate, liquidate,
liquidate.  They want a softer, more humane capitalism, and are trying to
avoid the hard-nosed, cold-blooded US variety.  And they think it can
work, i.e. that this can be a way out of Japan's bad loans problems and
deepening recession.  

But, according to Marx's theory, there is no softer way to get out of
the problems of low profits and high debts.  The only way to solve these
problems is to liquidate, liquidate, liquidate.  Which will of course
make the recession worse, and perhaps turns the recession into a
depression, at least in the short-run.  The question is: how long will the
short run last?  Japanese officials (and bankers and capitalists) do not
seem want to take this chance, and with good reason.  

Fred




Re: Re: failing firms must be promptly liquidated

2001-11-02 Thread Fred B. Moseley


On Thu, 1 Nov 2001, Chris Burford wrote:

 At 31/10/01 20:38 -0600, you wrote:
 On Wednesday, October 31, 2001 at 17:35:00 (-0800) Michael Perelman writes:
  Chris, the economy will be stronger after liquidation -- if it survives the
  shock -- but it will mean mass unemployment and a further concentration of
  economic ownership.
 
   ... liquidate labor, liquidate stocks, liquidate the farmers,
   liquidate real estate.
 
   ---Treasury Secretary Andrew Mellon, advising Herbert Hoover in
   1930
 
 
 Bill
 
 
 Yes, Prof Takagi and Andrew Mellon were perhaps right wing Marxists without 
 even knowing it.
 
 Marx described this back in 1848. And of course the destruction of capital, 
 includes the destruction of a portion of living variable capital - the 
 section of the work force that are thrown out of the capitalist wage system 
 until hopefully at some time eventually the capitalist cycle picks up again 
 and they have the opportunity to leave the reserve army of labour.
 
 I do not think there is much serious dispute about the overall pattern of 
 capitalist cycles, if the bourgeois can permit themselves to be really 
 frank (like in an article tucked away on page 12 of the Nikkei Weekly).
 
 The progressive question is what very very little can working people do to 
 buck the trend? If there is any influence that can be brought to bear at 
 all, it would be better to update mechanisms of social control over the 
 production process than merely to try to mitigate cuts in the average real 
 wage.
 
 Perhaps the whole apparatus of apparently responsible banking that Takagi 
 appears to describe should be updated by making the bidding for development 
 or liquidity funds more transparent and democratic and to take into account 
 the views of works councils, the local environment and the community.
 
 But the brutality of the overall process is as Marx indicated.


Yes, I agree.


 I think leftist economists should be able to discuss all this quietly and 
 penetratingly with the rapidly expanding ranks of neo-Keynesians.


But who else recognizes the centrality of the rate of profit in the
behavior of the macroeconomy?  Who else even has the rate of profit as a
variable in their theory?  I hope there are some such neo-Keynesians that
I have overlooked.

Fred




Re: Re: Fed's actions

2001-09-20 Thread Fred B. Moseley


Thanks very much to Bill Burgess for further information on the Fed's
infusion of cash last week.  I have not seen anything in the papers this
week about further infusions of cash (only the 1/2 point reduction in the
fed. funds rate).  Has anyone else seen any reference to further cash
infusions this week?

Thanks,
Fred



On Sat, 15 Sep 2001, Bill Burgess wrote:

 Date: Sat, 15 Sep 2001 23:25:24 -0700
 From: Bill Burgess [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Reply-To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Subject: [PEN-L:17211] Re: Fed's actions
 
 I don't think this is all for buying bonds, but Saturday's Globe and Mail 
 reports a $US 82.5 billion infusion of short term cash into the US 
 financial system by the Fed on Friday, for a total of $188 billion since 
 Wednesday. An economist with J.P. Morgan Canada is quoted as estimating the 
 addition of funds this week by the Fed was 20 times the normal amount.
 
 Bill Burgess
 
 At 12:51 AM 16/09/01 -0400, you wrote:
 
 A question for Doug Henwood (Hi Doug) and others:
 
 The New York Times reported on Friday that the Fed purchased government
 bonds of $70 billion on Thursday (after buying $38 billion on Wednesday),
 which it called one of the biggest such operation in memory.  It also
 said that on a normal day the purchase would be several billion dollars.
 
 Does anybody know:
 
 1. Other examples of such high purchases, and what the numbers were?
 
 2. How much the Fed purchased on Friday, which was not reported in
 Saturday's paper (at least I couldn't find it).
 
 
 Thanks in advance,
 Fred Moseley
 
 
 P.S.  The Monday opening of Wall St. should be very interesting.
 
 




Fed's actions

2001-09-15 Thread Fred B. Moseley


A question for Doug Henwood (Hi Doug) and others:

The New York Times reported on Friday that the Fed purchased government
bonds of $70 billion on Thursday (after buying $38 billion on Wednesday),
which it called one of the biggest such operation in memory.  It also
said that on a normal day the purchase would be several billion dollars.  

Does anybody know:

1. Other examples of such high purchases, and what the numbers were?

2. How much the Fed purchased on Friday, which was not reported in
Saturday's paper (at least I couldn't find it).  


Thanks in advance,
Fred Moseley


P.S.  The Monday opening of Wall St. should be very interesting.




Re: Journal of Economic Perspectives

2000-02-01 Thread Fred B. Moseley


I think Brad De Long's idea of a JEP mini-symposium on "radical
economics" is an excellent one, which I appreciate.  

One possibility to consider: I edited a book published in 1995 entitled
*Heterodox Economic Theories: True or False* (the title was a take-off on
one of Mark Blaug's books).  One of the sections was on "radical
economics."  Michael Reich (one of Brad's colleagues at  Cal-Berkeley) 
wrote a response to a previous "methodological appraisal" of
"radical economics" by Blaug, Blaug responded, and a comment on this
exchange was made by economic methodologist Wade Hands.   I think the
debate was interesting.  Perhaps these individuals could adapt and
"update" their appraisals for the JEP.  

Also, Brad, how about a similar mini-symposium on "Marxian economics" (as
distinct from "radical economics")?   My edited book also includes a
section on "Marxian economics", in which I responded to a similar
"methodological appraisal" of "Marxian economics" by Blaug, Blaug
responded again, and this exchange was commented on my Bruce
Caldwell.  Maybe something along these lines could be adapted for the JEP?

These papers were originally presented at a session sponsored by the  
History of Economic Society at one of the ASSA meetings (in Annaheim, 
as I remember).


Thanks again for your suggestion.


Fred Moseley



On Tue, 1 Feb 2000, Brad De Long wrote:

 Date: Tue, 1 Feb 2000 15:14:10 -0800
 From: Brad De Long [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Reply-To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Subject: [PEN-L:15935] Journal of Economic Perspectives
 
 A while ago the _JEP_ had a short symposium on "Austrian" economics: 
 Harvey Rosen wrote a sympathetic critique of the Austrian school, and 
 Leland Yeager responded. This seemed to work: communication was 
 accomplished. The selection of Harvey as someone definitely in the 
 establishment but not unsympathetic to the Austrian point of view 
 proved a good way to get Austrian concerns and views in front of the 
 _JEP's_ readership. The selection of Leland to comment prevented  the 
 symposium from collapsing into being just Harvey Rosen's view of 
 Austrian economics.
 
 Should the powers-that-be at the _JEP_ decide that it is time to do 
 the same thing for "Radical" economics, who should play the role of 
 Harvey Rosen? Who should play the role of Leland Yeager?
 
 
 Brad DeLong
 
 



[PEN-L:4260] request for book

1995-02-23 Thread Fred B. Moseley


I had such good luck with my last request of this kind, I will try again.
This one will be harder:

Does anyone have a copy of Marxism and Materialism by D.-H. Ruben
(Humanities Press, 1977) that they would be willing to sell me?

Thanks,
Fred MOseley



[PEN-L:3904] Krause

1995-01-22 Thread Fred B. Moseley


A strange request:  does anyone have a copy of Money and Abstract Labor
by Ulrich Krause (1982) they would be willing to sell me.  It is long our
of print and I have been unable to obtain a copy any other way.

If so, please send a message directly to me:
[EMAIL PROTECTED]

Thanks,
Fred



[PEN-L:3848] trip to New Orleans?

1995-01-19 Thread Fred B. Moseley


Anyone out there interested in attending the Southern Economic 
Association meetings in New Orleans next November 18-20 and perhaps
organizing a "radical" session?  I have been asked by John Seigfreid 
of Vanderbilt, the incoming President of the SEA who is in charge of 
the program, to organize such a session.  Seigfried mentioned the 
subject of "what's left of Marxism?", but is open to any subject.  
The session would consist of 3 papers.  Seigfried has promised to 
enlist the discussants, if necessary.  

If you are interested, please send me a message, including your ideas about other 
possible participants, as soon as possible directly to me at:  
[EMAIL PROTECTED]

Thanks.




Re: URPE summer conference

1994-04-25 Thread Fred B. Moseley

Hi Teresa,

The dates of the URPE Summer Conference are August 20-23.

Location:  a different camp in Connecticut (I forget the name).
   back to pony country.
   may Camp Sequoia burn to the ground!

Cheers,
Fred Moseley