On Nov 24, 2011, at 3:50 PM, robert bristow-johnson wrote:
On 11/24/11 2:20 PM, David L Wetzell wrote:
Let me start off by saying that I'm thankful for this list-serve of people passionate about electoral reform and that you put together a working consensus statement. I'm trying to work it some more...

My belief is that the US's system makes it necessary to frame electoral reform simply and to limit the options proffered.

but they should be *good* options. limiting the proffered options to IRV is proven by our experience in Vermont to eventually fail.

That justifies promoting Condorcet - see below. Others deserve arguing against: FPTP- can only vote for one - why we are considering what to promote. Approval - can vote for more, but does not support expressing unequal liking. Range/score - demands expressing (in an amount understandable) how much better one candidate is than another. IRV or IRV3 - good voting, but counting does not promise to be complete (see Burlington). PR - that deserves promoting for such as legislators - but here we are thinking of electing single officers such as mayors and governors.

 This is what FairVote does and they do it well.

no they don't. FairVote sells ranked-choice voting and the IRV/STV method of tabulating the ranked ballots as if they are the same thing. i.e., once they convince voters, city councilors, and legislators that ranked-choice voting is a good thing (by accurately pointing out what is wrong with FPTP in a multiparty context and/or viable independent candidates), they present IRV as it is the only solution. that backfired BIG TIME here in Burlington Vermont.

If you're going to undercut their marketing strategy then ethically the burden of proof is on you wrt providing a clear-cut alternative to IRV3.

Condorcet.

which Condorcet method i am not so particular about, but simplicity is good. Schulze may be the best from a functional POV (resistance to strategy) but, while i have a lot of respect for Markus, the Schulze method appears complicated and will be a hard sell. i also do not think that cycles will be common in governmental elections and am convinced that when a cycle rarely occurs, it will never involve more than 3 candidates in the Smith set. given a bunch of Condorcet-compliant methods that all pick the same winner in the 3- candidate Smith set, the simplest method should be the one marketed to the public and to legislators.

The ranking offers a bit of power that is easy to express - rank as many candidates as you approve of, showing for each pair whether you see them as A>B, A=B, or A<B, but no need to assign a value as to how much the better exceeds the weaker (note that ranking a candidate you do not approve of risks helping that reject win). It is in ranking multiple candidates that we lead to voting for more than two parties for we can vote among those parties plus our true desire.

The voting is much like IRV's, except also permitting A=B. The vote counting, unlike IRV's, considers all the ranking you vote.

While you can use as many ranks as the ballot permits, you are not required to do more than express your desires - ranking one as in FPTP, or more as equal as in Approval, is fine if that expresses your thoughts (especially if you only wish the leader to win or lose).

To get a cycle you have to have three or more near tied candidates in which each beats at least one of its competitors. Resolving such requires a bit of fairness, but requires little more than that, since we got there by being near to ties.


Dave Ketchum
--

r b-j                  r...@audioimagination.com

"Imagination is more important than knowledge."


----
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info

Reply via email to