http://online.wsj.com/articles/joel-mokyr-what-todays-economic-gloomsayers-are-missing-1407536487

> By
> Joel Mokyr
> Updated Aug. 8, 2014 6:22 p.m. ET
> There is nothing like a recession to throw economists into a despondent mood. 
> Much as happened in the late 1930s—when there was a fear of so-called secular 
> stagnation, or the absence of growth due to a dearth of investment 
> opportunities—many of my colleagues these days seem to believe that "sad days 
> are here again." The economic growth experienced through much of the 20th 
> century, they tell us, was fleeting. Our children will be no richer than we 
> are. The entry of millions of married women into the workforce and the huge 
> increase in college graduates that drove post-1945 growth were one-off boons. 
> Slow growth is here to stay.
> 
> What is wrong with this story? The one-word answer is "technology." The 
> responsibility of economic historians is to remind the world what things were 
> like before 1800. Growth was imperceptibly slow, and the vast bulk of the 
> population was so poor that a harvest failure would kill  millions. Almost 
> half the babies born died before reaching age 5, and those who made it to 
> adulthood were often stunted, ill and illiterate.
> 
> What changed this world was technological progress. Starting in the late 18th 
> century, innovations and advances in what was then called "the useful arts" 
> began improving life, first in Britain, then in the rest of Europe, and then 
> in much of the rest of the world.
> 
> Enlarge Image
> 
> A sample of graphene Corbis
> 
> Why did it happen? In brief: Science advanced. One reason science advanced so 
> rapidly is that technology provided the tools and instruments that allowed 
> "natural philosophers" (as they were known then) to study the physical world. 
> An example is the barometer. Invented by a student of Galileo's named 
> Torricelli in 1643, it showed the existence of atmospheric pressure. That 
> scientific insight spurred the development of the first steam engines (known 
> as atmospheric engines).
> 
> In 1800 another Italian, Alessandro Volta, invented the "pile"—the first 
> battery. It served primarily as a tool for chemical research, allowing 
> chemists to map out the newly discovered world of elements and compounds that 
> unleashed the chemical industries of the 19th century.
> 
> In that fashion technology pulled itself up by its bootstraps: An invention 
> in one area stimulated progress in another. The germ theory of disease and 
> the subsequent revolution in medical technology might never have occurred 
> without improved microscopes.
> 
> Compared with the tools we have today for scientific research, Galileo's look 
> like stone axes. We have far better microscopes and telescopes and barometers 
> today, and the digital codification of information has penetrated every 
> aspect of science. It has led to the reinvention of invention. Words like 
> "IT" or "communications" don't begin to express the scope of the change. Huge 
> searchable databanks, quantum chemistry simulation and highly complex 
> statistical analysis are only some of the tools that the digital age places 
> at science's disposal.
> 
> The consequences are everywhere, from molecular genetics to nanoscience to 
> research in Medieval poetry. Quantum computers, though still experimental, 
> promise to increase this power by orders of magnitude. As science moves into 
> new areas and solves problems that were not even imagined, inventors, 
> engineers and entrepreneurs are waiting in the wings to design new gizmos and 
> processes based on the new discoveries that will continue to improve our 
> lives.
> 
> In the speculation on what the new technologies will look like and do, robots 
> and artificial intelligence remain front and center, at once wished for (who 
> likes making beds?) and feared as job-killers. We haven't seen a fraction of 
> what is possible in information and communication technology. But the most 
> unexpected advances may come from less glamorous corners, such as material 
> science.
> 
> Materials are the core of our production. The terms Bronze and Iron Ages 
> signify their importance; the great era of technological progress between 
> 1870 and 1914 was wholly dependent on cheap and ever-better steel. But what 
> is happening to materials now is a leap far beyond any of the past, with new 
> resins, ceramics and entirely new solids designed in silico, (that is, on a 
> computer) developed at the nanotechnological level. These promise materials 
> that nature never dreamed of and that deliver custom-ordered properties in 
> hardness, resilience, elasticity and so on.
> 
> One example is graphene, a sheet of very thin carbon whose molecules can be 
> arranged to make it either the strongest or the most flexible material on 
> earth. It conducts electricity and heat better than any material ever 
> discovered. In the future graphene is likely to replace silicon in 
> transistors, solar cells and other applications we cannot yet imagine.
> 
> Genetic modification is another area of expanding frontiers. Plants will be 
> designed to fix nitrates in the soil or to absorb more carbon dioxide from 
> the atmosphere and that can adapt to more extreme temperatures and rainfall. 
> These could be our best defense against environmental  degradation, climate 
> change and other nasty side effects of earlier, cruder agricultural 
> techniques. "Nanobombs" that physically penetrate bacterial membranes are the 
> next weapon in mankind's never-ending war on microbes.
> 
> The breakthroughs are not "on the horizon." They are here. The economy may be 
> facing some headwinds, but the technological tailwind is more like a tornado. 
> Fasten your seat belts.
> 
> So: If everything is so good, why is everything so bad? Why the gloominess of 
> so many of my colleagues? Part of the story is that economists are trained to 
> look at aggregate statistics like GDP per capita and measure for things like 
> "factor productivity." These measures were designed for a steel-and-wheat 
> economy, not one in which information and data are the most dynamic sectors. 
> They mismeasure the contributions of innovation to the economy.
> 
> Many new goods and services are expensive to design, but once they work, they 
> can be copied at very low or zero cost. That means they tend to contribute 
> little to measured output even if their impact on consumer welfare is very 
> large. Economic assessment based on aggregates such as gross domestic product 
> will become increasingly misleading, as innovation accelerates. Dealing with 
> altogether new goods and services was not what these numbers were designed 
> for, despite heroic efforts by Bureau of Labor Statistics statisticians.
> 
> The aggregate statistics miss most of what is interesting. Here is one 
> example: If telecommuting or driverless cars were to cut the average time 
> Americans spend commuting in half, it would not show up in the national 
> income accounts—but it would make millions of Americans substantially better 
> off. Technology is not our enemy. It is our best hope. If you think rapid 
> technological change is undesirable, try secular stagnation.
> 
> Mr. Mokyr is professor of economics and history at Northwestern University. 
> His most recent book is "The Enlightened Economy: An Economic History of 
> Britain 1700-1850" (Yale, 2012)."


-- 
Kim Holburn
IT Network & Security Consultant
T: +61 2 61402408  M: +61 404072753
mailto:k...@holburn.net  aim://kimholburn
skype://kholburn - PGP Public Key on request 




_______________________________________________
Link mailing list
Link@mailman.anu.edu.au
http://mailman.anu.edu.au/mailman/listinfo/link

Reply via email to