David L Wetzell wrote:

    KM:I think this is where we differ, really. On a scale from 0 to 1,
    you think their relative merit is something like:

    0: Plurality
    0.7: IRV3/AV3
    0.72: Condorcet, MJ, etc

    while I think it's something like:

    0: Plurality
    0.25: IRV
    0.3: IRV3/AV3
    0.7: Condorcet, MJ, etc.

    (Rough numbers.)

    If you're right, of course arguing for Condorcet seems like an
    angels-on-the-head-of-a-pin thing - and it's even harmful because
    X_IRV * p(IRV) >> X_Condorcet * p(Condorcet) . The step from
    IRV3/AV3 to Condorcet is only 0.02 after all, and the momentum
    difference is huge! But if I'm right (and this is why I keep
    bringing up the examples where IRV has been used), then going for
    IRV is much more likely to rebound on you later.


dlw: This is a good statement of our diffs. I'd say I rank the partial use of PR to get a contested duopoly (or to prevent a contested monopoly) very high, while you rank it rather low, especially relative to the development of a multi-party system, not unlike what you have in Norway. This is likely a matter of political cultural differences, which makes my valuations more likely to be prevalent in the US.

I base my low confidence of PR's capacity to pull stronger towards competition than IRV does towards consolidation in that IRV pulls stronger wherever it's been tried. You say they aren't applicable. You may have that opinion, but then there's little I can show that will help.

So there are two disagreements. Ultimately, I think that multiparty democracy would be better than your contested two-party rule. I could pull market analogies for this (oligopolies and cartels), or I could simply say "it's harder to buy off ten than to buy off two". Here you may claim that this is because of my political difference if you want to do so.

However, stronger is this: even if you wanted a contested two-party rule, I think IRV would pull too strongly. Again I take my evidence from other countries where that is the case - where the major two are the same as they have been a long time ago, and again, you say that's not applicable. Of course, nothing is absolute: even with Plurality, your own major parties have changed a few times since the time of the Founding Fathers. I just don't think IRV will make a difference.

So if we boil down our disagreement further, I think that we *can* generalize from other IRV nations. You think we can't, because your rules are different. There have been many IRV elections (so there are samples to pick), but not very many different systems of government in which IRV is placed. If I pull 100 local Australian elections and NatLibs or Labor win in 95 of them, you could say that's because of the Australian rules so they only count as one sample.

I think you're judging IRV too harshly on account of Burlington VT. The sample size is too small to make such a strong judgment.

Well, Burlington just confirms things. The simulations say IRV can fail to pick the CW, and may squeeze the center out, and the less minor the minor parties are, the worse it gets. As Burlington agrees with the simulations, that doesn't count in IRV's favor.

      4. This is why I pick away at how the args in favor of other
      election rules get watered down or annihilated when you make the
      homo politicus / rational choice assumptions more "realistic" or
      you reduce the number of effective candidates, or you consider
      how perceived biases/errors get averaged out over time and
      space, or you focus on the import of marketing and how IRV has
      the advantage in that area of critical importance to the
      probability of successful replacement of FPTP.


   You try to do so. From my point of view, when I give you examples
   from the real world, you say that it'll be different here (re
   Australia on the one hand and France on the other, for instance).
   When I pull from theory, you say that the theory doesn't apply
   because it assumes too much; and when I pick examples where theory
   and practice seem to agree (Burlington), you say that that's just
   because the status-quo-ists put pressure to bear on IRV.


dlw: 1. Well, the sample of IRV uses is small, which makes it hard to render verdict on it.

So why would IRV improve things enough over Plurality? That verdict, too, has to come from somewhere.

2. AU does use IRV/PR in the opposite from ideal mix if the goal is to increase the number of competitive elections. 3. WRT France, we disagreed on matters of taxonomy. I classified their top two as a hybrid. You classified it as a winner-take-all and used it to show how IRV has been improved upon and could be improved upon further.

Let me try your pragmatism for a minute. You say that our disagreement about top-two is taxonomy. Why should taxonomy matter, though? If I have a "tacs"-type voting method, and an "intar"-type voting method, both elect winners to single positions, and the voters know both, but the difference is that the "intar" method produces a greater diversity of winners than does the "tacs" method, then why not use the "intar" method?

Or, moving back into reality, if we're comparing TTR and IRV, and TTR is known in the US and shows you can go beyond a dominant two-party system even without PR, why not use it? Whether TTR is a "proper" single-winner rule doesn't matter if you're pragmatic.

I say top-two (TTR) is known, since runoff elections are used many places in the US. FairVote tends to market IRV as "runoffs without the runoff" there, and as my list showed, that particular form of marketing carries with it a risk of backfiring.

From what I understand, the answer is "because IRV is linked to STV, so it's a way of getting PR in the door". But PR can be implemented, as the proportional representation organizations have shown in the past, without even mentioning IRV. So if that's the answer, it can essentially be rephrased as "because that's the way FairVote sells STV, and FairVote's got all the momentum these days". If *that* is true, I don't see that we should abandon other methods simply because FairVote made a mistake about how to market PR.

Also note that I didn't use it to show how IRV "has been improved upon". Top-two got there first. The most significant point I was making with top-two was that it *is* possible to have multiparty democracy with single-member districts. The multi- may not be as multi as with PR, but by showing this, I can counter statements of the form that "IRV leads to two-party domination within IRV seats, but so do all single-member rules". You might use that kind of statement against Condorcet, but you can't use it against runoffs.

4. Rational choice theory is unrealistic (at least for all political elections). This makes a lot of the Condorcet et al stuff be much ado about nothing. You acceded that fuzziness in the perceptions of voters and the positioning of candidates muddied the waters considerably.

Condorcet regards not just a single very precise result, but a whole class of them. Therefore, it is resistant to perturbation, so I don't think there's "much ado about nothing".

To clarify by taking an extreme, you could argue in the same manner against majority rule. Say something like "chaos means there may be majorities when the *real* majority isn't in favor, so Majority compliance doesn't matter". That sounds absurd - it is - but it's absurd because the majority criterion is robust.

As for "muddying the waters", I said that to the extent it does so, it cuts against IRV. First, I introduced the Yee diagram, where IRV has much more comple win regions than Condorcet. The thinner and more convoluted the "border" between win regions, the greater the chance that an election result will fall in the wrong "country". Second, I pointed at IRV's amplification dynamic, where near-ties in one round could lead the method on a completely different path in a later round. Third, I showed Brian Olson's graphs, which seem to show that IRV handles noise less well than the other methods.

So I was saying "Alright, you think that rational choice is too simplistic on account of fuzziness. Well, here's what happens if you take noise into account, and it's not favorable to IRV".

5. You can't divorce what happened in Burlington from the real-politik. It's not a slam-dunk, because the opponents of electoral reform are well aware of the divide and conquer strategy.

Are they? I don't think the opponents of electoral reform know about Condorcet, much less Majority Judgement, Range, Approval, or the likes. The greater you think the order of magnitude in p_IRV >> p_Condorcet, the less of a point you'd think there would be for the opponents to even care about Condorcet.

To me, it seems more plausible that they said "okay, we want to repeal this. What can we throw at IRV and have it stick?". Then they might have looked at pages of people like Warren and thrown nonmonotonicity at IRV. This would have had a much lesser chance to actually stick if IRV had behaved properly. When FairVote advertises IRV as the way you can vote without having spoilers distort the outcome, then people vote, and spoilers distort the outcome, then that's not just the opponents of electoral reform using massive marketing machines to convince the people. Draw attention to, perhaps, but attention or not, there was a majority who preferred Montroll to Kiss, and that majority got its wish denied in favor of the Kiss-over-Montroll minority.

All of which is to say that | X_IRV-X_Condorcet | is likely smaller than the electoral analytics purport, while you concede p_IRV is considerably greater than p_Condorcet.

If FairVote continues on its marketing of IRV and we do nothing, yes, IRV is more likely to be adopted than Condorcet, at least in the short term.

However, I think that would be unfortunate in two ways. First, I don't think IRV improves Plurality enough that it'll matter. It'll keep major parties safe as long as minor parties are minor enough, but not beyond that point. Therefore, if you do end up with IRV, you keep your uncontested two-party rule. Second, you may not even keep IRV. If IRV gets it wrong often enough, or reproduces Plurality's results often enough that it doesn't seem to be worth it, then the option of reverting it can seem quite tempting. If FairVote claims that it's a runoff-without-runoff or that you can vote as you wish without fearing spoilers, and that turns out to be false, then IRV may not last; and if IRV is considered equal to ranked balloting, then the immediate reform chance is lost. You might have to go a far more circuitous route involving augmenting Plurality with MMP - and that wouldn't help executive positions like Governor or President.

   KM:How can we go anywhere from there? If you can say every
   application is a special case that doesn't apply in the situation
   you have in mind, and if you can say that the theory that remains
   has no verification in the form of practical results, then we're not
   left with much except restating our relative merit numbers to each
   other.


dlw: There is a small data set for IRV apps and an even smaller one for the infinite array of alternative electoral rules.

There's a small number of rulesets. There's a substantial number of IRV elections, but most of them (local Australian elections) have the same overarching ruleset that you would probably argue taints the results.

My point is that when you argue "falsely" that | X_IRV-X_Condorcetetal | >> 0, with the latter over the former, you risk lowering | p_IRV-p_Condorcetetal | by making p_IRV drop a lot more than p_Condorcetetal rises. p_Condorcetetal does not rise because there's no heir apparent, likely because the Xothers vary relatively little among real world voters.

The lack of a heir apparent might not be that bad. Committees like the Rhode Island one might pick the best among near-equals according to what they deem important. This kind of approach has worked in New Zealand and led to election reform referenda in parts of Canada (though the voters there decided not to go for it in two cases, and had a majority but not a supermajority in the third).

If you want electoral reform to happen from the bottom up, you don't need the national government to set up the committee. A state can do so, or a more local area like a city.

We can't say it's just a matter of opinion, cuz it's probably not such, and so what makes sense to me is to rally around IRV3/AV3 and trust that when it's use is prevalent that it'll be the basis for choosing among a wider set of electoral reforms, which will have a further ratchet effect in expanding upon what is democracy.

It's a matter of data either incomplete or considered incomplete. From your position on what does and does not count as a valid distinct sample, and from your relative merit ideas, your conclusion follows. I see that. I can put myself in your shoes, as it were. From mine, my follows. I don't want to risk that IRV turns out to make no difference or that p_IRV turns out to be hollow (to collapse when enough scrutiny is brought to it).

dlw: And I'm saying the real life sample sizes are too damn small to justify rhetorically torpedoing FairVote's marketing/bundling strategy. Why not, push for more experimentation with other election rules in Norway or elsewhere and trust that the US will find its way in its own way, hopefully with some critical learning from across the pond.

I don't think there's any support for that here. Modified Sainte-Lague (with two-tier proportionality - a sort of double list MMP based on the same counts) is good enough, or so goes the opinion of most of the voters. A vote is only "wasted" when it doesn't change the party's rounded number of seats, which happens much less with 169 MPs than with a single president. Therefore, most voters (who don't vote for parties below the threshold) feel their vote matters, and we don't get lesser-evil strategy problems.

In an ideal world, perhaps we'd be using STV with Schulze's adjustments for the second tier of proportionality. Or perhaps we'd pick our "representatives" completely randomly with different advisory bodies giving options for different sorts of legislation, so the representative sample of the population determine "what" and the advisory bodies determine "out of which options" and "how". Who knows? In any event, that's very far off: people are basically satisfied.

(And you may find this of interest: After independence, there were two main parties in Norway: the Conservative Party and the Liberal Party. While the Conservative party has remained strong (it's currently third largest by support), the Liberal Party's support has been below 10% since 1969. Major party status can indeed change in PR. I find the image of an US equivalent funny: a Democratic Party at 6-7% support?)

----
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info

Reply via email to