# Death by halving ## Summary
If miner's income margin are less than 50% (which is a healthy situation when mining hardware is readily available), we might experience catastrophic loss of hashpower (and, more importantly, catastrophic loss of security) after reward halving. ## A simple model Let's define miner's income margin as `MIM = (R-C_e)/R`, where R is the total revenue miner receives over a period of time, and C_e is the cost of electricity spent on mining over the same period of time. (Note that for the sake of simplicity we do not take into account equipment costs, amortization and other costs mining might incur.) Also we will assume that transaction fees collected by miner are negligible as compared to the subsidy. Theorem 1. If for a certain miner MIM is less than 0.5 before subsidy halving and bitcoin and electricity prices stay the same, then mining is no longer profitable after the halving. Indeed, suppose the revenue after the halving is R' = R/2. MIM = (R-C_e)/R < 0.5 R/2 < C_e. R' = R/2 < C_e. If revenue after halving R' doesn't cover electricity cost, a rational miner should stop mining, as it's cheaper to acquire bitcoins from the market. ~~~ Under these assumptions, if the majority of miners have MIM less than 0.5, Bitcoin is going to experience a significant loss of hashing power. But are these assumptions reasonable? We need a study a more complex model which takes into account changes in bitcoin price and difficulty changes over time. But, first, let's analyze significance of 'loss of hashpower'. ## Catastrophic loss of hashpower Bitcoin security model relies on assumption that a malicious actor cannot acquire more than 50% of network's current hashpower. E.g. there is a table in Rosenfeld's _Analysis of Hashrate-Based Double Spending_ paper which shows that as long as the malicious actor controls only a small fraction of total hashpower, attacks have well-define costs. But if the attacker-controlled hashrate is higher than 50%, attacks become virtually costless, as the attacker receives double-spending revenue on top of his mining revenue, and his risk is close to zero. Note that the simple model described in the aforementioned paper doesn't take into account attack's effect on the bitcoin price and the price of the Bitcoin mining equipment. I hope that one day we'll see more elaborate attack models, but in the meantime, we'll have to resort to hand-waving. Consider a situation where almost all available hashpower is available for a lease to the highest bidder on the open market. In this case someone who owns sufficient capital could easily pull off an attack. But why is hashpower not available on the market? Quite likely equipment owners are aware of the fact that such an attack would make Bitcoin useless, and thus worthless, which would also make their equipment worthless. Thus they prefer to do mining for a known mining pools with good track record. (Although hashpower marketplaces exist: https://nicehash.com/ they aren't particularly popular.) Now let's consider a situation where mining bitcoins is no longer profitable and the majority of hashpower became dormant, i.e. miners turned off their equipment or went to mine something else. In this case equipment is already nearly worthless, so people might as well lease it to the highest bidder, thus enabling aforementioned attacks. Alternatively, the attacker might buy obsolete mining equipment from people who are no longer interested in mining. ## Taking into account the Bitcoin price This is largely trivial, and thus is left as an exercise for the reader. Let's just note that the Bitcoin subsidy halving is an event which is known to market participants in advance, and thus it shouldn't result in significant changes of the Bitcoin price, ## Changes in difficulty Different mining devices have different efficiency. After the reward halving mining on some of these devices becomes unprofitable, thus they will drop out, which will result in a drop of mining difficulty. We can greatly simplify calculations if we sum costs and rewards across all miners, thus calculating average MIM before the halving: `MIM = 1 - C_e/R`. Let's consider an equilibrium break-even situation where unprofitable mining devices were turned off, thus resulting in the change in electricity expenditures: `C_e' = r * C_e`. and average MIM after the halving `MIM' = 0`. In this case: r * C_e = R/2 C_e / R = 1/2r (1 - MIM) = 1/2r r = 1/(2*(1-MIM)) Let's evaluate this formulate for different before-halving MIM: 1. If `MIM = 0.5`, then `r = 1/(2*0.5) = 1`, that is, all miners can remain mining. 2. If `MIM = 0.25`, then `r = 1/(2*0.75) = 0.66`, the least efficient miners consuming 33% of total electricity costs will drop out. 3. If `MIM = 0.1`, then `r = 1/(2*0.9) = 0.55`, total electricity costs drop by 45%. We can note that for the before-halving MIM>0, r is higher than 1/2, thus less than half of total hashpower will drop out. The worst-case situation is when before-halving MIM is close to zero and mining devices, as well as cost of electricity in different places, are nearly identical, in that case approximately a half of all hashpower will drop out. ## MIM estimation OK, what MIM do we expect in the long run? Is it going to be less than 50% anyway? We can expect that people will keep buying mining devices as long as it is profitable. Break-even condition: `R - C_e - P = 0`, where P is the price of a mining device, R is the revenue it generates over its lifetime, and C_e is the total cost of required electricity over its lifetime. In this case, `R = C_e + P`, and thus: MIM = 1 - C_e / (C_e + P) `f = C_e / P` is a ratio of the cost of electricity to the cost of hardware, `C_e = f * P`, and thus MIM = 1 - f * P / (f * P + P) = 1 - f / (f + 1) = 1 / (1 + f) MIM is less than 0.5 when f > 1. Computing f is somewhat challenging even for a concrete device, as it's useful lifetime is unknown. Let's do some guesstimation: Spondoolies Tech's SP35 Yukon unit consumes 3.5 KW and costs $4000. If it's useful lifetime is more than 2 years and a cost of KWh is $0.1, the total expenditures on electricity will be at least $6135, thus for this device we have `f > 6135/4000 > 1.5`. If other devices which will be sold on the market will have similar specs, we will have MIM lower than 0.5. (Well, no shit.) ## Conclusions Reward halving is a deficiency in Bitcoin's design, but there is some hope it won't be critical: in the equilibrium break-even situation hashpower drop is less than 50%. Hashrate might drop by more than 50% immediately after the halving (and before difficulty is updated), thus a combination of the halving and slow difficulty update pose a real threat.
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
_______________________________________________ Bitcoin-development mailing list Bitcoin-development@lists.sourceforge.net https://lists.sourceforge.net/lists/listinfo/bitcoin-development