> Date:          Fri, 22 Jun 2001 14:23:18 -0700
> From:          Michael Perelman <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>
> I don't know what the biggest risk is for capitalism: Third World
> upheavals, financial implosion, global warming, overcapacity, or
> resource constraints.  I think it would be very useful to think
> about how these various forces relate to each other.

Let's say, these crisis-symptoms all occur in a more amplified form 
because of, at root, the tendencies of overaccumulation/unevenness, 
right? I think the merits of my PhD advisor David Harvey's work (e.g. 
the newly reissued Limits to Capital) is the focus on the role of 
finance in crisis-displacement, and geopolitical processes that 
logically follow. (Finance displaces overaccumulated capital across 
time throught the credit mechanism--allowing consumption now, surplus 
extraction to pay for it later--and finance moves money across the 
world in a twinkling of an eye, so the geographical devalorisation 
can occur wherever resistance is weakest.) 

A few more words on Jim's post, and then I ask comrades to help us 
on some Zimbabwe deliberations.

> Date:          Fri, 22 Jun 2001 18:19:57 -0700
> From:          Jim Devine <[EMAIL PROTECTED]>
> Unfortunately for Marx, his volume III theory of the rising organic 
> composition of capital doesn't work very well on either a theoretical or a 
> practical level. Not only can the capitalists compensate for any rise in 
> the organic composition of capital by cutting wages relative to 
> productivity (raising the rate of surplus-value),

Jim, there are always countervailing tendencies (absolute/relative 
s.v. extraction), of which I think the most important since the 
current int'l slowdown in accumulation began three decades or so ago, 
has been the temporal/spatial *displacement* of the devalorisation of 
overaccumuled capital. Third World lending has been one vehicle 
(even if not, in the whole scheme of things, a particularly large one 
in volume terms... but we've really felt it down here!).

Consider, for instance, the Suter/Eichengreen studies of financial 
crashes: every 50 years like clockwork since 1820s, involving 1/3 of 
all nation-states (the WB's 2000 Global Finance report actually 
promotes the financial-Kwave theory, I guess because Stiglitz still 
had his hand in and Eichengreen refused to draw the logical 
conclusions). It seems that the big difference during the 1980s was 
the concentrated power of the WB/IMF--as cops for NY/London/Frankfurt 
banks--to NOT ALLOW the devalorisation of financial capital by 
instead rescheduling debt (Nyerere and Castro failed to get the 
debtors' cartel up and running).

But the point here is that this process of displacing the 
overaccumulation crisis South didn't solve it. Racing to repay 
unpayable debt, the Third World glutted most raw material and light 
mfg. markets. So the displacement -- the recent spatio-temporal 
countervailing tendencies Marx did not really foresee or theorise -- 
simply means that the overaccumulation problem grows worse, right?

>  but any crisis that 
> occurs purges imbalances from the system, destroying capital and allowing 
> accumulation to recover -- to drive itself into crisis once again. 

A matter of the balance of class forces, right? Including territorial 
struggles? So, that's why helping to more surgically identify the 
pockets of resistance and empower them--instead of comrade Chris' 
utopian global-regulatory strategy--becomes ever more crucial. To 
link the pockets of resistance obviously also calls for the need for 
solidarity--the globalisation of people (not of capital or state 
functions, which will overwhelm us if they maintain their 
current international capacities, without nation-states reigning in 
capital, e.g., through a new round of exchange controls).

> Even this doesn't inevitably lead to capitalism's demise. Instead, it 
> encourages collective solutions, i.e., the monopolization of markets and 
> the rise in the role of the state. The last time capitalism had a gigantic 
> Crisis -- the 1930s -- it encouraged the rise of state solutions, from 
> social democracy to fascism, with the U.S. New Deal in the middle, on a 
> national level. The next Crisis will likely see its solution on the global 
> level, as seen in embryonic form in the Kyoto accords. (Somehow, the 
> Bushwackers aren't anti-abortion on _this_ issue.) If the current US 
> slowdown turns into a global depression, it encourages further development 
> of collective control, perhaps the creation of a global Fed. "Human 
> ingenuity" would show up in the form of a New Bretton Woods conference, a 
> global-statist version of social democracy or fascism or something 
> in-between. This eventually would allow the re-establishment of capitalist 
> accumulation ....

Why are you so sure, comrade Jim, about global "solutions" 
(restructuring of relations of production)? The old familiar 
intercapitalist-competition plus bloc-formation process plus 
geo-military conflict seems just as likely, doesn't it?

Let's return to geopolitical problems associated with the economic 
crisis, because I still think that, whether we like it or hate it 
(yeah Doug, we know where you stand!), the nation-state (and maybe 
subsequently the region) is the single most important unit of control 
for defending territorial alliances of those social forces resisting 
the devalorisation of, e.g., NY financial capital... via, 
logistically/mechanically, delinking from the most destructive 
circuits of global K. 

Actually, that's one reason Zimbabwe's quagmire is so fascinating 
right now.

This is draft and not for circulation, possibly to go into Z, but 
I'd love to get a sense of whether the economic argumentation 
associated with aggressive debt management is convincing...

                         Zimbabwe's lurch
                    towards a pauper's burial?

  by Patrick Bond
  (Bvumba mountains, Zimbabwe, 19 June)

  Last year, I spent June rambling the roads of
  Zimbabwe's Eastern Highlands mountains.
  The human warmth of the Shona people and
  physical beauty of the rural landscape are
  world-class. My job should have been inspiring: 
  election-observation for a regional team trying
  to document whether the parliamentary vote was
  free and fair.

  But last June was a tragic time (1), because
  of the decay of Robert Mugabe's once-
  liberatory nationalist politics. Exhausted,
  corrupted, desperate and prone to violence,
  the Zimbabwe African National Union
  (ZanuPF) barely held off a challenge by the
  nine-month old Movement for Democratic
  Change (MDC), winning just over half the
  120 contested parliamentary seats.

  Mugabe's socialist vision evaporated long
  ago, although he calls forth radical rhetoric
  periodically to confuse matters. "Talk left,
  act right" is the chosen formula, as
  Zanu(PF) continually seeks to revive popular
  memory of a time when the party was
  indeed a fish in the sea of the masses, while
  concurrently repressing those who protest
  vigorously from the Left.

  In early June, for example, Zimbabwe
  National Students' Union president
  Nkululeko Sibanda was tortured by
  Mugabe's secret police, the Central
  Intelligence Organisation, after the CIO
  accused him of "working with the MDC to
  topple the government." Sibanda is leading
  widespread student protest over unaffordable
  university fees and privatisation of campus
  facilities and services.

  But the topic of the gloomy present was
  replaced, during a recent weekend visit, by the
  question of Zimbabwe's very uncertain
  financial future. I flew two hours from
  Jo'burg to Harare, drove east for four hours
  and joined a dozen civil society strategists in
  a sunny, wintertime seminar up in the
  mountains bordering Mozambique.

  We gathered to debate the country's most
  durable economic problem, the buildup of
  foreign and domestic debt: $5 billion and
  $1.5 billion, respectively. Zimbabwe is
  considered only "moderately" indebted by
  the World Bank, but the burden of
  repayment is so brutal that Mugabe finally
  said no around a year ago.

  For two NGO activists, Davie Malungisa of
  the Zimbabwe Coalition on Debt and
  Development (Zimcodd) and Eunice
  Mafundikwa of the African Network on
  Debt and Development (Afrodad), the
  protests they joined at the spring meetings of
  the World Bank and IMF over the past two
  years took on new meaning as we reviewed
  a new debt study. The report's author,
  Masimba Manyanya, was formerly a chief
  economist for Mugabe's finance ministry but
  quit to join the trade union movement in
  1999.

  All three thirty-somethings are progressive
  professionals who, while differing on party-
  political affiliations, share the concern that a
  national debate over economic policy has not
  yet even really begun, and that resolving the
  debt crisis has to be central.

  Zimcodd was founded last year by the main
  organisations in the social justice, church,
  women's, NGO and trade union movements.
  "Debt is already genocidal in Zimbabwe,"
  insists Malungisa, "because so few of our
  urgent social priorities can be met. The last
  budget saw a 26% crash in health spending,
  for instance."

  Indeed, debt peonage couldn't have come at
  a worse time, given that life expectancy is
  falling into the thirties because of
  HIV/AIDS. By cutting living standards so
  dramatically, structural adjustment
  contributed to the opportunistic infections
  and breakdown of the state health system
  through which AIDS flourishes.

  Continues Malungisa, "Debt is a threat
  against which all Zimbabweans can and must
  unite. Otherwise we face a pauper's burial.
  Zimcodd is even joining the World Bank Bonds
  Boycott campaign to drive this point home
  where it counts: Jim Wolfensohn's wallet."

  Malungisa and the others are far out ahead
  of the political curve here. In next April's
  presidential elections, the MDC will
  probably win, vindicating the political
  courage of its founders, the Zimbabwe
  Congress of Trade Unions and its
  supporters, the mass of the urban poor, the
  youth, and the working-classes.

  But here arises another hurdle. In February
  2000, the impoverished young party also
  welcomed big business, white farmers and
  even overseas supporters with imperialist
  designs, who gave enthusiastic financial and
  logistical support once the MDC defeated
  Mugabe by 55% to 45% in a referendum
  over a new constitution.

  If the MDC becomes the ruling party, it is
  likely to be pressured into adopting hard-
  core neoliberal economic policies (2). But
  that won't do the country any good, given
  the neoliberal roots of the current political
  tumult.

  The disaster of neoliberalism in Zimbabwe
  is not surprising news, no doubt (3). But it's
  worth returning to the debt issue because
  Harare has adopted some interesting
  emergency policies which any genuinely
  progressive government would want to
  consider amplifying.

  In particular, three recent government
  decisions are considered insane by
  conventional economists: running such a
  relaxed monetary policy since January that
  interest rates (15%) are at least 45% below
  the inflation rate; pegging the currency at 55
  Zimdollars to one US$ when the black
  market rate is at least double that; and
  servicing foreign debt only haltingly.

  We need to look at these objectively, and the
  post-independence context is crucial. My
  own theory is that the foreign debt burden
  and the failure of the 1991-95 structural
  adjustment programme designed by the
  World Bank together drove Mugabe around
  the bend, in classical nationalist zig-zag
  mode, in mid-1997.

  Ironically, in 1995, the Bank had judged
  Mugabe's turn to neoliberalism as "highly
  satisfactory" (the highest possible ranking).
  Most macroeconomic, sector and financial
  objectives were "substantially" achieved
  (again, the highest mark), said an official
  Bank evaluation.

  In reality, the formerly well-balanced
  economy became deindustrialised and
  massively indebted. The social wage
  collapsed as budget cuts bit deep. Gender,
  race and class inequity soared. And
  Zimbabwe became much more vulnerable to
  international shocks.

  Over the period 1990-95, gross domestic
  product fell by a fifth, from $8.50 billion to
  $6.80 billion, as foreign debt soared 55%,
  from $3.25 billion to $5.05 billion,
  according to the World Bank's own debt
  tables.

  Meanwhile, grassroots protest was relatively
  erratic and easily contained. Finally in 1996-
  97, trade unions, civil servants and
  farmworkers all challenged Mugabe from the
  left.

  Simultaneously, Mugabe was berated by
  several thousand of his former comrades
  from the 1960s-70s struggle who had
  received none of the spoils of liberation. In
  late 1997 he struck a deal with these war
  veterans, giving them a few thousand dollars
  as a pension in exchange for allegiance.

  Within a year, some of the most aggressive
  war vets had become a quasi-paramilitary
  force, harassing trade unionists and others
  who staged periodic strikes. (And within two
  and half years, the war vets had staged
  bloody occupations of more than 1,000
  white-owned farms, which aided Mugabe's
  2000 election campaign by reviving
  nationalist memories of the need to rid
  settlers from the best land.)

  But the pincer squeeze on Mugabe was
  tightening hard during the late 1990s, as
  local democracy activists and international
  financiers made contradictory demands. In
  1998, the last full year Mugabe authorised
  repayment of the foreign debt, there was
  only one other country in the world (Brazil)
  paying higher debt-servicing charges in
  relation to its ability to earn exports. (That
  fact, embedded deep in the World Bank's
  latest Global Development Finance report,
  has never been reported in Zimbabwe.)

  After several years of spending $650 million
  annually on debt servicing, Zimbabwe
  coughed up $981 million in 1998, against
  just $2.57 billion earned from exports, an
  untenable ratio of 38%. But even though
  over the period 1994-98, Zimbabwe had
  paid $910 million more in debt servicing
  than it received in new loans, the debt
  actually rose over those five years from
  $4.54 to $4.72 billion. (At the same time,
  grant aid fell by half, from a peak of $310
  million in 1995 to $150 million in 1998.)

  Because of repayment scheduling and the
  tyranny of compound interest, Mugabe found
  himself sliding backwards on the debt
  treadmill. Finally in early 1999, he jumped
  off, refusing to pay the IMF and Bank,
  thereby joining a list of rogue-financial states
  like Yemen, Iraq and the Democratic
  Republic of the Congo (DRC).

  The costs of short-term IMF "help" now
  finally outweighed the benefits. Those costs
  included three main conditions attached to
  $200 million in IMF credit promised in
  1999. Mugabe was ordered to immediately
  reverse the only redistributive policies he
  had adopted in a long time, namely a) a ban
  on holding foreign exchange accounts in
  local banks (which immediately halted the
  easiest form of capital flight by the country's
  elites); b) a 100% customs tax on imported
  luxury goods; and c) price controls on staple
  foods in the wake of several urban riots.

  Mugabe resisted the IMF, and was cut off
  after the first small tranche of the loan. But
  hatred of the Zanu(PF) leader continued to
  grow in the cities when he deployed 10,000
  troops to the DRC war, partly as an act of
  solidarity against the US-backed
  Ugandan/Rwandan invasion of the east of
  the DRC.

  However, Zimbabwe's intervention was soon
  unveiled as a ghastly mercenary-style
  arrangement with the soon-to-be-assassinated
  Laurent Kabila. The deal allows Harare's
  military and state elites to loot the wretched
  DRC's cobalt, copper and diamonds.

  Tellingly, the IMF permitted Mugabe to
  continue his DRC adventure at a crucial
  negotiating stage in mid-1999: "We have had
  assurances" about Mugabe's plans for
  further deployment, an IMF source told
  Agence France Press. "If there is budgetary
  overspending, there will be cuts in other
  budget sectors."

  In other words, health, education and other
  badly-defended sectors would suffer more
  pressure on behalf of Mugabe's military
  cronies.

  These are some of the reasons Malungisa
  says Zimbabwe's foreign debt should be
  considered "odious," not subject to
  repayment by a democratic successor. 

  The foreign loans that Robert Mugabe
  signed for during the 1980s and early 1990s
  backed the ruling Zanu(PF) party's worst,
  most self-destructive tendencies, and were
  contracted in a non-transparent manner
  contrary to society's interests.

  A full audit of Zimbabwe's foreign debt
  would reveal systemic failure. Not only did
  loan conditionality throughout the post-
  independence period screw the poor. The
  credits also created space for degeneracy by
  elites, who used the hard currency to import
  inappropriate luxury goods and unsustainable
  machinery, to be repaid by the future
  generations.

  But the days of easy foreign credit ended by
  the mid-1990s, so government turned
  increasingly to domestic borrowing. The
  interest bill on local and foreign loans was
  projected by the finance minister late last
  year to reach a phenomenal 48% of the
  annual government budget--of about $2
  billion--in 2001. (And that's even after
  Mugabe absurdly projected privatisation
  revenues of $200 million this year, a
  promise which no one believes he'll keep
  since parastatal corporations are vital to his
  political patronage system.)

  The only light I see at the end of the debt
  tunnel is that whatever party is ruling after
  the April 2002 election might, perhaps, learn
  from present circumstances that it's ok to
  default.

  Having failed to make key foreign debt
  payments since 1999, the government is now
  $600 million in arrears. Zimbabwe finance
  minister Simba Makoni promised the World
  Bank and IMF he'd spend about that sum
  this year to repay foreign loans, but it seems
  that Mugabe won't let him.

  Makoni, who is considered a reliably
  neoliberal technocrat, conceded to the World
  Economic Forum meeting in Durban a
  earlier this month, "We are committed to
  fulfilling these obligations, but it's clear that
  our economy is in no state to generate
  sufficient funds to clear these arrears."

  Even if the debt was serviced, the IMF's
  Stanley Fischer told Makoni that there won't
  be any new loans until Mugabe fulfills a set
  of new conditions, including getting war vets
  off the commercial farms they occupied last
  year.

  With the prospect of net repayment outflow,
  Mugabe appears justified in ignoring IMF
  repayment demands and instead hijacking a
  portion of foreign exchange earned by
  tobacco and other exports, for emergency
  purchases, including fuel. Even so, the price
  of petrol, which has been in very short
  supply this year, was raised overnight by
  70% last Thursday. (A two-day general
  strike has been called by the unions for the
  beginning of July to reverse the increase.)

  An interesting geopolitical/economic
  question immediately arises: in the wake of
  having effectively defaulted on foreign debt
  and now facing chronic foreign exchange
  shortages, what further material punishment
  can the world economy impose on Mugabe?

  Aid has been withdrawn by most donors, or
  redirected to civil society. Trade sanctions
  proposed by Jesse Helms--which are not
  supported by the Zimbabwean opposition--
  would in any case not bite much harder.

  The only country that could really finally
  push Zimbabwe over the economic cliff if it
  wanted to, is South Africa, through which
  most exports and imports flow. But Thabo 
  Mbeki has repeatedly come to Mugabe's aid
  in various ways (although it appears that
  Pretoria is now finally ready to recognise the
  Movement for Democratic Change as the
  likely next government).

  In sum, Zimbabwe is down but not out.
  Periodic shortages--including essential drugs
  and California-style electricity load-
  shedding--contribute to the misery of daily
  life.

  Government justifies maintaining an official
  exchange rate half that which is available on
  the black market, on grounds it can't afford
  to pay for vital imports at the market rate.
  The private sector reverts to the higher rate
  for its own imports, while government
  insists on exchanging a quarter of all the hard
  currency revenues earned by exporters, but at the
  lower rate.

  And then there's the 15% rate of interest
  government decided to pay domestic
  creditors for short-term loans, at a time
  inflation is roaring above 60%. The state
  forces institutional investors to purchase
  Treasury Bills, and in the process spreads
  the pain of debt payback to relatively
  wealthier savers who get a negative rate of
  return, after discounting inflation.

  The upside of the negative real interest rate
  is that only half the amount that was
  anticipated (nearly $1 billion) will be
  required to service domestic debt this year.
  And productive investment can be financed
  more cheaply than at any time in the last
  decade, for those very rare businesses
  interested in expanding during the midst of
  depression.

  But because institutional investors aren't
  getting the return on interest-earning assets
  that they want, they've pushed
  unprecedented funding into the Zimbabwe
  Stock Exchange, which was the fastest rising
  in the world over the last year. And the
  stocks they're buying are absurdly
  overvalued, so they'll lose again when
  normalcy returns and the market crashes.

  These contradictory policies aren't tenable
  over the medium-term. But if the MDC is
  ruling Zimbabwe next year it may have to
  drop the overall neoliberal formula for one
  simple reason. The debt has become so
  oppressive that there is only one way out:
  defaulting the foreign lenders and cheating
  the local institutional investors (and by
  extension savers, including some workers
  whose pension funds are now shrinking
  quickly).

  This leaves three other residual challenges:

       * redirecting financial capital which is
       now flooding away from interest-bearing
       assets into the stock market;
       * protecting the pensions of ordinary
       workers; and 
       * shielding the poor from inflation, for
       instance through well-conceived subsidies
       on basic needs.

  Even if he acted on these forcefully (which
  he won't), it's hard to envisage Mugabe holding
  on to power, no matter how much he
  intimidates the rural electorate to again vote
  Zanu(PF). Over the past few weeks, he lost
  three key nationalist militants--defense
  minister Moven Mahachi, employment
  minister Border Gezi and war vets leader
  Chengerai Hitler Hunzvi--in unexpected
  deaths (two accidental car crashes and
  illness, respectively). Rumours have
  circulated that a Zanu(PF) military clique is
  anxious to take over, possibly via a coup, if
  Mugabe continues to falter.

  Other support is also waning for the 77-year
  old president. Controversial information
  minister Jonathan Moyo, on whom Mugabe
  has come to rely for spindoctoring, had his
  wings clipped this month by cabinet
  colleagues. The judiciary still leans against
  the ruling party. And a string of smaller
  elections coming up will tire Mugabe in the
  run-up to the presidential race.

  But matters are not much rosier for the
  opposition. Former trade union leader
  Morgan Tsvangirai is likely to be the
  MDC's candidate for president, although
  Mugabe has him awaiting trial for
  threatening violence last September, which
  potentially could disqualify Tsvangirai from
  the election. And even if the MDC wins
  next April, it would not control parliament
  immediately, and would have an enormous
  struggle to establish political stability in such
  a divided society.

  The biggest struggle, though, looks to be
  about ten months away: if the MDC can
  extricate itself from the grip of big money
  and orthodox economic ideas (and right
  now, I'd bet no), how would they slay the
  debt monster? Tsvangirai, after all, said in
  an uncharacteristically slippery way last
  year, "I still hate the World Bank and IMF,
  like I hate my doctor."

  If the MDC can't shake off neoliberalism,
  will civil society groups offer as vibrant
  advocacy on socio-economic rights as they
  do today on political and civil rights?

  Late at night, next to the blazing Bvumba
  fireplace as our seminar came to an end,
  Davie Malungisa, Eunice Mafundikwa,
  Masimba Manyanya and the other folks
  chatting over local beers swore that in
  coming months, they'll be at the forefront of
  linking Zimbabwe's best grassroots activists
  to the international anti-neoliberal
  movement.

  (For those readers who want to see a
  democratic Zimbabwe without the burden of
  a $5 billion foreign debt, Zimcodd and the
  Jubilee South movement--http://aidc.org.za-- 
  promote 100% cancellation. The best ways
  to help out are to join Davie, Eunice,
  Masimba and other Zimbabweans protesting
  at the Washington annual meetings of the
  World Bank/IMF in early October, and to
  support the World Bank Bonds Boycott:
  http://www.worldbankboycott.org)


  (1) ZNet, Commentary, 6/22/00:
  "Zimbabwe's Election: Who's Right, Who's
  Left?"

  (2) I address this dilemma more fully in the
  Journal of World Systems Research, current
  issue (http://csf.colorado.edu/jwsr).

  (3) ZNet Commentary, 4/30/00:
  "Zimbabwe's Crisis Showcases Reasons for
  IMF/World Bank Protest" 

Reply via email to