Unhealthy Societies

1999-12-22 Thread Ian Ritchie

FYI
 --
 From: Keith Rankin[SMTP:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
 
 Did you see the Tuesday documentary on TV1 last night? It was called "The
 Great Leveller" and is based on the book _Unhealthy Societies_ by British
 economic historian Richard Wilkinson.
 
 Wilkinson has shown through painstaking research that the predominant
 determinant of a nation's life expectance is economic inequality. People
 who
 are RELATIVELY disadvantaged within their societies have a much increased
 chance of dying prematurely of especially heart disease; ie relative
 poverty
 is actually more of a problem than is absolute poverty. After relative
 affluence, the second way to live a long life is through socialisation,
 including shared adversity. Thus people who lived through World War 2 had
 much higher life expectancies than their parents. [I have been convinced
 for
 a long time that people born after 1955 will live shorter lives on average
 than their parents, and inequality will be the main cause.]
 
 Re heart disease, inequality accounted for 60% of deaths, whereas factors
 relating to diet, smoking and exercise together only accounted for 40% of
 deaths.
 
 The campaign against poverty and inequality is actually much more
 important
 than most of us realise. The solution is not to place most of us into
 subservient jobs.
 
 The reasoning is that stress levels are very high in people at the bottom
 of
 their pecking orders at work and elsewhere. The reasoning suggests that
 people facing poverty traps - ie unable to use their own initiative to
 improve their situation - are more susceptable to premature death than are
 people who are simply poor and live in communities in which poverty is
 normal.
 
 Interestingly, my own research into the Great Depression in NZ and
 Australia
 bears out similar points. In Adelaide in the GD, negative social
 indicators
 were highest at the onset of depression and during the recovery. These
 were
 the years when the victims stood out from their peers as victims. Crime 
 suicide rates in NZ tell a similar story.
 
 Books : Social Sciences PicturePicturePicturePictureUnhealthy
 Societies: The Afflictions of Inequality PictureAuthor:Richard G.
 Wilkinson (University of Sussex)
 PictureAvailability:  Usually shipped within 10 working days
 PictureNZ$76.46 
 PictureNZ$64.99 
 PicturePicturePicturePaperback - 272 pages
 12/09/96
 ISBN:0415092353 PictureNotes:   * Taylor  Francis Books Ltd  * Size
 (216 x 138) mm  * Illustrations PicturePictureDescription 
 Among the developed countries it is not the richest societies which have
 the best health, but those which have the smallest income differences
 between rich and poor. Inequality and relative poverty have absolute
 effects: they increase death rates. But why? How can smaller income
 differences raise average life expectancy? Using examples from the USA,
 Britain, Japan and Eastern Europe, and bringing together evidence from the
 social and medical sciences, this text offers an explanation. Healthy,
 egalitarian societies are more socially cohesive. They have a stronger
 community life and suffer fewer of the corrosive effects of inequality. As
 well as inequality weakening the social fabric, damaging health and
 increasing crime rates, the text aims to show that social cohesion is
 crucial to the quality of life. The contrast between the material success
 and social failure of modern societies marks an imbalance which needs
 attention. The relationship between health and equality suggests that
 important social needs will go unmet without a larger measure of social
 and distributive justice. 
 
 from Amazon.com
 Unhealthy Societies : The Afflictions of Inequality 
 by Richard Wilkinson 
 
 PicturePictureShopping with us is 100% safe. Guaranteed. 
 (We'll set one up for you) 
 View my Wish List
 List Price: $27.99
 Our Price: $25.19
 You Save: $2.80 (10%)
 
 
 Availability: On Order; usually ships within 1-2 weeks.
 Picture: HollyHoliday Note: This item may not arrive by December 24.
 Visit Gift Ideas to find items we can ship today. 
 
 
 Paperback (February 1997) 
 Routledge; ISBN: 0415092353 
 Amazon.com Sales Rank: 48,828 
 Avg. Customer Review: Picture: 5 out of 5 stars 
 Number of Reviews: 2
 
 
 



Info on welfare to work

1999-12-16 Thread Ian Ritchie

Can you help with leads, info etc?
 --
 From: Deborah Tucker[SMTP:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
 
 My main research work that I'm just starting on, (working under Ian
 Shirley), both to finish the Masters and possibly for the Ministry of
 Social
 Policy,  is a comparative study on the interface between benefits and
 work,
 looking at North America, the UK, Ireland, Australia, NZ, Sweden, Denmark,
 Germany, the Netherlands, Canada and Finland.  It will look at the range
 of
 benefit types in each of the countries, how they are operationalised, then
 how the respective governments are responding in terms of welfare-to-work
 initiatives.
 
You
 may know of some useful contacts or websites.  
 Many thanks,
 Deborah
 
 



FW: Eu Full Employment Thematic Network

1999-11-15 Thread Ian Ritchie

FYI
 --
 From:
 [EMAIL PROTECTED][SMTP:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
  The website of the Thematic Network on Full Employment for Europe at 
  www.barkhof.uni-bremen.de/kua/memo/europe/tser/ may be of interest to
 
  members of this list.
  
  The Network is an international group of European economists, funded 
  by the European Union under its Targeted Socio-Economic Research 
  Programme, whose purpose is to challenge the present neoliberal 
  dominance of employment policy.
  
  The website has details of the members and programme of the network, 
  together with many papers available for downloading.
  
  David Webster
  Glasgow City Housing
  
  [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 



Business contributions to the community

1999-11-14 Thread Ian Ritchie

I am seeking ideas and information
I have been making representations to the City Council (Palmerston North,
New Zealand) on the need to update their employment and economic development
policies, from the general and meaningless to something more specific, along
the lines of employers more likely to stay in town, those that pay good
wages, are involved in activities that are sustainable etc.
When a new business comes to town one of the few things highlighted is the
number of jobs it will create. This seems to be a key measure of
desirability, presumably the wages that will be paid, ie increased spending
power in the community. But if the jobs are Mc jobs they may be of little
value.
I remember from a report a friend produced, but neither of us can locate,
from a visit to Chicago where a group had researched the vaccuum cleaner
effect of a suprermarket - owned elsewhere, it took many millions out of the
community.
The damage casinos do is getting some close scrutiny.
Can you help me with suggestions, references etc on ways to look at the
contribution individual businesses make to a community etc 
Many thanks
Ian

http://www.geocities.com/Athens/Academy/3142/IR/#pag



John Tomlinson's 6th U/E conf paper

1999-10-06 Thread Ian Ritchie

FYI

The Importance of Trust

Paper given at the 6th National Conference on Unemployment, University of
Newcastle, 2324 September 1999.
John Tomlinson

Abstract

The major problem facing Australian people without paid employment (or
sufficient paid work) is not the absence of work but the absence of a decent
income support mechanism. 

There are many way of providing sufficient paid employment to all who desire
it. Identifying ways to surmount the obstacles to full employment are by no
means intellectually challenging.  Langmore and Quiggan (1994) set out a
detailed blueprint to reduce unemployment to 3%. Governments, since 1974,
have failed in this important task. The last Labor Government at least
presented a coherent plan to train unemployed people and reduce the level of
unemployment to 5% by the end of this century (Keating 1994). 

In this paper I concentrate upon ideological impediments to policies which
would ensure both full employment and a decent universal income support
system because there are no economic obstacles which would preclude such
social advances (Saunders 1995, Rankin 1999). 

There are underlying reasons successive Australian Governments have rejected
both full employment and decent income support. The on going debate about: 
*   inclusion versus exclusion,
*   the fiscal drain of what the Labor and Liberal Parties call
"dependency",
*   universalism versus targeted benefits (thread bare safety-nets for
the "deserving"),
*   compulsion and punishment, 
*   neglect versus liberation, and 
*   the confused dependency rhetoric and moral jeopardy arguments 
is sucking this nation into a cesspool of policy busyness rather than a
determination to get on with the business of sorting out both income support
and the labour market.  The interplay of these debates has resulted in the
hegemonic economic fundamentalist preoccupation with small government
leading in turn to the loss of commercial opportunities and wasted social
opportunities.

I seek to follow on from the paper I gave at the 5th National Conference on
Unemployment ( NZUBI Web site) to further tease out the reason we fail to
trust ourselves (and others) and why this leads in turn to our failure to
introduce an unconditional basic income.

http://www.geocities.com/~ubinz/JT/



re Genuine Progress

1999-10-06 Thread Ian Ritchie

FYI
You've seen the headlines, "GDP Up 5.4%." Good news, right? Not really. The
gross domestic product simply adds up all the money we spend, and calls the
results economic growth. Yet for years, economists, policymakers, reporters,
and the public have relied on the GDP as a shorthand indicator of progress. 

In 1995, Redefining Progress created a more accurate measure of progress,
called the Genuine Progress Indicator (GPI). It starts with the same
accounting framework as the GDP, but then makes some crucial distinctions:
It adds in the economic contributions of household and volunteer work, but
subtracts factors such as crime, pollution, and family breakdown. We
continue to update the GPI on a yearly basis to document a more truthful
picture of economic progress. 

http://www.rprogress.org/progsum/nip/gpi/gpi_main.html

also some excellent papers by Clive Hamilton of the Australia Institute who
did the GPI for Australia and visited NZ recently

Papers by Clive Hamilton (see also the Australia Institute site):
New Measures of Sustainability; the Genuine Progress Indicator for
Australia, 20 November 1997
Economic Growth and Social Decline, Australian Quarterly May-June 1998
Economic Growth: The Dark Side of the Australian Dream, 24 February 1999
on
http://www.geocities.com/~ubinz/IR/IRlinks.html(top half)



re the plight of the middle class

1999-08-23 Thread Ian Ritchie

FYI
Keith Rankin's Thursday Column Whither the Bourgeoisie?

We frequently hear these days about the plight of the middle class, or the
middle classes. But who are the middle classes? Are they simply those people
(or households?) who earn between the median income and the 90th or 95th
percentile? Can we really regard salaried persons as middle class? (After
all, salaries started out as stipends of salt paid to soldiers.)

Historically, the bourgeoisie were urban capitalists: merchants, financiers,
self-employed professionals, manufacturers. The middle classes were
entrepreneurs; they worked for profit, not wages. They came to be seen as
dour, because - unlike the upper (landed) and lower classes - they (being
insecure, with less tangible assets than land) saved like crazy. Because
they ploughed their savings back into their enterprises, or into others'
enterprises, they were seen by the classical economists as the agents
(although not the ultimate beneficiaries) of economic growth.

The classes were defined according to the sources of persons' incomes: land
rent (upper class), profit (middle class) and wages or peasant farming
(lower class). The class system arose because most people received all their
income from a single "fund" (eg the "wage fund").

(You could even define whole nations according to this class system.
Countries like Australia, New Zealand, Argentina and Saudi Arabia, which
derived their income mainly from land, were upper class. Western Europe was
middle class. The Third World was lower class.)

Classical economics predicted that the lower classes would be something of a
reserve army of labour (in perpetual oversupply), while the middle class
capitalists would make the key investments. The upper classes would sit back
and collect the rent, eventually leaving everyone else in penury. As late as
the 1950s, this class division seemed to make sense, both for households and
for nations.

The class system went awry with the emergence of a salaried professional
class, and the replacement of proprietorial and partnership businesses with
the corporate business sector. "Businessmen" became managers. By the 1970s,
the social elite, in fulfilment of Joseph Schumpeter's predictions in 1945
(Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy), were working for wages. (Could any of
us imagine Jane Austen's social elite being employees?)

So, when we muse over the plight of the middle classes, are we musing about
the future of professional employees? Or are we musing about
entrepreneurship? Will those in the vanguard of the brave new knowledge
economies be employees of corporate organisations? Or will they be
electronically connected individuals selling their ideas to the highest
bidders?

Maybe we should bury the class system as a relic of the fading millennium.
The era of the highly paid full-lifetime employee is dying, if not dead.
Those 40-somethings who identify with that kind of career path, and who have
made financial commitments on the expectation of fulltime careers with ever
rising salaries, really do feel a sense of dread. Their perceptions of their
standing in society are determined by both the particular professions that
they are in, and the size of their salary packages. Although their social
status is displayed through conspicuous consumption, their social status
means much more to them than does the mere consumption of goods and
services.

The irony of the present times is that economic circumstances are propelling
them from elite working class towards something more closely resembling the
nineteenth century middle class, with all the insecurities that that
implies.

The key difference is that our worried salarymen will not lose all of their
security. They will not end up in a debtors' prison if their incomes fall in
Dickensian fashion from "20s 6d" to "19/6d" while their expenses remain at
"£1". We have already come to live from multiple income streams.

It is now normal for families to derive their incomes from a variety of
sources; some from wages/salaries, some from profits, some from
rents/interest/benefits (and some from crime). The class system ceases to
have meaning when we no longer depend on income from a single class fund.

The class system vanished:

1.. with the multiple-income household becoming the norm. Many people
receiving entrepreneurial income have partners who receive wage income. 2..
with individuals increasingly working through varieties of contracts, many
of which are much closer to customer-supplier than employer-employee
relationships. An individual with two or more jobs is not unusual. At least
one of those "jobs" might involve some creative activity that might yield a
substantial profit but more likely will not. 3.. with the creation of the
welfare state, and its evolution into a welfare society. Beneficiaries are
analogous to the landlords of the ancien regime. Benefits are paid out of a
social wage fund that represents a return on all our forms of collective
capital: our 

New Zealand Employment Summit

1999-08-09 Thread Ian Ritchie

The Proceedings of the Employment Summit which was held in Palmerston North,
New Zealand, on 30 March are now available on the Web.

http://www.geocities.com/~ubinz/IR/1999summit/ProcCover.html#e

As Steve Maharey, the local MP, said on the day, the Summit was the place to
be for people interested in employment issues at the local level because the
forum included the cream of workers in this field in the country.

Several groups around the country have been very interested in the Summit,
particularly with a view to running one of their own, said Ian Ritchie, one
of the organising group. The Proceedings will give a lot of ideas and
practical suggestions as to what communities around New Zealand can do.

As well as the papers and discussions from the day, a number of other papers
have been included which add to the usefulness of the collection and
together with the Background Papers published earlier, provide a valuable
resource for local, employment rich, economic development.

For further information refer to:
http://www.geocities.com/~ubinz/IR/1999summit/sum.html



When our working lives end at 45

1999-08-05 Thread Ian Ritchie

FYI

When our working lives end at 45

DAVID THOMSON looks at trends in age group employment and suggests that
people in their later 40s and 50s will soon have to find something else to
do.

Dialogue, NZ Herald, 5 August 1999
 

Paid work past about age 45 is vanishing fast. This change of the past 20
years has been huge and relentless, touches all levels of society, spreads
right across the developed world and shows few signs of halting, let alone
reversing.

And if present trends continue, then within a decade a third of all New
Zealand men by their later 40s will be "retired" (without significant
prospects of getting paid work again) and half of them by their mid-50s.
Even fewer women will have substantial paid work - perhaps 40 per cent at
their mid-50s.

Consider just how deeply we are already into this "post-work world." Until
the 1970s, 96 in every 100 men had fulltime paid work through their from
their 20s to their early 50s: only then did employment fall off.

Using data from the population census, in which fulltime work is 20 or more
hours a week, we find that by 1996 the proportion of men in fulltime work
was below 80 per cent at every age - 77 per cent for those in their later
40s, 65 per cent in their later 50s and 40 per cent in their early 60s. Only
a few per cent more had some part-time work.

Moreover, each successive birth cohort now begins paid work (and earning)
later in life, reaches its employment peak at a lower and earlier point and
sees its work fall off sooner and faster than for any predecessors.

For those born in the early 1950s, for instance, full-time employment peaked
at 90 per cent in their later 20s and was down to 75 per cent by their early
40s.

Among Maori and Pacific Islanders it is all happening sooner and faster
still. Where 96 per cent of Maori men had full- time work at age 40 in the
1960s and 1970s, just 65 per cent do so now.

Among women the trends are different - yet similar. Through the past
half-century, growing fractions in their 20s, 30s and 40s have had paid
work. But that historical rise has ended, with a peak at 60 per cent
fulltime employment around age 45 and after that employment is now falling
steeply.

Nearly 60 per cent of the women born in the 1930s had fulltime paid work at
age 45, but just 35 per cent of the same group had it at age 55. That
fall-off around age 45 is evident for every other cohort too, without
exception.

The nature and quality of the shrinking work are changing also. More and
more of it after age 45 is self-employment, much of it uncertain, insecure
and low paying.

Twenty years ago 75 per cent of men aged 50 to 54, for example, received
wages or salary for 20 or more hours a week and 20 per cent were
self-employed. By 1996, just 50 per cent had wages or salary for 20 or more
hours and 27 per cent were self-employed. The rest included some
part-timers, but most were simply without work.

Wages and salaries often now come in smaller amounts and with less security,
continuity or "perks" than they did 20 and more years ago. The decline in
"work" and its rewards is greater than the simple figures might hint.

None of this is peculiar to New Zealand, and it likely points to a
permanent, historic shift in modem capitalist economies.

International studies suggest the important explanations for the trends are
not poor health (today's middle-aged are healthier than ever), mandatory
retirement laws (most people finish work long before any compulsory
retirement age), state pension age (again, most "retire" long before
reaching this), or employment in the public or private sector (both drop
older workers equally readily).

More unexpected - and unwelcome perhaps - is that overall economic
performance matters little either. Booming and stumbling economies alike
have for 20 years been shedding their mature employees, as "jobless growth"
policy takes hold.

Several key forces are at work. First is automation, or the computer
revolution, which helps to do away with many routine procedures or lets them
move to cheaper places and people.

Secondly, the blind drive of global capital for short term "efficiencies,"
which leads to retaining as few staff as possible and as young, pliant,
insecure and cheap as is possible. For many, it leads to an unpleasant,
pressured workplace which we want to leave when we can.

Thirdly, the disappearance of much manufacturing from developed economies
and with it large numbers of better- paying jobs once dominated by the
middle-aged.

Fourthly comes attitudes, or the (questionable) belief that older workers
are more expensive, slower; less enter prising, adaptable or retrainable
than younger ones.

Fifthly, and easy to overlook, is life- style choice, or a rising "culture
of leisure" - the expectation among the middle-aged of an extended period
free of work while still physically vigorous.

All this is likely to intensify in the next few years, for the middle-aged
are the fastest-growing segment of the 

Charles Leadbetter

1999-07-14 Thread Ian Ritchie



The NS Essay - Towards the knowledge society 

Markets are too cruel, communities too stifling, third ways too much of a
fudge. Charles Leadbeater offers a fourth and better way

PictureI will start with myself. I do not work for a company or a
university. I am neither a business consultant nor a civil servant. I have
no job title nor job description, no office nor expense account and I do not
belong to a clearly defined occupational group. When people ask me, "What do
you do?", I find it hard to come up with a clear, concise answer. I work
from home, sometimes writing books, sometimes reports, often for a
think-tank, sometimes for the government or a company. My father had a
steady, predictable career, which carried him through to a well-earned,
properly funded and enjoyable retirement. In contrast, although I am not yet
40 I have already had several mini-careers, in television and newspapers.
Now I am one of Charles Handy's portfolio workers, armed with a laptop, a
modem and some contacts. Peter Drucker christened people such as me
"knowledge workers". Put it another way: I live on my wits. 

At times, I do yearn for the security of a large organisation: something
solid, dependable, with a recognised brand name. But never for more than a
minute. Most large organisations seem pretty soulless, increasingly focused,
driven, lean machines, designed to deliver shareholder value. The lights
never go out these days in modern companies: no sooner have you found a cosy
corner of the organisation in which to settle down than some ambitious
manager points the spotlight at you, questioning your contribution to
profitability. Employees have to live with the threat of downsizing,
reorganisation or merger. They are no more secure than I am. 

And that is the dilemma that faces most people. To go it alone is risky,
demanding and stressful. Yet to rely upon larger organisations and
institutions - companies and trade unions - isn't much of an improvement,
because they seem either too cumbersome or too callous. Our societies and
governments have simply failed to develop the institutions that can respond
both to human needs and to the needs of the new economy. We are weighed down
by organisations, laws and cultures largely inherited from the industrial
19th century: joint-stock companies, local authorities, trade unions,
schools and universities. That century was as revolutionary as it was
because technological innovation went hand in hand with institutional
innovation. By contrast, we are scientific radicals but institutional
conservatives. The Victorians had a grand political and social imagination
to match their achievements in science and industry. Our era, thus far, has
failed that test. 

To understand the scale of the renewal we need, we must understand the three
forces driving change in the economies of modern societies. The first is
finance capitalism, the most obvious and maligned force, which sends a
shiver down most people's spines. It is the disruptive power of deregulated,
interconnected global financial markets, which swill around the world in
pursuit of shareholder value. This is familiar ground: the recent crisis
that has plunged millions of Asians into poverty and sent commodity prices
plummeting is only the latest in a long line. Since the collapse in 1973 of
the Bretton Woods system, which was set up after the second world war to
regulate world financial markets, there have been 69 banking crises and 87
currency crises. As Martin Wolf, the chief economic commentator at the
Financial Times, put it: "Financial systems are not so much an accident
waiting to happen, as one that is constantly happening." 

But a second force driving the new world economy, though just as pervasive
and powerful as financial capitalism, is less well recognised. This is
knowledge capitalism: the drive to generate new ideas and turn them speedily
into commercial products and services. When you buy products today, you
often pay mainly not for the materials used, but for the intelligence
embedded in their software and technology. Radios became smaller as
transistors replaced vacuum tubes. Thin fibre-optic cable has replaced tons
of copper wire. When Henry Ford began mass-manufacturing cars, the miracle
was that all those materials - iron, steel, rubber, glass - could be brought
together in the same place. The steel in the latest luxury cars in the US
costs $1,000; the electronics cost $3,000. The laptop I now use weighs a
little less than the old laptop I bought five years ago. The two machines
have broadly the same ingredients - plastic, copper, gold, silicon and a
variety of other metals. Yet the new machine is ten times more powerful, far
faster and more adaptable than the old machine. None of this extra power
comes from new materials, but from human intelligence, which has allowed the
makers to reorganise the available materials in minutely different ways. And
it is this kind of creativity that now fuels economic advance. 


Jeremy Rifkin - 1-6-99

1999-07-13 Thread Ian Ritchie

Work, Social Capital, and the Rebirth of the Civil Society: 
A Blueprint for a New Third Sector Politics

Rapporteur: Mr Jeremy Rifkin, President of the Foundation on Economic
Trends, Washington, DC 

Picture: bouton_Conference.GIF (1078 bytes)Index



The global economy is undergoing a fundamental transformation in the nature
of work brought on by the new technologies of the Information and Biotech
revolutions. These profound technological and economic changes are going to
force every country to rethink their long held assumptions about the nature
of politics if they are to adjust to the radical new world being readied for
the 21st century. In the new era, the traditional political spectrum of
marketplace vs government is likely to be replaced by the notion of a
three-legged political stool with the marketplace, government, and civil
sectors each acting as a check and balance against the other in a new kind
of tripartite politics. The new political paradigm is going to have far
reaching consequences, reshaping our very ideas of citizenship in the coming
century.

The revolutionary changes in technology and work are already laying the
groundwork for this historic shift in the exercise of political power.
Sophisticated computers, robotics, telecommunications, gene splicing, and
other Information Age technologies are fast replacing human beings in
virtually every industry. Nowhere is this trend more apparent than in the
manufacturing sector. The number of factory workers in the United States
declined from 33 percent of the workforce to under 17 percent in the past 30
years, even as American companies continued to increase production and
output, maintaining our country's position as the number one manufacturing
power in the world. 

For most of the 1980s it was fashionable to blame the loss of manufacturing
on foreign competition and cheap labor markets abroad. In some industries,
especially the garment trade and electronics, that has been the case.
Recently, however, economists have begun to revise their views in light of
new in-depth studies of the manufacturing sector. Economists Paul R. Krugman
of MIT and Robert L. Lawrence of Harvard University, suggest, on the basis
of extensive data, that "the concern, widely voiced during the 1950s and
1960s, that industrial workers would lose their jobs because of automation,
is closer to the truth than the current preoccupation with a presumed loss
of manufacturing jobs because of foreign competition."

Automated technologies have been reducing the need for human labor in every
manufacturing category. Within 10 years, less than 12 percent of the
American workforce will be on the factory floor, and by the year 2020, less
than 2 percent of the entire global workforce will likely still be engaged
in factory work. Over the next quarter century, we will see the virtual
elimination of the blue collar, mass assembly line worker from the
production process.

Until recently, economists and politicians assumed that displaced factory
workers would find new job opportunities in the service sector. Now,
however, the service sector is also beginning to automate, eliminating vast
numbers of white collar workers in the process. In banking, insurance, and
the wholesale and retail sectors, companies are deconstructing. They are
eliminating layer after layer of management and infrastructure, replacing
the traditional corporate pyramid and mass white collar workforces with
small, highly skilled professional work teams, using state of the art
software and telecommunication technologies. Even those companies that
continue to use large numbers of white collar workers have changed the
conditions of employment, transferring workers from permanent jobs to
"just-in-time" employment, including leased, temporary, and contingent work,
in an effort to reduce wage and benefit packages, cut labor costs, and
increase profit margins.

Acknowledging that both the manufacturing and service sector are quickly
reengineering their infrastructures and automating their production
processes, many mainstream economists and politicians have turned to the
emerging knowledge sector, pinning their hopes on new job opportunities
along the information superhighway and in cyberspace. While the "knowledge
sector" will create many new jobs, they will likely be too few to absorb the
millions of workers displaced by the new technologies. That's because the
knowledge sector is, by nature, an elite workforce and not a mass workforce.
Engineers, highly skilled technicians, computer programmers, scientists, and
professionals will never be needed in "mass" numbers to produce goods and
services in the Information Age. Indeed, the shift from mass to elite labor
forces is what distinguishes work in the Information Age from that of the
Industrial Age.

With near workerless factories and virtual companies already looming on the
horizon, every nation will 

FW: DOWN AMONG THE ECONOMISTS

1999-07-12 Thread Ian Ritchie



 --
FYI
 From: stu[SMTP:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
 
 DOWN AMONG THE ECONOMISTS 
 by Jonathon Rowe 
 Of the organized belief systems in America today, economics is surely
 among 
 the strangest - and economists themselves are even stranger. How such
 agile 
 and ambitious minds could drift so far out of touch with daily reality, is
 a 
 question which merits the attentions of our most astute psychologists. The
 
 profession is like a cult of the highly IQd, and I've always wondered
 about 
 the strange rites and rituals that could enable their beliefs to persist. 
 So last winter, when I heard that the American Economic Association was 
 holding its annual meeting around the corner from my office, I felt a
 little 
 like an anthropologist who finds an encampment of aborigines in his back 
 yard. Would anyone raise questions about basic premises, as opposed to the
 
 arcane mathematics of hypothetical markets and pecuniary gain? Would they 
 talk about the actual experience of ordinary Americans, or only
 abstractions 
 like "productivity" and "growth?" I never imagined they'd be talking about
 
 me. Several months before, the Atlantic Monthly had published an article
 by 
 myself and two colleagues, Cliff Cobb and Ted Halstead, called "If the 
 economy is up, why is America down?" The article explored the paradox that
 
 had befuddled the nation's policy establishment during the 1992 
 Congressional campaigns. The economy was doing well, by the conventional 
 reckonings - the GDP was up: people were supposed to be happy and
 fulfilled. 
 But they weren't. 
 In fact they were feeling pretty crummy. Alan Greenspan, America's
 economic 
 pontiff, expressed the high-level headscratching in a speech to a business
 
 audience in San Francisco. Despite the economy's robust performance
 (again, 
 as economists define it) he said, "there seemingly inexplicably remains an
 
 extraordinarily deep-rooted foreboding about the [economic] outlook" among
 
 the populace. 
 What was really "inexplicable," we argued in the Atlantic article, was
 that 
 Greenspan and other economists can't see the obvious. Their reckonings are
 
 archaic; and their very language tends to barricade their minds against
 what 
 is actually happening in the world. Prime evidence is how they measure 
 economic well-being: the gross domestic product or GDP. As have countless 
 others before us, we pointed out that the GDP is a Mad Hatter's accounting
 
 system which adds but never subtracts. It lumps together just about 
 everything that happens in the economy (the monetized portion, at least) 
 under the archaic assumption that people become happier and better off 
 whenever money changes hands. If you have been maimed in a multicar wreck,
 
 or gone through a grueling and costly divorce, or installed water filters
 in 
 your home because the water supply is so bad, then please take a bow. You 
 have caused economists to smile, and made your contribution to the GDP. 
 These people can't tell misery from well-being, only more from less. And
 on 
 top of that, we observed, economists can't even see the informal economies
 
 of family and community at all, because no money changes hands. The
 kitchen 
 table becomes McDonald's, the watchful eyes of neighbors become burglar 
 alarms and police - the more the informal economy breaks down, and a 
 monetized "service sector" takes its place, the more the GDP goes up. 
 Meanwhile, society is literally falling apart. 
 We suggested that the American economy is approaching a turning point, if 
 it hasn't gotten there already. Increasingly the negative, or "illth,"
 side 
 of GDP seems to be outweighing the wealth. The fastest growing portions of
 
 the US economy today include such things as crime and prisons, gambling, 
 disease, and entertainment. Is it any wonder, then, that "growth" doesn't 
 always leave people feeling that life is getting better? Yet economists 
 don't even have a language by which they can acknowledge - let alone
 measure 
 - this fact, which is obvious to just about everyone else. 
 There are economists who realize that the conventional belief system is 
 crumbling. Several purchased bulk copies of the Atlantic article for their
 
 classes; one told us it prompted more class discussion than anything else
 on 
 the reading list. But all were not pleased, especially at the upper levels
 
 of the profession, where stature and acclaim are bound up in the
 orthodoxies 
 we had questioned. Or so I gathered at the AEA session I dropped in on
 that 
 Saturday morning. 
 The session was called "Covering the Economy," and featured a panel of 
 reporters and the economists they often quote. 
 It got off to a promising start. Louis Uchitelle of the New York Times
 said 
 that journalists should endeavor to find out how people are actually
 faring 
 in the economy, as opposed to what economists are saying. More, he
 wondered 
 why reporters regularly quote Wall Street analysts 

FW: Irish Workfare

1999-07-06 Thread Ian Ritchie



 --
 From: B Sandford[SMTP:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
 FYI
 
 ICQ: 20816964 
 Fax: USA(707)215-6524
 
 ***
 News via ainriail the Irish Anarchist Bulletin list
 see http://flag.blackened.net/revolt/inter/email_lists.html
 ***
 
   Social Welfare Bill 1999
  Hassling people into very low paid jobs
 
 
 The Scheme Workers Alliance organises people on 
 employment schemes to combat cutbacks and win the 
 extension of part-time workers rights. Uisce from 
 'Workers Solidarity' spoke to Leo Duffy and Seamas 
 Carrehan of the SWA about the upcoming Social Welfare 
 bill.
 
 The Government is continuing its campaign against 
 working class people. Workfare was introduced last year 
 by Mary Harney, the Minister for Enterprise, Trade  
 Employment. It forces people into shit low paid jobs by 
 cutting their social welfare completely. The next phase 
 in this assault is the proposed Social Welfare Bill 
 1999. 
 
 Contained in it are provisions for increasing welfare 
 benefits for the unemployed, pensioners and other people 
 on welfare. However, the increase would not even buy a 
 packet of cigarettes, the price of which was raised in 
 the last budget. Hidden among these titbits from the 
 Tiger's table is Article 26, a draconian piece of 
 legislation directed at further oppressing the working 
 class.
 
 "This Welfare Bill, and particularly the section dealing 
 with vehicle checkpoints, comes at the end of a three 
 year sustained and covert campaign by the state against 
 the most vulnerable people in our society" said Seamas 
 Carrahen. It allows for Social Welfare inspectors to 
 mount checkpoints to (in theory) catch social welfare 
 recipients who are also working in the black economy. 
 
 Welfare inspectors, when accompanied by a cop can stop a 
 vehicle suspected of "being used in the course of 
 employment or self-employment." Dermot Ahern, Minister 
 for Welfare has assured us "that the powers will 
 continue to be used responsibly. This programme is not 
 aimed at the ordinary citizen going about their 
 business."
 
 But as Leo Duffy put it "it reinforces the sense of 
 threat that people in vulnerable positions, on social 
 welfare (will be) hassled under the new welfare 
 arrangement". It will be used where unemployment is 
 endemic and it will infringe on the lives of working 
 class people. The Irish Council for Civil Liberties 
 described it as "another inroad into peoples liberty to 
 come and go in the course of legitimate activity."
 
 Even though the powers for social welfare inspectors are 
 only now being legislated for, these multi-agency check-
 points have been in operation over the past year. When 
 criticised by other TDs who had never heard of these 
 checkpoints 'till they saw the Bill, Dermot Ahern 
 apologised saying "in retrospect it, perhaps, should 
 have been mentioned."
 
 Ahern "has done all of this without negotiating with any 
 of the people involved" said Seamas Carrehan, pointing 
 to the lack of consultation between Ahern's Department 
 and trade unions and unemployed groups. A reason that 
 Ahern is legislating for the checkpoints now may be that 
 "by formalising it in legislation it does give it a 
 status where it could be more easily manipulated against 
 vulnerable people" said Leo Duffy.
 
 Dermot Ahern, in defence of the checkpoints, said that 
 in February that 10% of vehicles stopped at certain 
 checkpoints revealed fraud cases. What he didn't say was 
 whether these particular cars had been deliberately 
 targeted.
 
 Perhaps he is implying that 10% of working class people 
 are criminals. According to Leo Duffy "anybody who is 
 carrying a plastic social welfare card is automatically 
 going to come under suspicion or threat".
 
 Seamas Carrahen described the Bill as primarily 
 representing "the interests of business. But the people 
 it represents and the people who are saying that we need 
 cutbacks and we cannot afford the welfare state are 
 actually the people, at this point, who are becoming 
 phenomonally wealthy". He added that the continuing 
 campaign against unemployment by the government is not 
 designed to help the unemployed. It is actually to drive 
 the unemployed into low wage jobs, and again that's a 
 business persons agenda that's being promoted by the 
 government.
 
 There has been minimal protest against the new bill. Leo 
 Duffy said that "protests have come from other agencies. 
 They haven't necessarily coalesced in that, but on their 
 own initiative they have sent protests to the Department 
 of Social Welfare". Seamas added "there has been a 
 fragmented response to the bill from isolated quarters. 
 There has been no co-ordinated or adequate attack on it, 
 it has been accepted as a fait accompli". 
 
 Welfare Inspectors will be coming to a neighbourhood 
 near you, soon!
 
 This article is 

FW: Book on Full Employ UBI now in PUBLIC DOMAIN.

1999-04-22 Thread Ian Ritchie

FYI
 --
 From: Dr Gavin Putland[SMTP:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
 
 Dear Sir/Madam,
 
 Please note that my book SIX MONTHS TO FULL EMPLOYMENT, which
 advocates a universal basic income, is now in the PUBLIC DOMAIN
 and is available at www.users.bigpond.com/putland .
 
 Some more recent ideas, e.g. a retail tax and land value tax to
 replace the proposed value-added tax for Australia, are
 contained in my Senate submission MAKE IT A RETAIL SALES TAX,
 which is also available under the same home page.
 
 
 Enjoy (?),
 
 
 Dr Gavin Putland
 43 Azalea Crescent
 Calamvale, Q 4116
 AUSTRALIA
 Phone + 61 7 3272 5984
 Email [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 WWW   http://www.users.bigpond.com/putland
 



RE: basic income scheme

1999-04-20 Thread Ian Ritchie

Have a look at this

"A Universal Basic Income (UBI) is an unconditional cash payment to
individuals sufficient to meet basic needs."

[EMAIL PROTECTED]
http://www.geocities.com/~ubinz/

also

I have developed a model "Widgets in S-Basic" that demonstrates that a
"Citizen's Dividend" not only can provide a socially beneficial effect
but can actually be structured to cause the greatest rate of growth in
an economy. The model is available on line at:
http://www.geocities.com/CapitolHill/1067/widgets.html 
With explanations and details at:
http://www.geocities.com:80/CapitolHill/1067/c04r4a.html
 and part 2 at:
http://www.geocities.com:80/CapitolHill/1067/c04r4p2a.html

I'd appreciate any comments. Thank you,

J.B. O'Donnell

Tax Privilege, Not People
___
Come visit and see a new economic perspective --
   http://www.geocities.com/CapitolHill/1067
   Comments/arguments welcome. 
.

 --
 From: Mark Elliot[SMTP:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
 Sent: Tuesday, 20 April 1999 2:30
 To:   [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Subject:  basic income scheme
 
 A while back on this list there was a discsusion
 of basic income schemes. Can anyone give a reference 
 (web or hard) to work on this. I am particularly interested 
 in stuff moddelling the tax/national accounts effects, 
 but general stuff would be good too.
 
 Thanks
 
 Mark
 
 -
 Mark Elliot - 
 CCSR
 Faculty of Economics
 University of Manchester
 Oxford Road
 Manchester
 M13 9PL
 [EMAIL PROTECTED] 
 Phone number UK: 0161-275-4257
 Phone number international 0044-161-275-4257
 Fax: 0161-275-4722
 



Does The Public mean all of us, equally?

1999-01-27 Thread Ian Ritchie

Does "The Public" mean all of us, equally? 

Keith Rankin, 24 January 1999


We have become accustomed to thinking of "the public" as a collective term
for all of the people who make up a nation. Furthermore, as members of the
public, we all belong equally to that collective entity.

Pinning down the various interpretations of publicness is not easy, however.
The identity of the public can change over time, and may, implicitly if not
explicitly, vary from one member of a society to another.

Who is the public that benefits from public policy? Citizens? State?
Consumers? Each of these concepts can include all persons who together make
a nation. The notion of consumers as the public is particularly problematic.
While all of us may be consumers to some extent, clearly some of us (with
high incomes) consume much more than others.

The implication is that the more we spend, the greater is our stake in "the
public". Under this kind of worldview, the main task of government - the
agent of public policy - is to protect the economic interests of the
affluent. Thus, the term "consumer" is much more exclusive than it sounds
when it glibly rolls off the tongues of the Ministers of Commerce, Finance
and Consumer Affairs; or from the Opposition spokespersons for Commerce
et.al .

The "State" and the citizenry are likewise ambiguous concepts. The welfare
state can, for example, be presented, inclusively, as our friend (who
supports us with social security, education and health care) and servant. Or
the State can be an agency of bureaucratic power whose interest is
diametrically opposed to ours; an agent who seeks to deny us benefits, to
find any excuse to not provide or otherwise fund public services, and to
charge us exorbitant taxes on the first dollars we earn. The state can be
either an "us" or a "them"; inclusive or exclusive. The public interest is
not our interest to a state that sees itself as apart from the people.

"Citizenship" can also be either an inclusive or an exclusive concept. It
all depends on how we define "citizen". Historically, the citizenry has
excluded women, persons without property, slaves, the foreign-born, persons
who do not practice a nation's official faith, the incarcerated. In future,
the term might exclude persons without officially recognised tertiary
qualifications. The status of citizen is capable of acting as a euphemism
for an elite to identify their interest as the public interest, leaving
those excluded as simply private persons. Indeed we may already be
experiencing a process of social change - of social exclusion - that is
better thought of as the publicisation of privilege than as the
privatisation of the public sphere.

Last night I watched a British movie, made in 1994, "The Advocate". (It was
screened on TV3 in December.) It is a black comedy about a real-life lawyer
in 15th century France who made his reputation defending animals in court.
It focussed on the specific case that made his reputation; defending a pig
that was charged with murdering a boy in Abbeville in 1452. (The real
murderer was the seigneur's son, who, as it proved, was a serial killer.)

In the medieval worldview, the concept of "public" was hierarchical. At the
top were the nobility - in France, the seigneurial class. The monarch
identified with that class. At the same time, there was no distinction in
law between people and animals, although some ordinary people were seen as
lower than others. In cases of sodomy, both the person and the animal were
hanged. Consenting heterosexual sex between a Christian and a Jew could be
classed as sodomy, because a Jew was considered in law to be the exact
equivalent of a dog.

In 15th century Europe, debate became quite contentious when actually
figuring out who or what was superior to who or what. Apparently, it took
three days of priestly debate to decide that flies were inferior in law to
domestic animals. As the century progressed animals came to be seen in law
much as children, the intellectually disabled, and the insane are today: as
being unable to understand the consequences of their actions. In the opening
sequences of the film, a man and a donkey were set to hang for sodomy. The
donkey got off with a last-minute reprieve, on account of diminished
responsibility.

The status gap between public (meaning privileged) and private (meaning
unprivileged) was much bigger than that between private persons and animals.
Both persons and animals were fully subject to the law, but the law was only
for the benefit of the public; ie of the propertied consuming citizenry.

In such a hierarchical worldview, a crime only exists when a lower being
harms an equal or a superior being. In such a case, the felony is a public
matter, and the public is as much the victim as the harmed person. In the
reverse case, where the victim is of inferior status, the harm is generally
deemed to be a private matter, no different to mistreating an animal. (That
attitude encapsulates apartheid 

FW: CITIZENS' PUBLIC TRUST TREATY

1999-01-20 Thread Ian Ritchie

FYI

 --
 From: Caspar Davis[SMTP:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
 
 Dear Friends,
 
 Here is the official release of our CITIZENS' PUBLIC TRUST TREATY. It
 is being circulated world wide in English, Spanish, and French, for
 signature.
 
 Please circulate it and post it anywhere you have not yet seen it.
 
 Caspar Davis
 
 THE CALL:
 
 We call upon the nations of the world to ensure the rights of present and
 future generations to genuine peace, social justice and ecological
 integrity
 by implementing the principles of this Citizens' Public Trust Treaty.
 
 We urge you to support the Treaty by adding your name to the petition,
 by passing it on, and by sending copies to heads of states and
 legislators.
 
 January 1st, 1999
 
 _
 
 
 WE, THE CITIZENS OF THE WORLD,
 
 DETERMINED
 * to create a world based on true participatory democracy within a
framework of public trust principles;
 
 * to accept the inherent limits to the Earth's resources and to promote
the peaceful coexistence of all nations, races, and species;
 
 * to develop a stable and peaceful international society founded on the
rule of law;
 
 * to prevent the damaging consequences of unprincipled economic growth;
 
 * to ensure that the economy conforms to the limitations of the ecosystem;
 
 RECOGNIZING
 the interdependence of Peace Building, Human Rights, Environmental
 Protection, and Advocacy for Social Justice;
 
 NOTING
 that through more than 50 years of concerted effort, the member states
 of the United Nations have created international Public Trust
 obligations, commitments and expectations:
 
 1. to Promote and fully guarantee respect for human rights including
 labour
  rights, the right to adequate food, shelter and health care, and
  social justice;
 2. to Enable socially equitable and environmentally sound development;
 3. to Achieve a state of peace, justice and security;
 4. to Create a global structure that respects the rule of law; and
 5. to Ensure the preservation and protection of the environment, respect
 the inherent worth of nature beyond human purpose, reduce the
 ecological
 footprint and move away from the current model of over-consumptive
 development;
 
 AFFIRMING
 that the freedom from fear and want can be achieved only if conditions
 are created whereby everyone is able to enjoy economic, social and
 cultural rights, as well as civil and political rights
 (Universal Declaration of Human Rights);
 
 AWARE
 that the rule of law and the good-faith implementation of international
 legal principles are the foundation for peace, security, and
 co-operation amongst States (Declaration on Principles of International
 Law Concerning Friendly Relations and Co-operation among States in
 Accordance with the Charter of the UN [General Assembly Resolution
 2625 (XXV)]);
 
 RECALLING
 the obligations of States under the Charter of the United Nations to
 guarantee respect for human rights as set out in the International Bill
 of Rights, and to "prevent the scourge of war";
 
 * the expectations created through the United Nations Universal
   Declaration of Human Rights (1948), now accepted as part of customary
   international law, to guarantee "the inherent dignity and the equal and
   inalienable rights of all members of the human family";
 
 * the obligation undertaken by States in various multilateral treaties on
   human rights, that there must be no discrimination on the following
   grounds:
 
 -   race, tribe, or culture;
 -   colour, ethnicity, national ethnic or social origin, or language;
 -   nationality, place of birth, or nature of residence (refugee or
 -   immigrant, migrant worker);
 -   gender, sex, sexual orientation, gender identity, marital status, or
 -   form of family;
 -   disability or age;
 -   religion or conviction, political or other opinion, or
 -   class, economic position, or other status;
 (1966 International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights, and the
 1966 International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights,
 among others);
 
 * the obligations of States to ensure full employment and enjoyment of
   just and favourable conditions of work (1966 Covenant on Economic,
   Social and Cultural Rights);
 
 * the expectation, created by the adoption of the precautionary principle
   as part of customary international law, that where there is a a threat
   of serious environmental damage or of harm to human health, the lack of
   full scientific certainty will not be used as a reason for postponing
   measures to prevent that threat;
 
 * the expectation, created by the adoption of the principle of
   intergenerational equity, that the rights of future generations to an
   ecological heritage will be respected (Convention on the Preservation of
   Cultural and Natural Heritage, 1972);
 
 * that the potential irreversibility of environmental harm gives rise to
   special responsibility to prevent such harm 

Pro-active Money - Flemming Funch

1999-01-08 Thread Ian Ritchie

This may be of interest
Ian

 Proactive Money
 
 by Flemming Funch, 9 April 95.
 
 I was just pondering how the concept of money can make sense at all in an
 information economy, and I've got some ideas.
 
 Before the arrival of agricultural societies money wasn't needed. Hunters
 and gatherers would simply take what they needed or wanted, fight for it
 if
 necessary, and continuously move on to where they could find the resources
 they were seeking.
 
 In "first wave" agricultural societies surpluses would be produced. The
 land
 would be worked to produce food stuff and what is produced is either
 stored
 up or it is traded. Trading would open the need for money as a means of
 exchange. Also, it suddenly became important what you HAVE, what you own.
 If
 you have land you can grow stuff and sell it. If you have produce you can
 sell it. Power and affluence is measured by how much you currently own.
 
 The "second wave", the industrial revolution, centralized production and
 brought about the need for a lot of machinery and buildings that needed to
 be in place BEFORE something valuable was produced. That brought about the
 need for financing, for somehow having or borrowing money before you could
 create more. And then the monetary value of what you produced is in part
 based on the need to recuperate the investments made, and the costs of the
 resources that had to be acquired to put into the product. As opposed to
 agricultural production, industrial production requires that you get stuff
 from elsewhere that you can build your products of and with. Money comes
 to
 symbolize what is OWED for the previously used resources that went into
 what
 you are paying for. Wealth is based on how much you have produced in the
 past that you are now being owed for.
 
 The "third wave", the information society, changes the equation again,
 even
 though the change isn't fully realized yet. Information and knowledge do
 not
 have mass or weight. They can potentially be arrived at instantly and they
 can in principle be replicated any number of times without any use of
 resources. What becomes important is not what happened before, but what
 happens AFTER a piece of information is generated or distributed. The
 value
 of an idea is in what it allows you to do, not in the amount of trouble it
 took to arrive at it, nor in its value as a possession of yours.
 
 But our economic system is still based on second wave principles. Our
 currencies are still defined by the amount of debt they represent. Our
 financial institutions are based on the financing of production that then
 is
 owed for and needs to be repaid with interest by the proceeds from trading
 with the production.
 
 Information products fit poorly into this scheme and it creates friction
 and
 unnecessary hindrances to their use that they are treated by the old
 industrial model. For example, the concept of intellectual property is an
 attempt to treat information as material products.
 
 If a factory produces a car, a certain amount of materials go into it and
 it
 is in itself a very tangible product. It will always be worth something in
 that there is a limited number of cars and raw materials and there is a
 need
 for both. It is quite workable for the car factory to expect to get back
 what they've spent on making the car, and then some, in exchange for
 granting somebody the privilege to take possession of the car. That person
 would after all be able to trade further with the car, as it has value in
 itself.
 
 A knowledge product, such as a software program, works quite differently.
 It
 can be reproduced with no incremental cost and without any resources
 required by its original manufacturer. Potential users will of course
 quickly discover that they themselves can manufacture a fresh instance of
 a
 software product.
 
 A car manufacturer could probably care less if you went home and
 constructed
 a copy of his car in your garage, because he knows that he gets paid for
 the
 resources and work he puts into the production of his car. A knowledge
 worker can not have the same assurance and might have impossible
 difficulties ensuring that he will get his investments in time and
 resources
 back, because he has nothing tangible to show for it. Somebody might help
 him installing some kind of police state methods of monitoring how people
 use his product so he can be paid, but that is really only stalling the
 inevitable conclusion.
 
 Information providers, such as copyright owners, software producers, or
 artists running around angrily trying to stop people from using their
 information without paying for their past work, is a sign of the economics
 no longer being in tune with the methods of production and distribution.
 
 The fact of the matter is that information inherently can be reproduced
 infinitely and there is no inherent value in simply owning it, or in
 having
 worked hard at it. There is only value in using it.
 
 If instances of 

FW: Rapid job growth in the not for profit sector

1998-11-16 Thread Ian Ritchie

 From the Economist
 
 The non-profit sector  - LOVE OR MONEY
 
 FOR economists, the non-profit organisation is something of an
 evolutionary oddity. Without the forces that drive conventional
 firms-shareholders, stock options and, of course, profits-it has still
 managed to thrive in the market economy. Indeed, a pioneering
 international study*, published this week, shows that the non-profit
 sector now accounts for an average of one in every 20 jobs in the 22
 developed and developing countries it examined. 
 
 In the nine countries for which the change between 1990 and 1995 could be
 measured, non-profit jobs grew by 23%, compared with 6.2% for the whole
 economy. In some countries, they grew faster still: by 30% in Britain,
 according to Jeremy Kendall of the London School of Economics, who carried
 out the British end of the study. Why this remarkable expansion? 
 
 Non-profits span a vast range. Some sell goods and services (such as
 American hospitals) and compete head-on with profit-making firms; others
 are religious bodies and campaigning groups, supported largely by
 donations. In between, in Europe, are the Catholic and Protestant
 non-profits, such as Germany's Caritas, which provide many social
 services, and are financed by the state, but independent of it. Because
 the Netherlands has many such bodies, it tops the list for non-profit
 employment (see chart). To find a definition that fitted all 22 countries
 meant including institutions such as universities, trade unions and
 business associations. 
 
 Graph - Non profit share of total employment 1995  - Source John Hopkins
 University
 
 A clue to the success of non-profits is that their growth seems to have
 been fastest in countries where government social-welfare spending is
 high. That suggests they complement government provision, rather than
 substituting for it. Indeed, public money partly finances many
 non-profits-such as Britain's housing associations, which rely on a mix of
 state cash and rents to house the poor. They are, in a sense, an
 off-balance-sheet arm of government. 
 
 At their best they are flexible and innovative. However, as non-profits
 become more important, so do their shortcomings. One is what Mr Kendall
 delicately terms "accountability lapses": non-profits tend to reflect the
 interests of many different groups, but those of the consumer often come
 low on the list. Boards of directors of non-profits are typically much
 larger than those of firms, but they serve a different function. As
 Rosabeth Moss Kanter, a management guru at Harvard Business School, puts
 it, they "are often treated like cheerleaders who have to be given good
 news so they'll go out and raise funds." 
 
 Another problem, says Lester Salamon, one of the study's main authors, is
 finding competent line managers. Moreover, management may be more complex
 than in a conventional company. Because a firm typically makes money
 directly from its customers, it has an incentive to provide what they
 want. In a non-profit, the money may come not from the clients-the
 homeless, say, or the elderly-but from a mixture of grants, donations and
 charges. 
 
 Training for running non-profits is still scarce. Michael O'Neill, of the
 Institute for Nonprofit Organisation Management at the University of San
 Francisco, reckons that 10m people and 100m volunteers work for
 non-profits in America; but no more than 1,000 students a year pass
 through management courses such as the ones he runs. Across the country,
 at the Harvard Business School, the social-enterprise programme that James
 Austin directs aims to ensure that MBAs who go into mainstream business
 know something of running non-profits. Mr Austin recently surveyed 10,000
 HBS graduates and found that about 80% were involved in non-profits in
 some way; 57% sat on the board of a non-profit. 
 
 In fact, points out Ms Moss Kanter, the largest non-profits can attract
 professionals to the top jobs. John Sawhill, a former McKinsey partner,
 heads America's Nature Conservancy; Frances Hesselbein ran the Girl Scouts
 of the USA and graced the cover of Business Week. "Among certain groups of
 people I know," she says, "it now has a certain social cachet to say that
 you are starting a non-profit organisation." Ditching the profit motive
 may become the career opportunity of the future. 
 
 * "The Emerging Sector Revisited" by Lester M Salamon, Helmut K Anheier
 and Associates. Johns Hopkins University Institute for Policy Studies. 
 
 Copyright 1998 The Economist Newspaper Ltd. All Rights Reserved.
 
 http://www.economist.co.uk/editorial/freeforall/current/wb9691.html
 
 



from the Beyond Capitalism Seminar in NZ

1998-10-20 Thread Ian Ritchie


Localising capitalism 

Simon Collins reports from the `Beyond Capitalism' conference 

From City Voice, Wellington NZ


FULLTIME jobs for all who want them, at wages sufficient to sustain a
family. Or a "post-job economy" where only a few do fulltime paid work but
their income is shared with the community. Those were the two broad pictures
of our future at a conference grandly titled `Beyond Capitalism', held at St
John's Church, Willis St, on Friday (2 Oct). A surprising 150 people
attended. Both sides of the argument agreed that our current form of
capitalism is unfair, with the super-rich growing richer while those unable
to get paid work, or reliant on occasional or casual work, sink into
poverty. 

Auckland economics professor Tim Hazledine argued for fulltime jobs for all.
He advocated going "beyond rationalism" - beyond the view that people make
economic decisions out of narrow, "rational" self-interest. In his book
Taking NZ Seriously, he argues that every New Zealander who wanted a job in
the 1950s and 60s had one because there was a shared "sympathy" for one
another. Employers felt duty bound to find jobs for people, and the
unemployed felt a duty to seek work. 

Sympathy 

That sympathy has been lost as the country has opened up to the world.
Multinational companies, which now own most of our big corporates, have no
sympathy for the unemployed. And joblessness has become so widespread that
the unemployed have lost hope of finding work. 

Hazledine advocates: 

* Keynesian monetary policy, using interest and exchange rates to promote
employment, not just to contain inflation. When there is unemployment, as
there is now, the Reserve Bank would push interest and exchange rates down
to encourage more borrowing and investment, and to boost local production
and jobs by making imports dearer. 

* "Moderate tariffs" - in a discussion group he suggested 5% - and "perhaps
some control of foreign direct investment". Our regulations used to allow
foreign takeovers of NZ companies only if the foreigner brought expertise or
access to markets; otherwise there was a presumption that foreign owners
would have less sympathy for NZ workers. 

* "Re-legitimise the union movement." Unions are seen as vital to ensuring
that wages are sufficient to feed a family, giving couples the choice of
having one parent stay home to look after the children. 

* "Re-regulate the pay and perks of chief executives." Hazledine would
outlaw incentive payments because they lead to under-achieving other goals
for which no incentives are offered. He would put two `Kiwi Share' directors
on every public company board, and require that they help set executive pay.


* Abolish welfare. "We have to ask whether beneficiaryism has gone too far,"
he said. In his book, he advocates abolishing all benefits to put pressure
both on employers to provide jobs and on the unemployed to take them. 

Home 

In the book, Hazledine digs at Anne Else's book False Economy by suggesting
that many mothers would be keen to stay home with the kids if they could
afford it. "The unsympathetic reader (which I am not) might wish to subtitle
False Economy: `Middle-class mothers moan about their lives'," he wrote.
Anne Else hit back on Friday, saying she considered calling her talk,
`Middle-aged male academics fantasise about perfect wives'. She said
Hazledine was still bound up in the "romance of capitalism" - the idea that
men should work hard, even at the cost of their health, to support their
families. In fact, she said: "There is no evidence that capitalist
production will ever again conjure up enough jobs... to provide anything
like what we have come to see as a decent standard of living for all - let
alone put back the social pattern of the `family wage-earner'." 

Women 

She said women had never been caught up in the capitalist romance, because
capitalism ignored most of their work - which was unpaid. "Unpaid work
represents one of the few genuine challenges to capitalist logic." Ideally,
Anne Else would pay everyone a basic income. People could then find their
own useful work to do, without having to worry about paid jobs to feed the
family. More immediately, like Hazledine, she would strengthen labour laws
to make sure that paid work is at least paid well and with flexible hours,
so that it can be fitted in around family responsibilities. 

Other speakers at the conference tended towards Else's view. Australian Paul
Wildman advocated developing local economies using networked community
credit unions, operating in parallel with the world economy. He also
favoured a basic minimum income. A workshop led by Anne Else came up with a
list of local initiatives which exist already: green dollar and `bartercard'
schemes, the Women's Loan Fund, the Hokianga Health Trust and the People's
Resource Centre which provide free health care to members. But another
workshop led by Tim Hazledine advocated "a highway to full employment" with
import duties and controls on 

Restructurings at Levi's

1998-10-14 Thread Ian Ritchie


 ICFTU On Line
 215/981009/ND
 
 Restructurings at Levi's: trade unions want global discussion 
 
 Brussels, 13 October 1998 (ICFTU on-line): "Levi Strauss is applying a
 profoundly anti-union strategy.  It announces to the world that it is
 pro-worker, but its real attitude is totally out of sync with the
 quality image it seeks to put across. It was quick to adopt a code of
 conduct committing it to minimum employee relations standards, but this
 has remained a dead letter".  Meeting this week in Berlin, the Executive
 Committee of the International Textile, Garment and Leather Workers'
 Federation (ITGLWF), an ICFTU affiliate, denounced the hypocrisies of
 the world's number one jeans manufacturer which on 29 September last
 announced its intention to close four European plants (3 in Belgium and
 one in France) with 1461 workers in all."  After the discussion we have
 just had with the American delegates, we are convinced of the need to
 broaden the discussion to the world level.  A letter was sent this
 Thursday morning to the Levi's head office in which we invite group CEO
 Bob Haas to meet us.  For Patrick Itschert, the Secretary General of the
 European trade union federation for the sector, the explanations that
 Levi's has been putting forward for several months now in order to
 justify the major restructurings (11 plants closed in the United States,
 and two other American units facing the same fate) do not hold water.
 If the brand has lost its appeal among young consumers, the real reason
 is its desire to maximize profits at all costs.  "The Belgian and French
 sites threatened with closure are profitable.  But the group's purported
 over-capacities are due - as if by accident - to growing activities
 outside the European Union.  Levi's is running its business on a
 sub-contracting and joint venture basis.  In Turkey, for example, it has
 signed a contract with an exclusive sub-contractor and a plant has been
 set up.  This plant employed 150 workers in August 1997, a number soon
 to be tripled.  My deep conviction is that this is disguised delocation,
 which has been on the drawing board for a long time".
 
 Nor, Patrick Itschert continues, does Levi's respect ILO conventions 87,
 98 and 135 on trade union freedom and the freedom of collective
 bargaining.  "In Hungary, management has prevented workers from setting
 up trade unions.  We fought for two years and, finally, given the size
 of the movement, it had to give way".  These practices will hardly
 surprise American delegates meeting in Berlin this week for the ITGLWF
 Executive Committee.  The federation has therefore decided to step up
 pressure on central group management to respect its commitments (its
 code of conduct) and labour standards.
 
 As to the fate of the 1461 Belgian and French workers, the Levi's
 European works' council meeting of 5 October ended with the decision to
 give workers' representatives two months in which to come up with
 counter-proposals based on experts' reports.  But the
 unrepresentativeness of this Levi's committee makes the forthcoming
 discussions very problematic and is stoking trade union wrath:
 "Management has manoeuvred cleverly" Patrick Itschert says, "putting the
 trade unionists delegated by European production units representing more
 than 3,000 workers into a minority against a mass of employee
 "representatives" who are in fact commercial unit executives sent by
 Levi's management.  For example,  the Finnish delegate representing 7
 people has as much say as the French delegate speaking for 530 people
 under threat of redundancy at the "La Bassée" plant.  When negotiating
 the setting up of the council, we asked for proportion representation,
 but Levi's said no.
 
 The directive on European works councils which the European Council of
 Ministers adopted in 1994 is intended to enable workers from so-called
 "Community-sized" enterprises to be better informed and consulted about
 their groups' activities, prospects, structure, economic and financial
 situation and likely development, in short, everything that could affect
 workers.  This legislation applies to enterprises with at least 1,000
 workers in the 18 signatory states, and at least 150 in two or more of
 these countries. Right now, some 450 European works' councils are
 already up and running.  The directive is due for reassessment by
 European social partners in a few months' time.  These works' councils
 can have a major impact on industrial relations and contribute to
 greater transparency in the way multinationals operate.  Information and
 consultation can be no more than stages on the path of negotiation.
 Everything depends on the goodwill of corporate head offices.  As is
 demonstrated by the negative examples of the recent closure of Renault
 Vilvoorde and those announced by Levi's today.
 
 Contact: ICFTU Press, Tel. 32.2.224.02.12 (Brussels).  For further
 information, please visit our internet site 

FW - re Long-Term Unemployment Myths

1998-09-09 Thread Ian Ritchie

 FYI
 --
 From:
 [EMAIL PROTECTED][SMTP:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
 Subject:  Long-Term Unemployment Myths
 
  LONG-TERM UNEMPLOYMENT MYTHS
  
  A warm welcome for a new paper by Stephen Machin (UCL) and Alan 
  Manning (LSE) `Long-Term Unemployment:  Exploding Some Myths', 
  Employment Audit No.8 (Employment Policy Institute), Summer 1998.
  
  This independently corroborates many of the points made in my 
  University of Glasgow paper `The L-U Curve:  On the non-existence of
 a 
  long-term claimant unemployment trap' (May 1997), specifically (all 
  quotes from Machin  Manning):-
  
 * "every time and every place there are high rates of
 unemployment, 
  there is a high incidence of long-term unemployment";  "long-term 
  unemployment has never been a problem when unemployment itself is
 low"
  
 * it is a myth "that there has been a ratcheting up in the level
 of 
  long-term unemployment so that, for a given level of unemployment, we
 
  now have a higher incidence of LTU"
  
 * "while the long-term unemployed do find it more difficult to
 find 
  work than the short-term unemployed, this has always been true and 
  their relative disadvantage does not seem to have worsened over time"
  
 * "any policy that acts to increase the outflow rate from 
  unemployment will act to reduce the incidence of long-term 
  unemployment;  and, moreover, there is no reason why such policies 
  should particularly be focussed on those who have been unemployed for
 
  long periods"
  
 * "The most successful recipe for helping the long-term unemployed
 
  back into work is a buoyant labour market.  If we were fortunate 
  enough to have unemployment rates fall to the levels we had in the 
  1960s there is little doubt that we would have a similar incidence of
 
  long-term unemployment whether we have the `New Deal' or not"
  
 * "as the long-term unemployed are concentrated in the areas where
 
  unemployment itself is highest and there are fewest jobs, it is quite
 
  likely that it is going to be more difficult to find private-sector 
  jobs for the long-term unemployed in depressed regions (which is the 
  preferred outcome in the `New Deal')" (this point - about areas
 rather 
  than regions - is also made in Turok  Webster, Local Economy
 Feb.98).
  
  Machin and Manning refer to a longer version of their paper:  `The 
  causes and consequences of long-term unemployment in Europe', 
  forthcoming in O.Ashenfelter and D.Card (eds) Handbook of Labor 
  Economics, North Holland Press (an update of a US handbook first 
  published in 1986 when Ashenfelter's co-editor, ironically, was none 
  other than Richard Layard, one of the principal advocates of the
 ideas 
  being criticised here).
  
  I hope this additional support will make it easier to obtain the 
  required changes in UK government employment policy.  At present 
  almost all the effort and all the additional expenditure is being 
  devoted to what is largely a non-problem, the supposed lack of 
  "employability" of particular segments of the labour force.  
  Meanwhile, spending is being cut on the only type of policy which 
  would make a real difference, namely the promotion of blue collar
 jobs 
  in areas of high unemployment, through such things as derelict land 
  reclamation in the cities.  And the problem is being worsened by 
  macro-policies which undermine the manufacturing sector.  
  
  On the basis of the shorter Machin-Manning paper (I have not yet seen
 
  the longer one), it is worth noting a few apparent differences
 between 
  their analysis and mine:-
  
 * Their analysis is purely in terms of LAPU (the proportion of the
 
  unemployed who are long-term).  For the reasons given in my paper, I 
  think L (the proportion of the labour force who are long-term 
  unemployed) is a better measure.
  
 * They do not allow for the 6-quarter timelag between change in 
  total unemployment and change in LAPU and hence show the type of 
  "cobweb cycle" chart for the UK 1955-96 which the OECD (in Employment
 
  Outlook and the 1994 Jobs Study) has incorrectly interpreted as 
  indicating the existence of "ratcheting" of the level of LTU.
  
 * They imply that all of the long-term unemployed find it more 
  difficult to obtain jobs and will therefore benefit from New Deal
 type 
  policies;  my analysis is that it is only a subset of the long-term 
  unemployed with genuine employment handicaps who will benefit from
 the 
  New Deal.  The remainder simply have the misfortune to live in areas 
  of high unemployment, or are unlucky for stochastic reasons, and any 
  New Deal 

Two 'poems' you may like to use.

1998-08-19 Thread Ian Ritchie

Cecil Rajendra's came from Don Borrie's paper to the Anti-privatisation
conference - privatisation by NZ local authorities
The second is from a Sustainable America workshop - not sourced.
Ian


Until they Right the Wrong, I shall sing no Celebratory Song


So long as car parks take precedence over hospitals.
Multi-story hotels over homes for people,
Irrelevant factories over fields of our daily sustenance

I shall sing no celebratory song no matter how many suns go down
This tongue will be of thistle and thorn until they right the wrong!

So long as law comes before justice
The edifice before service
The payment before treatment and appearance before essence

I shall sing no celebratory song no matter how many suns go down
This tongue will be of thistle and thorn until they right the wrong!

So long as the poet is debased and the businessman praised
The realist rewarded and the idealist degenerated

I shall sing no celebratory song no matter how many suns go down
This tongue will be of thistle and thorn until they right the wrong!

So long as foreign investors devastate our estate
and the voice of capital speaks louder than the pleas of fisher folk

I shall sing no celebratory song no matter how many suns go down
This tongue will be of thistle and thorn until they right the wrong!

So long as blind bulldozers are allowed unchecked to guard our landscape

and multi-nationals licensed to run amuck across this land

I shall sing no celebratory song no matter how many suns go down
This tongue will be of thistle and thorn until they right the wrong!

So long as the rivers and streams, our beaches, our air, our oceans, 
Our trees, our birds, our fish, our butterflies, our bees
Are strangled, stifled, polluted, poisoned, crushed, condemned by
lopsided development

I shall sing no celebratory song no matter how many suns go down
This tongue will be of thistle and thorn until they right the wrong!



Cecil Rajendra

UNITED FOR A FAIR ECONOMY

Because CEOs make more in a day than many of us make in a year and
Sweatshops are here again and
We're being downsized and out-sourced and off-loaded and
Where corporations get most of the welfare and
We're working longer hours with fewer benefits and 
We don't have time for our children and
The American dream is slipping away and
Inequality hurts all of us, even the wealthy, and
A woman gets 72 cents on a man's $1 and
More black men have been to prison than to college and
The rich get tax breaks while our teachers get pay cuts and
The top one percent has more wealth than the bottom 90 percent and
We're still waiting for the "trickle down" and
The problem is not politicians, but the corporations that buy them and
Two million of us have seen our wealth double, while 200 million of us
become more insecure and
People make the system and people can change it and
Labour's on the move again and
What we do is more important than what we own and
The minimum wage should be a living wage and
Every child should have their chance and
Because when we all come together, there is nothing we can't do, we are
UNITED FOR A FAIR ECONOMY




Employment Statement by NZ Catholic Bishops

1998-07-20 Thread Ian Ritchie

 FYI
 Ian
 --
 From: Louise May[SMTP:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
 Subject:  RE: Employment Statement
 
 
 Some Concerns About Employment
 A Statement from the New Zealand Catholic Bishops Conference
 
 
 
 In 1991 when the Employment Contracts Legislation was being promoted,
 we stated that:
 
   As Bishops of New Zealand we must speak against this proposed
 legislation, 
   as its underlying ideology is contrary to the social doctrines
 of the Church.
 
 The underlying ideology of the new individual legislation is
 unacceptable, we argued:
 
   because it emphasises free choice without balancing this concept
 with concern 
   for the common good ... and because it emphasises the rights of
 the individual
   without their accompanying duty to act in solidarity, and
 without giving any 
   corresponding rights to the group.
 
 One of the concerns expressed in our 1991 statement was that not only
 does the legislation appear to emphasise the concept of free choice at
 the expense of the common good, it actually fails to give workers a
 genuine freedom of choice.  A solitary worker facing negotiations with
 an employer is often not free to choose anything other than between
 unemployment and that which is offered. 
 
 This concern has become a reality in the changing working environment
 under the Employment Contracts Act.  A market survey in October 1992
 showed that 37% of employees said they did not feel free to choose the
 type of employment contract covering them.  Deteriorating work
 conditions since 1991 reflect this lack of ability of workers in
 setting the standards and conditions under which they are employed.
 In 1996 it was found that over 43 % of workers had either lower or
 unchanged ordinary time wages since 1991.  Around the same percentage
 of employers had cut overtime rates and reduced allowances and other
 penal rates.  This is despite economic expansion in this period and
 high levels of profit growth for business.  The introduction of the
 Employment Contracts Act, along with other related employment reforms
 since 1991, have clearly led to the overall deterioration of worker
 conditions by tipping the balance of power in the employment
 relationship even further to the employers' advantage.
 
 Worker Representation
 One of our fears which has come to pass is that the legislation has
 resulted in a weakening of organisations whose purpose is to protect
 the rights of workers.  Statistics reveal a dramatic loss in union
 membership since the implementation of the new employment legislation.
 There has been an overall decline in union membership, which reckoned
 across all unions, is calculated to be 44% between the years 1991 and
 1996.  It also concerns us that the Employment Contracts Act
 legislation results in lessening accessibility of unions to workers
 and the workers' rights to be represented by a collective bargaining
 agent in employer-employee negotiations.  
 
 Catholic Social Teaching is very clear on the matter of worker
 representation.  It tells us that workers have the right to be
 represented by unions, as they can "not only protect the just rights
 of the workers but - as an indispensable element in modern,
 industrialised societies - are to be a mouthpiece for the struggle for
 social justice".  This implies that the employer must be bound to
 recognise and accept the workers' representative, something which the
 Employment Contracts Act does not guarantee.  Such undermining of the
 rights of workers in relation to negotiations is in direct
 contravention to Catholic Social Teaching.   
 
 Equal Pay
 As predicted in our original statement, the burden has fallen
 especially on women.  The pay gap between men and women gradually
 reduced between 1986 and 1991, but since the repealing of the
 Employment Equity Act, and the introduction of the Employment
 Contracts Act, the pay gap has stabilised, with women presently
 earning between 80.5% to 81.5% of men's pay.  It is obvious that the
 marketplace alone is not able to deliver pay equity for women. 
 
 Hours of Work
 One of the results of the legislation of 1991 is that many low-paid
 workers have to work (sometimes at an additional job) at night or at
 the weekend while workers in more highly paid jobs are often expected
 to work almost limitless hours.  As a consequence many workers are
 denied the opportunity to spend adequate time with their families
 through "over-employment", that is, by working more than 50 hours a
 week.  In 1995 it was found that over 130,000 people were then
 routinely working more than 60 hours per week, and more than 50,000 of
 these people were working over 70 hours per week.  The average weekly
 hours worked has increased each year from 1991 when the Employment
 Contracts Act took effect.  The number of paid hours on overtime has
 actually decreased alongside the rise in hours worked. 
 
 The lack of worker protection under the new legislation, and the
 

FW: Call for papers - LEEDS

1998-07-02 Thread Ian Ritchie



 --
 From: C.J. FORDE[SMTP:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]
 Reply To: C.J. FORDE
 Sent: Thursday, 2 July 1998 05:21
 To:   [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Subject:  Call for papers
 
 
 
 LEEDS UNIVERSITY BUSINESS SCHOOL
 
 THIRD ANNUAL POST-GRADUATE CONFERENCE
 
 13TH NOVEMBER 1998
 
 CALL FOR PAPERS
 
 The Third Annual Post-Graduate Conference at the Leeds University
 Business School will take place on Friday 13th November 1998 at
 Bodington Hall, Otley Road, Leeds. 
 
 
 This conference is organised by post-graduates, for post-graduates 
 and aims to provide a unique opportunity to present and discuss their 
 research. We are eager to develop a genuine plurality of debate 
 between areas and approaches within economics and related social 
 sciences. Papers are invited from any area or perspective in 
 economics. We especially welcome papers on  the following: 
 
 The Economics of Work and Employment 
 
 Methodological and Philosophical Issues in Economics 
 
 Money and Uncertainty 
 
 Industrial Change in a Global Economy 
 
 
 Please send abstracts of up to 1000 words to Gary Slater, 
 address below. The deadline for submissions is Friday 4th  September, 
 and full papers will be required by 30th October. 
 
  If you are able to display a poster for this call for papers please 
  download the attached copy in Word 6.0. 
 
 
 For more information please consult the Conference Web Page
 at http://www.leeds.ac.uk/cipp/pgc.htm or contact : 
 
 
 Gary Slater 
 ([EMAIL PROTECTED]) 
  Post-Graduate Conference 
 Leeds University Business School 
 11 Blenheim Terrace 
  Leeds University 
  Leeds LS2 9JT 
 Phone: (+44)113-233-6858 
 Fax: (+44)113-233-2640 
 



Query re Mondragon

1997-10-13 Thread Ian Ritchie




 Does anyone know of a recent film or video about Mondragon?  "The
 Mondragon
 Experiment" is too old and too British to be effective for my
 students.
 
 Ric McIntyre
 Economics and Labor Research
 University of Rhode Island
 Kingston RI 02881
 
I don't know of a recent video or film but I gather the culture
has changed a little over the years. I enclose a report by Greg Pirie

From:   Greg Pirie[SMTP:[EMAIL PROTECTED]]

Mondragon:  When I attended the CICOPA (a sub-set of the ICA
specifically
orientated to artisanal  workers' coops) conference in June
1994 in
Vittoria, Spain, we visited the HQ of the Mondragon Cooperative
Group (MCG).
During the course of a promotional video on how the MCG was
geared up to
successfully exploit the integration of the European markets
into a
borderless single market, etc, etc, the ownership/operation of
factories in
Thailand and Brazil by the MCG was mentioned, almost as a
throwaway line
just to demonstrate diversification, dynamism, etc.

When, at a subsequent panel discussion session, a couple of us
asked about
these, we were told they were not separate worker cooperatives,
as are all
other components of the MCG, but direct subsidiaries of
Mondragon coops,
employing local labour under local conditions.  We specifically
asked about
worker participation in ownership and application of the MCG
norms about
wage relativities and were told (in our words) that this was a
standard
European investment in lesser developed economies.  Our
conclusion was,
therefore, that Mondragon coops were taking advantage of the
lower costs of
doing business in these countries in order to gain a competitive
advantage
in the European market.  When we questioned the inconsistency we
saw between
this behaviour and the espoused values on which the MCG is
based, we
received agreement from one of the MCG pioneers on the panel,
who
effectively expressed his disagreement with the action.

That was about it.  The two of us who had got a bit excited
about the issue
never had an opportunity to confront any of the MCG's leadership
-- it was a
big affair covering a host of matters.

It does, however, touch on the challenges for any coop system
about dealing
with the two questions of size and interfacing with the rest of
the world.
Within the mature Credit Union systems, there's stiff debate
about getting
"too" big.  Do you lose the essential characteristics of being a
coop when
you have member/owners in excess of 20,000 (or any other "too
big" number)?
What are the essential characteristics anyway, and are they
vulnerable to
issues of size?

Visiting one of the original Mondragon coops caused me to wonder
about the
reality of worker/owner participation.  The answers to various
questions
suggested it was limited to broad issues and only at annual
assemblies.  Day
to day, the management-worker relationship was pretty standard.
Jocelyn
once had a book about some participative research into
management-worker
relationships in coops that suggested it was essentially no
different from
the capital-labour model.  

Equally, Credit Unions have to put the money they have in
savings from
members but not out on loan somewhere.  That means in the
orthodox banking
system or equivalent.  Thus raising the question as to the use
of those
funds now 'outside' the Credit Union system.