Re: [EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-23 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

robert bristow-johnson wrote:

robert bristow-johnson wrote:

...

i dunno how to, other than take the raw ballot data of some
existing IRV elections, but i would like to see how many of these
municipal IRV elections, that if the ballots were tabulated
according to Condorcet rules, that a cycle would occur.


Kristofer Munsterhjelm wrote: ...

I haven't run the data through my simulator yet, but it seems
cycles are rare.


i have to confess that i am less worked up about what pathologies
would result from a Condorcet cycle than i am about what pathologies
result from FPTP or IRV (or Borda or whoever) failing to elect the
Condorcet winner whether such exists.  we know the latter actually
happens in governmental elections.  i still have my doubts to any
significant prevalence of the former.


That's what the data might provide information about. If it is 
representative and cycles are rare, then there's little to worry about, 
except how opponents might exaggerate the faults. If cycles are common, 
then one should be careful to pick the right cycle-breaker.



on the rare occasion a cycle ever happens, probably Tideman
Ranked-Pairs would be the best compromise between a fairer Schulze
beatpath and some method that has sufficient "lucidity" that voters
can understand it and have confidence that no "funny business" is
going on. 


Yes. I think so, too, but Schulze has momentum (within technical 
organizations, mostly), so the question is which is greater an advantage.



but whether it's beatpath or ranked-pairs or IRV rules as
the method that resolves a cycle,  at least in this very rare
occasion, it's picking a non-Condorcet winner meaningfully, even if
there are conceptual ways to turn tactical with it.  but then, how
profitable is it to vote tactically when there is little probability
to the conditions that would serve such tactical voting?


There would be two kinds, I think: attempted "vote management" by 
parties and what we might call "ignorant strategy" that the voters do by 
themselves, and which only distorts the outcome if lots of people do it. 
The latter is not much of a threat, I think, and the method only has to 
weather the former for a few elections before the parties see it isn't 
going to work.
In small committees, the two would converge: poison pill type tricks are 
possible with Condorcet methods, as well, but that's not the application 
we're speaking of at the moment.



if it were one of those Condorcet methods and if there is little
likelihood of a cycle happening and if a savvy voter knows that, how
does it benefit his/her political interests to do anything other than
vote for their fav as their first choice and cover their ass with a
tolerable 2nd choice?  how are they ever (assuming no cycle) hurting
their favorite or helping any unranked candidates (tied for last
place, in this voter's esteem) beat the 2nd choice?  i really find it
hard to see the tactical interests as differing from the sincere
political interests.


Ignorant strategy could take the form of "I really really hate [major 
party X], so I'll put him last", where there are also worse candidates 
in the running, but the voter is used to two-party systems. Burial by 
accident, as it were. Warren claims that will destroy most Condorcet 
methods, because DH3 applies to that instance as well, but I'm not so 
sure. It *does* destroy Borda, but so does agenda manipulating (fielding 
loads of clones).


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-23 Thread Dave Ketchum
FPTP:  For most elections this can handle the decision needed - though  
get near a tie and suspicion pushes toward doing a runoff.


IRV:  Does let voters do ranked voting, but we find plenty of reasons  
to complain about how it counts the votes.


Condorcet:  Lets voters do ranked voting for more than one, indicating  
which they like best.
 Matters often to let them express their desires more completely  
when they wish - though they can often adequately express their  
desires via bullet voting.
 Matters MUCH, though rarely, to sort out more complex  
decisions.  It is for this ability that we need such as Condorcet.


It is for the last topic, where there may be a cycle and no CW, that  
analyzing votes is more of a challenge.


The Llull method will find the CW if it exists.  Else it will find a  
cycle member.  Deciding which takes a bit more looking at the N*N  
array.  We debate how to choose a winner, which I claim should only  
consider cycle members (any cycle member would become CW if other  
members were rejected).


Tactical voting?  PROVIDED you know how all others will vote, you may  
be able to influence results by responding based on what you know.   
That results can be affected via such makes sense.  That you can both  
have the needed information and modify your vote as you plan is a  
suspect dream - perhaps someone can do useful analysis as to frequency  
of attainable useful results for such.


Dave Ketchum

On Nov 23, 2009, at 5:00 PM, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

robert bristow-johnson wrote:

...
i dunno how to, other than take the raw ballot data of some  
existing IRV

elections, but i would like to see how many of these municipal IRV
elections, that if the ballots were tabulated according to Condorcet
rules, that a cycle would occur.


Kristofer Munsterhjelm wrote:
...
I haven't run the data through my simulator yet, but it seems  
cycles are

rare.


i have to confess that i am less worked up about what pathologies  
would result from a Condorcet cycle than i am about what pathologies  
result from FPTP or IRV (or Borda or whoever) failing to elect the  
Condorcet winner whether such exists.  we know the latter actually  
happens in governmental elections.  i still have my doubts to any  
significant prevalence of the former.


on the rare occasion a cycle ever happens, probably Tideman Ranked- 
Pairs would be the best compromise between a fairer Schulze beatpath  
and some method that has sufficient "lucidity" that voters can  
understand it and have confidence that no "funny business" is going  
on.  but whether it's beatpath or ranked-pairs or IRV rules as the  
method that resolves a cycle,  at least in this very rare occasion,  
it's picking a non-Condorcet winner meaningfully, even if there are  
conceptual ways to turn tactical with it.  but then, how profitable  
is it to vote tactically when there is little probability to the  
conditions that would serve such tactical voting?


if it were one of those Condorcet methods and if there is little  
likelihood of a cycle happening and if a savvy voter knows that, how  
does it benefit his/her political interests to do anything other  
than vote for their fav as their first choice and cover their ass  
with a tolerable 2nd choice?  how are they ever (assuming no cycle)  
hurting their favorite or helping any unranked candidates (tied for  
last place, in this voter's esteem) beat the 2nd choice?  i really  
find it hard to see the tactical interests as differing from the  
sincere political interests.


r b-j




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-23 Thread robert bristow-johnson

> robert bristow-johnson wrote:
...
>> i dunno how to, other than take the raw ballot data of some existing IRV 
>> elections, but i would like to see how many of these municipal IRV 
>> elections, that if the ballots were tabulated according to Condorcet 
>> rules, that a cycle would occur.  

Kristofer Munsterhjelm wrote:
...
> I haven't run the data through my simulator yet, but it seems cycles are
> rare.

i have to confess that i am less worked up about what pathologies would result 
from a Condorcet cycle than i am about what pathologies result from FPTP or IRV 
(or Borda or whoever) failing to elect the Condorcet winner whether such 
exists.  we know the latter actually happens in governmental elections.  i 
still have my doubts to any significant prevalence of the former.

on the rare occasion a cycle ever happens, probably Tideman Ranked-Pairs would 
be the best compromise between a fairer Schulze beatpath and some method that 
has sufficient "lucidity" that voters can understand it and have confidence 
that no "funny business" is going on.  but whether it's beatpath or 
ranked-pairs or IRV rules as the method that resolves a cycle,  at least in 
this very rare occasion, it's picking a non-Condorcet winner meaningfully, even 
if there are conceptual ways to turn tactical with it.  but then, how 
profitable is it to vote tactically when there is little probability to the 
conditions that would serve such tactical voting?

if it were one of those Condorcet methods and if there is little likelihood of 
a cycle happening and if a savvy voter knows that, how does it benefit his/her 
political interests to do anything other than vote for their fav as their first 
choice and cover their ass with a tolerable 2nd choice?  how are they ever 
(assuming no cycle) hurting their favorite or helping any unranked candidates 
(tied for last place, in this voter's esteem) beat the 2nd choice?  i really 
find it hard to see the tactical interests as differing from the sincere 
political interests.

r b-j


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-23 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

Andrew Myers wrote:
I have ballot data from about 1500 elections run using CIVS. But I 
haven't had the time to write software to package it up nicely.


Could you use CIVS itself to quickly determine how many of them had 
proper Condorcet winners (i.e. Smith set of cardinality one)? That might 
be an interesting result and wouldn't take as long time as packaging up 
the data.


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-23 Thread Andrew Myers

Kristofer Munsterhjelm wrote:
Warren Smith has a copy of Tideman's election archive, as well as some 
other data, here: http://rangevoting.org/TidemanData.html


I haven't run the data through my simulator yet, but it seems cycles 
are rare.


There's also a database of STV elections at 
http://www.openstv.org/stvdb . While they could be processed by my 
program (if I write the correct converters), they are multiwinner 
elections and so the frequency of cycles might not be relevant to what 
would be the case for when voters are told the election is single-winner.


Does anybody know of any data sources apart from the above?
I have ballot data from about 1500 elections run using CIVS. But I 
haven't had the time to write software to package it up nicely.


-- Andrew

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-23 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Nov 23, 2009, at 1:43 AM, Dave Ketchum wrote:



Seems to me that cycles can occur even with sincerity - they relate to 
conflict among three or more voter views.



sure, they "can".  but i still question the prevalence of such 
happening.  and with the other methods, particularly the two used in 
governmental elections: FPTP and IRV, the prevalence of tactical voting 
(particularly compromising) is clear.  why is there so much worry about 
a pathology that just doesn't seem to occur often enough to be worth it 
when there seems to be plenty reason to worry about pathologies involved 
with the non-Condorcet methods?


i dunno how to, other than take the raw ballot data of some existing IRV 
elections, but i would like to see how many of these municipal IRV 
elections, that if the ballots were tabulated according to Condorcet 
rules, that a cycle would occur.  i know the answer for Burlington 2006 
and 2009 (no cycle in either case, the first case the IRV, Condorcet, 
and FPTP winner was the same person, the second case they were 3 
different persons, a clear pathology worth worrying about).  what about 
Cambridge MA or SF, anyone know?


Warren Smith has a copy of Tideman's election archive, as well as some 
other data, here: http://rangevoting.org/TidemanData.html


I haven't run the data through my simulator yet, but it seems cycles are 
rare.


There's also a database of STV elections at http://www.openstv.org/stvdb 
. While they could be processed by my program (if I write the correct 
converters), they are multiwinner elections and so the frequency of 
cycles might not be relevant to what would be the case for when voters 
are told the election is single-winner.


Does anybody know of any data sources apart from the above?

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-23 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Nov 23, 2009, at 1:43 AM, Dave Ketchum wrote:



Seems to me that cycles can occur even with sincerity - they relate  
to conflict among three or more voter views.



sure, they "can".  but i still question the prevalence of such  
happening.  and with the other methods, particularly the two used in  
governmental elections: FPTP and IRV, the prevalence of tactical  
voting (particularly compromising) is clear.  why is there so much  
worry about a pathology that just doesn't seem to occur often enough  
to be worth it when there seems to be plenty reason to worry about  
pathologies involved with the non-Condorcet methods?


i dunno how to, other than take the raw ballot data of some existing  
IRV elections, but i would like to see how many of these municipal  
IRV elections, that if the ballots were tabulated according to  
Condorcet rules, that a cycle would occur.  i know the answer for  
Burlington 2006 and 2009 (no cycle in either case, the first case the  
IRV, Condorcet, and FPTP winner was the same person, the second case  
they were 3 different persons, a clear pathology worth worrying  
about).  what about Cambridge MA or SF, anyone know?


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

"Imagination is more important than knowledge."





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-22 Thread Dave Ketchum

Trying to sort this out:
 Llull never heard of cycles, and did not have enough data to  
think of others doing more complex methods centuries later.
 River has the data, and Jobst explains, while describing River,  
that having defeat data, sorting defeats, and discarding defeats  
related to cycles, can result in a system competitive with the best  
other Condorcet methods.
 When Jobst wrote of "reverse Llull" his big topic was strategy.   
I do not see the protection that River included mentioned as attended  
to.


Seems to me that cycles can occur even with sincerity - they relate to  
conflict among three or more voter views.


Dave Ketchum

On Nov 19, 2009, at 7:55 PM, fsimm...@pcc.edu wrote:


Dave,

Jobst, the inventor of River, is well aware of the cycle problem,  
and Jobst
would never advocate public use of a Condorcet method that failed  
clone loser,
for example, but as near as I know his simple reverse Llull method  
is the first
Condorcet method that gives zero incentive for insincere rankings,  
even if
complete rankings are required (at least generically).  As a  
corollary, it
satisfies the Strong FBC.  No other extant Condorcet method does  
even that.


In other words it is a benchmark method.

It gives us something to shoot for; a clone free version of the  
same, for
example.  The complicated method you referred to was my crude  
attempt at that.


Forest




Dave Ketchum Wrote ...


Took me a while, but hope what I say is useful.



Jobst had good words, except he oversimplified.



Centuries ago Llull had an idea which Condorcet improved a bit -

compare each pair of candidates, and go with whoever wins in each
pair.  Works fine when there is a CW for, once the CW is found, it
will win every following comparison.


BUT, in our newer studying, we know that there is sometimes a cycle,

and NO CW.  Perhaps useful to take the N*N array from an election and
use its values as a test of Jobst's rules:
 There may be some comparisons before the CW wins one.  Then the
found CW will win all following comparisons.
 BUT, if no CW, you soon find a cycle member and cycle members
win all following comparisons, just as the CW did above.


Summary:

 We are into Condorcet with ranking and no approval cutoffs.
 Testing the N*N array for CW is easy enough, once you decide
what to do with ties.
 Deciding on rules for resolving cycles is a headache, but I
question involving anything for this other than the N*N array - such
as the complications Jobst and fsimmons offer.


Dave Ketchum




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-19 Thread fsimmons
Dave,

Jobst, the inventor of River, is well aware of the cycle problem, and Jobst
would never advocate public use of a Condorcet method that failed clone loser,
for example, but as near as I know his simple reverse Llull method is the first
Condorcet method that gives zero incentive for insincere rankings, even if
complete rankings are required (at least generically).  As a corollary, it
satisfies the Strong FBC.  No other extant Condorcet method does even that.

In other words it is a benchmark method.

It gives us something to shoot for; a clone free version of the same, for
example.  The complicated method you referred to was my crude attempt at that.

Forest




Dave Ketchum Wrote ...

>Took me a while, but hope what I say is useful.

>Jobst had good words, except he oversimplified.

>Centuries ago Llull had an idea which Condorcet improved a bit - 
compare each pair of candidates, and go with whoever wins in each 
pair.  Works fine when there is a CW for, once the CW is found, it 
will win every following comparison.

>BUT, in our newer studying, we know that there is sometimes a cycle, 
and NO CW.  Perhaps useful to take the N*N array from an election and 
use its values as a test of Jobst's rules:
  There may be some comparisons before the CW wins one.  Then the 
found CW will win all following comparisons.
  BUT, if no CW, you soon find a cycle member and cycle members 
win all following comparisons, just as the CW did above.

>Summary:
  We are into Condorcet with ranking and no approval cutoffs.
  Testing the N*N array for CW is easy enough, once you decide 
what to do with ties.
  Deciding on rules for resolving cycles is a headache, but I 
question involving anything for this other than the N*N array - such 
as the complications Jobst and fsimmons offer.

>Dave Ketchum

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-18 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Nov 18, 2009, at 6:25 PM, Dave Ketchum wrote:

BUT, in our newer studying, we know that there is sometimes a  
cycle, and NO CW.


there certainly *can* be a cycle.  since Condorcet is not yet used in  
governmental elections there is no track record there to say  
"sometimes".  have there been cases in organization elections (like  
Wikipedia and those listed in http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/ 
Schulze_method#Use_of_the_Schulze_method ) that evidently use a  
Condorcet method.  are there historical cases where there were cycles  
with any of those organizations?  or is it only the hypothesizing of  
election method scholars and commentators?  sure, we can create  
pathological cases where there is a cycle, but does it really happen?


i'm not saying it can't be expected to; when i voted for IRV for  
Burlington VT in 2005, i thought to myself that it would not likely  
ever elect a non-CW when a CW exists because we know that if the CW  
would have to be eliminated before the final IRV round.  that didn't  
happen in 2006, but that is exactly what happened in Burlington in  
2009.  so pathologies can happen even if we might guess they happen  
rarely.


but are there actual elections in some organizations where there was  
no CW?


  Perhaps useful to take the N*N array from an election and use its  
values as a test of Jobst's rules:
 There may be some comparisons before the CW wins one.  Then  
the found CW will win all following comparisons.
 BUT, if no CW, you soon find a cycle member and cycle members  
win all following comparisons, just as the CW did above.


Summary:
 We are into Condorcet with ranking and no approval cutoffs.
 Testing the N*N array for CW is easy enough, once you decide  
what to do with ties.
 Deciding on rules for resolving cycles is a headache, but I  
question involving anything for this other than the N*N array -  
such as the complications Jobst and fsimmons offer.


the outcome of resolving a Condorcet paradox should never depend on  
the chronological order that pairs are considered.  if the method  
does involving starting with a particular pair and proceeding to  
another pair (like Tideman would), it should come up with the same  
result, no matter which pair you happen to consider first.  and if a  
CW exists, the method should always pick the CW.


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

"Imagination is more important than knowledge."





On Nov 17, 2009, at 8:53 PM, fsimm...@pcc.edu wrote:


Here's a way to incorporate this idea for large groups:

Ballots are ordinal with approval cutoffs.

After the ballots are counted, list the candidates in order of  
approval.


Use just enough randomly chosen ballots to determine the Lull  
winner with 90%
confidence: let L(0) be the candidate with least approval.  Then  
for i = 0, 1,
2, ... move L(i) up the list until some candidate L(i+1) beats L 
(i) majority
pairwise (in the random sample). If the majority is so close that  
the required

confidence is not attained, then increase the sample size, etc.

Then with the entire ballots set, apply Jobst's Reverse Lull  
method:  Start with
candidate A at the top of the approval list.  If  a majority of  
the ballots rank
A above the Lull winner (i.e. the presumed winner if A is not  
elected) then
elect A. Otherwise, go down the list one candidate to candidate  
B.  Let L be the
top Lull winner with approval less than B.  If a majority of  
ballots rank B

above L, then elect B, else continue down the list in the same way.

In each case the comparison is of a candidate C with the L(i) with  
the most

approval less than C's approval.

If the decisions are all made in the same direction as in the  
sample, then the
Reverse Lull winner is the same as the Lull winner, but  
occasionally (about ten

percent of the time) there will be a surprise.

If a voter knew that her ballot was going to be used in the  
forward Lull sample,
she would be tempted to vote strategically.  But in a large  
election, most
voters would not be in the sample, so there would be little point  
in them voting
strategically.  If sincerity had any positive utility at all, it  
would be enough

to result in sincere rankings (in a large enough election).



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-18 Thread Dave Ketchum

Took me a while, but hope what I say is useful.

Jobst had good words, except he oversimplified.

Centuries ago Llull had an idea which Condorcet improved a bit -  
compare each pair of candidates, and go with whoever wins in each  
pair.  Works fine when there is a CW for, once the CW is found, it  
will win every following comparison.


BUT, in our newer studying, we know that there is sometimes a cycle,  
and NO CW.  Perhaps useful to take the N*N array from an election and  
use its values as a test of Jobst's rules:
 There may be some comparisons before the CW wins one.  Then the  
found CW will win all following comparisons.
 BUT, if no CW, you soon find a cycle member and cycle members  
win all following comparisons, just as the CW did above.


Summary:
 We are into Condorcet with ranking and no approval cutoffs.
 Testing the N*N array for CW is easy enough, once you decide  
what to do with ties.
 Deciding on rules for resolving cycles is a headache, but I  
question involving anything for this other than the N*N array - such  
as the complications Jobst and fsimmons offer.


Dave Ketchum

On Nov 17, 2009, at 8:53 PM, fsimm...@pcc.edu wrote:


Here's a way to incorporate this idea for large groups:

Ballots are ordinal with approval cutoffs.

After the ballots are counted, list the candidates in order of  
approval.


Use just enough randomly chosen ballots to determine the Lull winner  
with 90%
confidence: let L(0) be the candidate with least approval.  Then for  
i = 0, 1,
2, ... move L(i) up the list until some candidate L(i+1) beats L(i)  
majority
pairwise (in the random sample). If the majority is so close that  
the required

confidence is not attained, then increase the sample size, etc.

Then with the entire ballots set, apply Jobst's Reverse Lull  
method:  Start with
candidate A at the top of the approval list.  If  a majority of the  
ballots rank
A above the Lull winner (i.e. the presumed winner if A is not  
elected) then
elect A. Otherwise, go down the list one candidate to candidate B.   
Let L be the
top Lull winner with approval less than B.  If a majority of ballots  
rank B

above L, then elect B, else continue down the list in the same way.

In each case the comparison is of a candidate C with the L(i) with  
the most

approval less than C's approval.

If the decisions are all made in the same direction as in the  
sample, then the
Reverse Lull winner is the same as the Lull winner, but occasionally  
(about ten

percent of the time) there will be a surprise.

If a voter knew that her ballot was going to be used in the forward  
Lull sample,
she would be tempted to vote strategically.  But in a large  
election, most
voters would not be in the sample, so there would be little point in  
them voting
strategically.  If sincerity had any positive utility at all, it  
would be enough

to result in sincere rankings (in a large enough election).




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-17 Thread fsimmons
Here's a way to incorporate this idea for large groups:

Ballots are ordinal with approval cutoffs.

After the ballots are counted, list the candidates in order of approval.

Use just enough randomly chosen ballots to determine the Lull winner with 90%
confidence: let L(0) be the candidate with least approval.  Then for i = 0, 1,
2, ... move L(i) up the list until some candidate L(i+1) beats L(i) majority
pairwise (in the random sample). If the majority is so close that the required
confidence is not attained, then increase the sample size, etc.

Then with the entire ballots set, apply Jobst's Reverse Lull method:  Start with
candidate A at the top of the approval list.  If  a majority of the ballots rank
A above the Lull winner (i.e. the presumed winner if A is not elected) then
elect A. Otherwise, go down the list one candidate to candidate B.  Let L be the
top Lull winner with approval less than B.  If a majority of ballots rank B
above L, then elect B, else continue down the list in the same way.

In each case the comparison is of a candidate C with the L(i) with the most
approval less than C's approval.

If the decisions are all made in the same direction as in the sample, then the
Reverse Lull winner is the same as the Lull winner, but occasionally (about ten
percent of the time) there will be a surprise.

If a voter knew that her ballot was going to be used in the forward Lull sample,
she would be tempted to vote strategically.  But in a large election, most
voters would not be in the sample, so there would be little point in them voting
strategically.  If sincerity had any positive utility at all, it would be enough
to result in sincere rankings (in a large enough election).

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-16 Thread fsimmons
Here's a small group method for making decisions based on  Jobst's "Reverse 
Lull."

Randomly decide an ordering of the members of the group.

Vote approval style on each of the members in the given order.

If no member receives more than fifty percent approval, then the last member in 
the order makes the 
decision.

Otherwise, the first member to receive more than fifty percent approval makes 
the decision.

If I am not mistaken, this method is clone independent; either cloning the 
winning alternative nor cloning 
any losing alternative should make a difference in the choice. 

Of course the random order can make a difference, but the randomness doesn't 
detract from the fairness.

.

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-15 Thread Juho
One can thwart strategic voting in general by hiding the algorithm  
that makes the decision who wins. Instead of collecting perfect poll  
information (that voters are supposed to use accurately when they  
decide how to vote) one could upgrade the poll answers to actual  
ranked votes. The randomness / uncertainty could be introduced by  
determining the rules (in the case of a top level cycle) only after  
the votes have been collected (e.g. in using the randomization  
mechanism of the reverse Llull method).


If the method is Condorcet compliant voters may try to create a top  
level cycle if they don't like the expected Condorcet winner (that  
they guess based on some earlier polls etc.). Artificial cycles  
however typically include also candidates that are worse than the  
current winner and the candidate that one tries to promote. If one can  
not guess which one of the cycle members (or other candidates if that  
is allowed) will win then the benefits of strategic voting may easily  
be close to zero.


Polls are usually more sincere than actual votes. But actual votes may  
be one step more sincere if voting is heavily based on the polls but  
one's actual vote is independent of what one said in the polls.


The basic procedure was thus to collect ranked votes first and only  
after that decide the randomish procedure / algorithm input that is  
then used to decide which one of the "almost tied leading candidates"  
wins.


Juho



On Nov 14, 2009, at 2:32 PM, Jobst Heitzig wrote:


Dear folks,

it seems there is a stragegy-free Condorcet method after all -- say
good-bye to burying, strategic truncation and their relatives!

More precisely, I believe that at least in case of complete  
information
(all voters knowing some details about the true preferences of all  
other
voters) and when all voters will follow dominating strategies, then  
the
following astonishingly simple method will always make unanimous  
sincere

voting the unique dominating strategy, and it will always elect a true
beats-all winner (=Condorcet winner):


Method: Reverse Llull
=

1. Sort the options into some arbitrary ordering X1,...,Xn (e.g.
alphabetically or randomly), publish this ordering, and put i=n.

2. If already i=1, then X1 is the winner. Otherwise, ask all voters
whether they prefer Xi or the option they expect to be the winner of
applying this method to the remaining options X1,...,X(i-1).

3. If more voters prefer Xi, Xi is the winner. Otherwise, decrease i  
by

1 and repeat steps 2 and 3.


Why should this be strategy-free?

If n=2, the question in step 2 is whether X1 or X2 is preferred and  
the

method is traditional majority choice in which sincere voting is known
to be the dominant strategy in case of 2 options.

For n>2, we prove strategy-freeness inductively, assuming it has been
proved for n-1 options already: Since we assume that each voter  
follows

dominant strategies and knows enough about the other voter's
preferences, and since each voters knows that sincere voting is the
unique dominant strategy for all cases of at most n-1 options, she  
will

know in step 2 which option Xj would win if the method was applied to
X1,...,X(i-1), and she will also know that her vote at this step does
not influence which option Xj is but only whether Xi or Xj will win.
That is, in step 2 all voters face a simple majority choice between  
two

known options Xi and Xj, so again voting sincerely in this step is the
unique dominant strategy. By induction, the whole method is strategy- 
free.



The method is in some sense the reverse of Llull's famous earliest  
known
"Condorcet' method from the 13th century (cited recently on this  
list):

In the classical Llull method, voters would first make a majority
decision between X1 and X2, then a majority choice between the  
winner of

the first choice and X3, and so on working thru the whole list of
options, always keeping the last winner and comparing it with the next
option in the list. The overall winner is the winner of the last  
comparison.


So, the only difference between classical Llull and Reverse Llull is  
the

order in which these pairwise comparisons are done. If we assume all
voters vote sincerely in classical Llull, both method would be
equivalent. But with strategic voters, the difference is important: In
classical Llull, a voter's voting behaviour in one step can influence
the results of the later steps (because it can influence which  
candidate

"stays in the ring"), whereas in Reverse Llull it cannot.


In practice, the method can be sped-up by using approval-style ballots
on which each voter marks after step 1 every option Xi which she  
prefers

to the expected winner of the subset X1,...,X(i-1).

As for additional properties, Reverse Llull is Pareto-efficient,
Smith-efficient (i.e. elects a member of the Smith set), and  
monotonic,

but not clone-proof.

I wonder if we can also find a clone-proof version of this... Any  
ide

Re: [EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-14 Thread Warren Smith
Think some more re Jobst Heitzig's "Reverse Llull" method,
I think "strategy-free" is not the right phrase to describe it.

Why? Heitzig's recommended way to vote is totally strategic (!), i.e.
heavily dependent
on that voter's info about what all the other voters are doing.

By that reasoning, any strategic vote in ANY voting method is "honest"
provided the voter, when deciding on her strategic vote, is asked
(e.g. by her PC) a number of questions about both her preferences and
about her perceptions of the other voters, and she answers them all
honestly in order to generate the strategic vote!

Well, no.

But what Heitzig really does accomplish, is: he has a voting method
where voters, BY ACTING STRATEGICALLY, will elect the honest-voter
Condorcet winner (when one exists).

Now with ordinary approval and range voting, it is an already known theorem, see
http://rangevoting.org/AppCW.html
that voters, BY VOTING STRATEGICALLY, will always elect the honest-voter
Condorcet winner (when one exists).  It is assumed that
they choose their strategic vote in a certain (realistic) manner, and
they have enough information about the other voters to do so...  in
particular, they do not need to have perfect info about the other
votes, they merely need to know enough to know
who the Condorcet winner C, and who the approval-voting winner would
be if it were not C, are.

-- 
Warren D. Smith
http://RangeVoting.org  <-- add your endorsement (by clicking
"endorse" as 1st step)
and
math.temple.edu/~wds/homepage/works.html

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


[EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-14 Thread Warren Smith
Jobst Heitzig's "Reverse Llull" method was intended to
(1) elect Condorcet winners (under the assumption one exists)
(2) cause strategic and honest voting to be the same thing (at least,
under perfect info assumptions)

It would be better to replace his goal #1 by this better goal
(1') elect the max-summed-utility winner
but unfortunately I cannot see any way to accomplish that.

-

To make it crystal clear that (as I said before, but with less
clarity) the Reverse Llull winner can depend on the candidate
pre-ordering, consider an A>B>C>A Condorcet cycle.

Assume the Heitzig ordering is A,B,C.  Clearly with no C, the winner would be A.
So voters will "approve" C (since C>A says a majority) and it will win.
Arguing symmetrically, any one of the three will win, depending on
the Heitzig pre-ordering.

So it appears that with random pre-ordering, every member of a
top-cycle will be equally likely to be the winner with Reverse Llull.

---

I believe it is shown in one of the puzzles on the CRV puzzle page,
that with random votes in the limit of a large number of candidates
and voters,  the probability-->1
that EVERY candidate is a member of a top cycle ("pan-cyclicity")
so that with probability-->1 for a "random election" Reverse Llull just becomes
"random winner."  This, of course, is very poor in terms of Bayesian Regret
compared with (say) approval voting.

So all in all, despite Reverse Llull's beauty, a case could be made that
plain approval voting is better...

-- 
Warren D. Smith
http://RangeVoting.org  <-- add your endorsement (by clicking
"endorse" as 1st step)
and
math.temple.edu/~wds/homepage/works.html

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-14 Thread Warren Smith
(Same post as before, but with annoying typos corrected.)
> Jobst Heitzig (with slight editing by me):
>Method: Reverse Llull
>=
>1. Sort the options into some arbitrary ordering X1,...,Xn (e.g.
>alphabetically or randomly), publish this ordering, and put i=n.
 WDS: will different orderings yield different results? ("Agenda
 manipulation"?)

>2. If already i=1, then X1 is the winner. Otherwise, ask all voters
>whether they prefer Xi or the option they expect to be the winner of
>applying this method to the remaining options X1,...,X(i-1).
 WDS: a slight altering in wording would be "or the expected utility of
  the winner when applying this method to the remaining options X1,...,X(i-1)."
 This change makes no difference under the perfect info assumption that the
 voter can predict the winer 100% accurately, but does make a difference if
 imperfect info.

>3. If more voters prefer Xi, Xi is the winner. Otherwise, decrease i by
>1 and repeat steps 2 and 3.

>Why should this be strategy-free?

>If n=2, the question in step 2 is whether X1 or X2 is preferred and the
>method is traditional majority choice in which sincere voting is known
>to be the dominant strategy in case of 2 options.

>For n>2, we prove strategy-freeness inductively, assuming it has been
>proved for n-1 options already: Since we assume that each voter follows
>dominant strategies and knows enough about the other voter's
>preferences, and since each voters knows that sincere voting is the
>unique dominant strategy for all cases of at most n-1 options, she will
>know in step 2 which option Xj would win if the method was applied to
>X1,...,X(i-1), and she will also know that her vote at this step does
>not influence which option Xj is but only whether Xi or Xj will win.
>That is, in step 2 all voters face a simple majority choice between two
>known options Xi and Xj, so again voting sincerely in this step is the
>unique dominant strategy. By induction, the whole method is strategy-free.

>The method is in some sense the reverse of Llull's famous earliest known
>"Condorcet' method from the 13th century ...

 ---

 Fascinating.   Now I suppose one could argue in the same manner
 that the voter can provide all (n-1) of her votes ahead of time, as n-1
 binary "bits."  Which would actually be n bits if an extra (unused)
vote-bit also
 were provided for X1.  Note this then is an approval-voting-style ballot.
 Now suppose the candidate ordering happens to be
 the ordering in decreasing likelihood of victory.
 The "moving mean" strategy for approval voting (actually applicable to
 a wide class of kinds of voting, which I defined many years ago...)
 is precisely the following.

 1. order the candidates in decreasing likelihood of victory.
 2. approve exactly one of the first two candidates (whichever you prefer).
 3. go thru the remaining candidates in order, approving/disapproving
 each, if you prefer/not him versus the average utility among
 the preceding candidates.

One really should use weighted average weighted by conditional
 probability of victory -- though I had in mind unweighted average at
 that time, based on the theory that under certain circumstances they
 were going to be effectively the same thing.  When deciding on the
 approval of X[k+1] the probabilities for X1,X2,...,Xk need to be
 conditioned on the assumption that X[k+1]  is going to have a decent
 chance to win, i.e. is near-tied with the leader among X1,X2,...Xk,
 while X[k+2],...,Xn are regarded as having negligible winning chances.

 If this ordering happens to coincide with the one used by Jobst Heitzig,
 then the moving-mean-strategy approval ballot, will coincide with
 honest=strategic reverse-Llull voting.

 Now the following alternative vote-tallying algorithm will elect Jobst
 Heitzig's same winner:
 1. go thru the candidates in reverse order (n, n-1, n-2,..., 2, 1)
 2. As soon as you find a candidate with more than 50% approval, elect him.
 3. If no such candidate exists, elect X1 (but in fact, with Heitzian
 "honest" voting, i.e. Smithian moving-mean-strategic voting, one will
always exist, so X1's election would have been automatic without need
for rule 3).

 This way of rewording the algorithm seems to make it pretty clear that
 the winner CAN depend on the ordering.  (Answering my own question
 above.) Therefore, this method (if deterministic) disobeys
 "neutrality."

 A method which, however, is similar and happens to obey "neutrality"
 is plain old
 APPROVAL VOTING.

Observe that if a Condorcet winner exists, then it automatically is
unique and automatically is elected, both by Reverse Llull, and (with
the same votes) by ordinary approval voting.

They only can differ in circumstances where no Condorcet winner exists.


-- 
Warren D. Smith
http://RangeVoting.org  <-- add your endorsement (by clicking
"endorse" as 1st step)
and
math.temple.edu/~wds/homepage/works.html

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for 

[EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-14 Thread Warren Smith
> Jobst Heitzig (with slight editing by me):
>Method: Reverse Llull
>=
>1. Sort the options into some arbitrary ordering X1,...,Xn (e.g.
>alphabetically or randomly), publish this ordering, and put i=n.
WDS: will different orderings yield different results? ("Agenda manipulation"?)

>2. If already i=1, then X1 is the winner. Otherwise, ask all voters
>whether they prefer Xi or the option they expect to be the winner of
>applying this method to the remaining options X1,...,X(i-1).
WDS: a slight altering in wording would be "or the expected utility of
 the option they expect to be the winner of
 applying this method to the remaining options X1,...,X(i-1)."
This change makes no difference under the perfect info assumption that the
voter can predict the winer 100% accurately, but does make a difference if
imperfect info.

>3. If more voters prefer Xi, Xi is the winner. Otherwise, decrease i by
>1 and repeat steps 2 and 3.

>Why should this be strategy-free?

>If n=2, the question in step 2 is whether X1 or X2 is preferred and the
>method is traditional majority choice in which sincere voting is known
>to be the dominant strategy in case of 2 options.

>For n>2, we prove strategy-freeness inductively, assuming it has been
>proved for n-1 options already: Since we assume that each voter follows
>dominant strategies and knows enough about the other voter's
>preferences, and since each voters knows that sincere voting is the
>unique dominant strategy for all cases of at most n-1 options, she will
>know in step 2 which option Xj would win if the method was applied to
>X1,...,X(i-1), and she will also know that her vote at this step does
>not influence which option Xj is but only whether Xi or Xj will win.
>That is, in step 2 all voters face a simple majority choice between two
>known options Xi and Xj, so again voting sincerely in this step is the
>unique dominant strategy. By induction, the whole method is strategy-free.

>The method is in some sense the reverse of Llull's famous earliest known
>"Condorcet' method from the 13th century ...

---

Fascinating.   Now I suppose one could argue in the same manner
that the voter can provide all (n-1) of her votes ahead of time, as n-1 binary
"bits."  Which would actually be n bits if an extra (unused) vote-bit also
were provided for X1.  Note this then is an approval-voting-style ballot.
Now suppose the candidate ordering happens to be
the ordering in decreasing likelihood of victory.
The "moving mean" strategy for approval voting (actually applicable to
a wide class of kinds of voting, which I defined many years ago...)
is precisely the following.

1. order the candidates in decreasing likelihood of victory.
2. approve exactly one of the first two candidates (whichever you prefer).
3. go thru the remaining candidates in order, approving/disapproving
each, if you prefer/not him versus the average utility among
the preceding candidates.

   One really should use weighted average weighted by conditional
probability of victory -- though I had in mind unweighted average at
that time, based on the theory that under certain circumstances they
were going to be effectively the same thing.  Wehn deciding on the
approval or X[k+1] the probabilities for X1,X2,...,Xk need to be
conditioned on the assumption that X[k+1]  is going to have a decent
chance to win, i.e. is near-tied with the leader among X1,X2,...Xk,
while X[k+2],...,Xn are regarded as having negligible winning chances.

If this ordering happens to coincide with the one used by Jobst Heitzig, then
the moving-mean-strategy approval ballot, will coincide with honest=strategic
reverse-Llull voting.

Now the following alternative vote-tallying algorithm will elect Jobst
Heitzig's same winner:
1. go thru the candidates in reverse order (n, n-1, n-2,..., 2, 1)
2. As soon as you find a candidate with more than 50% approval, elect him.
3. If no such candidate exists, elect X1 (but in fact, with Heitzian
"honest" voting,
i.e. Smithian moving-mean-strategic voting, one will always exist, so
X1's election would have been automatic without need for rule 3).

This way of rewording the algorithm seems to make it pretty clear that
the winner CAN depend on the ordering.  (Answering my own question
above.) Therefore, this method (if deterministic) disobeys
"neutrality."

A method which, however, is similar and happens to obey "neutrality"
is plain old
APPROVAL VOTING.

Observe that if a Condorcet winner exists, then it automatically is
unique and automatically
is elected, both by Reverse Llull, and (with the same votes) by
ordinary approval voting.

They only can differ in circumstances where no Condorcet winner exists.




-- 
Warren D. Smith
http://RangeVoting.org  <-- add your endorsement (by clicking
"endorse" as 1st step)
and
math.temple.edu/~wds/homepage/works.html

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-14 Thread Juho

Very nice construction.

The first strategic thought in my mind is to give false poll  
information since the method relies on that information to be  
available. Let's see what happens with a simple loop of three.


1: A>B>C
1: B>C>A
1: C>A>B

The A supporter is strategic, so the poll results could be as follows.
1: B>A>C or B>C>A
1: B>C>A
1: C>A>B
=> the falsified strategic preferences indicate B>C>A

Depending on the ordering any one of the candidates could be the one  
that will be checked first. The A supporter will not know which one  
when giving the poll answer IF the ordering will be decided only just  
before (the first round of) the election.


- A will be checked first => A will be elected (since the C supporter  
is afraid that B would win A)
- B will be checked first => B will be elected (the A supporter votes  
for B since A would lose to C if B would not be elected)
- C will be checked first => C will not be elected (since the B  
supporter thinks that B will win A) => A will win since A is preferred  
over B


In this example the A supporter was able to improve the results. There  
could thus be some false information in the polls (or in the  
discussions between these three voters).


Juho


P.S. The A supporter could also try C>B>A in the poll.



On Nov 14, 2009, at 2:32 PM, Jobst Heitzig wrote:


Dear folks,

it seems there is a stragegy-free Condorcet method after all -- say
good-bye to burying, strategic truncation and their relatives!

More precisely, I believe that at least in case of complete  
information
(all voters knowing some details about the true preferences of all  
other
voters) and when all voters will follow dominating strategies, then  
the
following astonishingly simple method will always make unanimous  
sincere

voting the unique dominating strategy, and it will always elect a true
beats-all winner (=Condorcet winner):


Method: Reverse Llull
=

1. Sort the options into some arbitrary ordering X1,...,Xn (e.g.
alphabetically or randomly), publish this ordering, and put i=n.

2. If already i=1, then X1 is the winner. Otherwise, ask all voters
whether they prefer Xi or the option they expect to be the winner of
applying this method to the remaining options X1,...,X(i-1).

3. If more voters prefer Xi, Xi is the winner. Otherwise, decrease i  
by

1 and repeat steps 2 and 3.


Why should this be strategy-free?

If n=2, the question in step 2 is whether X1 or X2 is preferred and  
the

method is traditional majority choice in which sincere voting is known
to be the dominant strategy in case of 2 options.

For n>2, we prove strategy-freeness inductively, assuming it has been
proved for n-1 options already: Since we assume that each voter  
follows

dominant strategies and knows enough about the other voter's
preferences, and since each voters knows that sincere voting is the
unique dominant strategy for all cases of at most n-1 options, she  
will

know in step 2 which option Xj would win if the method was applied to
X1,...,X(i-1), and she will also know that her vote at this step does
not influence which option Xj is but only whether Xi or Xj will win.
That is, in step 2 all voters face a simple majority choice between  
two

known options Xi and Xj, so again voting sincerely in this step is the
unique dominant strategy. By induction, the whole method is strategy- 
free.



The method is in some sense the reverse of Llull's famous earliest  
known
"Condorcet' method from the 13th century (cited recently on this  
list):

In the classical Llull method, voters would first make a majority
decision between X1 and X2, then a majority choice between the  
winner of

the first choice and X3, and so on working thru the whole list of
options, always keeping the last winner and comparing it with the next
option in the list. The overall winner is the winner of the last  
comparison.


So, the only difference between classical Llull and Reverse Llull is  
the

order in which these pairwise comparisons are done. If we assume all
voters vote sincerely in classical Llull, both method would be
equivalent. But with strategic voters, the difference is important: In
classical Llull, a voter's voting behaviour in one step can influence
the results of the later steps (because it can influence which  
candidate

"stays in the ring"), whereas in Reverse Llull it cannot.


In practice, the method can be sped-up by using approval-style ballots
on which each voter marks after step 1 every option Xi which she  
prefers

to the expected winner of the subset X1,...,X(i-1).

As for additional properties, Reverse Llull is Pareto-efficient,
Smith-efficient (i.e. elects a member of the Smith set), and  
monotonic,

but not clone-proof.

I wonder if we can also find a clone-proof version of this... Any  
ideas?



Yours, Jobst

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for  
list info



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list i

Re: [EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-14 Thread fsimmons
Very ingenious!Perhaps the method could be adapted some way to choose a clone 
class, thenĀ  a sub clone class within the winning clone class, etc.- 
Original Message -From: Jobst Heitzig Date: Saturday, November 14, 2009 
4:32 amSubject: strategy-free Condorcet method after all!To: EM Cc: Forest W 
Simmons > Dear folks,> > it seems there is a stragegy-free Condorcet method 
after all -- say> good-bye to burying, strategic truncation and their 
relatives!> > More precisely, I believe that at least in case of complete > 
information(all voters knowing some details about the true > preferences of all 
other> voters) and when all voters will follow dominating strategies, > then 
the> following astonishingly simple method will always make unanimous > 
sincerevoting the unique dominating strategy, and it will always > elect a 
true> beats-all winner (=Condorcet winner):> > > Method: Reverse Llull> 
=> > 1. Sort the options into some arbitrary ordering 
X1,...,Xn (e.g.> alphabetically or randomly), publish this ordering, and put 
i=n.> > 2. If already i=1, then X1 is the winner. Otherwise, ask all voters> 
whether they prefer Xi or the option they expect to be the > winner of> 
applying this method to the remaining options X1,...,X(i-1).> > 3. If more 
voters prefer Xi, Xi is the winner. Otherwise, > decrease i by> 1 and repeat 
steps 2 and 3.> > > Why should this be strategy-free?> > If n=2, the question 
in step 2 is whether X1 or X2 is preferred > and the> method is traditional 
majority choice in which sincere voting is known> to be the dominant strategy 
in case of 2 options.> > For n>2, we prove strategy-freeness inductively, 
assuming it has been> proved for n-1 options already: Since we assume that each 
voter > followsdominant strategies and knows enough about the other voter's> 
preferences, and since each voters knows that sincere voting is the> unique 
dominant strategy for all cases of at most n-1 options, > she will> know in 
step 2 which option Xj would win if the method was > applied to> X1,...,X(i-1), 
and she will also know that her vote at this step does> not influence which 
option Xj is but only whether Xi or Xj will win.> That is, in step 2 all voters 
face a simple majority choice > between two> known options Xi and Xj, so again 
voting sincerely in this step > is the> unique dominant strategy. By induction, 
the whole method is > strategy-free.> > > The method is in some sense the 
reverse of Llull's famous > earliest known> "Condorcet' method from the 13th 
century (cited recently on this > list):In the classical Llull method, voters 
would first make a > majoritydecision between X1 and X2, then a majority choice 
> between the winner of> the first choice and X3, and so on working thru the 
whole list of> options, always keeping the last winner and comparing it with > 
the next> option in the list. The overall winner is the winner of the last > 
comparison.> So, the only difference between classical Llull and Reverse > 
Llull is the> order in which these pairwise comparisons are done. If we assume 
all> voters vote sincerely in classical Llull, both method would be> 
equivalent. But with strategic voters, the difference is > important: In> 
classical Llull, a voter's voting behaviour in one step can influence> the 
results of the later steps (because it can influence which > candidate"stays in 
the ring"), whereas in Reverse Llull it cannot.> > > In practice, the method 
can be sped-up by using approval-style ballots> on which each voter marks after 
step 1 every option Xi which she > prefersto the expected winner of the subset 
X1,...,X(i-1).> > As for additional properties, Reverse Llull is 
Pareto-efficient,> Smith-efficient (i.e. elects a member of the Smith set), and 
> monotonic,but not clone-proof.> > I wonder if we can also find a clone-proof 
version of this... > Any ideas?> > > Yours, Jobst>

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


[EM] strategy-free Condorcet method after all!

2009-11-14 Thread Jobst Heitzig
Dear folks,

it seems there is a stragegy-free Condorcet method after all -- say
good-bye to burying, strategic truncation and their relatives!

More precisely, I believe that at least in case of complete information
(all voters knowing some details about the true preferences of all other
voters) and when all voters will follow dominating strategies, then the
following astonishingly simple method will always make unanimous sincere
voting the unique dominating strategy, and it will always elect a true
beats-all winner (=Condorcet winner):


Method: Reverse Llull
=

1. Sort the options into some arbitrary ordering X1,...,Xn (e.g.
alphabetically or randomly), publish this ordering, and put i=n.

2. If already i=1, then X1 is the winner. Otherwise, ask all voters
whether they prefer Xi or the option they expect to be the winner of
applying this method to the remaining options X1,...,X(i-1).

3. If more voters prefer Xi, Xi is the winner. Otherwise, decrease i by
1 and repeat steps 2 and 3.


Why should this be strategy-free?

If n=2, the question in step 2 is whether X1 or X2 is preferred and the
method is traditional majority choice in which sincere voting is known
to be the dominant strategy in case of 2 options.

For n>2, we prove strategy-freeness inductively, assuming it has been
proved for n-1 options already: Since we assume that each voter follows
dominant strategies and knows enough about the other voter's
preferences, and since each voters knows that sincere voting is the
unique dominant strategy for all cases of at most n-1 options, she will
know in step 2 which option Xj would win if the method was applied to
X1,...,X(i-1), and she will also know that her vote at this step does
not influence which option Xj is but only whether Xi or Xj will win.
That is, in step 2 all voters face a simple majority choice between two
known options Xi and Xj, so again voting sincerely in this step is the
unique dominant strategy. By induction, the whole method is strategy-free.


The method is in some sense the reverse of Llull's famous earliest known
"Condorcet' method from the 13th century (cited recently on this list):
In the classical Llull method, voters would first make a majority
decision between X1 and X2, then a majority choice between the winner of
the first choice and X3, and so on working thru the whole list of
options, always keeping the last winner and comparing it with the next
option in the list. The overall winner is the winner of the last comparison.

So, the only difference between classical Llull and Reverse Llull is the
order in which these pairwise comparisons are done. If we assume all
voters vote sincerely in classical Llull, both method would be
equivalent. But with strategic voters, the difference is important: In
classical Llull, a voter's voting behaviour in one step can influence
the results of the later steps (because it can influence which candidate
"stays in the ring"), whereas in Reverse Llull it cannot.


In practice, the method can be sped-up by using approval-style ballots
on which each voter marks after step 1 every option Xi which she prefers
to the expected winner of the subset X1,...,X(i-1).

As for additional properties, Reverse Llull is Pareto-efficient,
Smith-efficient (i.e. elects a member of the Smith set), and monotonic,
but not clone-proof.

I wonder if we can also find a clone-proof version of this... Any ideas?


Yours, Jobst

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info