[PEN-L:9765] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread blairs

I just heard a description of the "Rethinking Marxism" conference that
occurred in Amherst late last year. The reporter (Olga Celle de Bowman, a
sociologist from Peru) said that there was a tremendous amount of (verbal)
conflict between the audience and the speakers at the plenaries, something
I hadn't heard about before. She said that the activists in the audience
were objecting to the lack of answers to the key "what is to be done?"
question and the lack of any kind of orientation toward people outside of
academe. Was anyone on pen-l at the conference and has a different
perspective on the conflict?




in pen-l solidarity,

Jim Devine   [EMAIL PROTECTED]
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
Econ. Dept., Loyola Marymount Univ.
7900 Loyola Blvd., Los Angeles, CA 90045-8410 USA
310/338-2948 (daytime, during workweek); FAX: 310/338-1950
"It takes a busload of faith to get by." -- Lou Reed.

Several people on PEN-L were at the conference and will undoubtedly offer
different perspectives, but the bottom line is that a bunch of orthodox
marxists were upset that suggestions from speakers were not the same as the
answers offered by orthodox marxists. Because we know that orthodox marxism
has all the answers. oh well.






Blair Sandler
[EMAIL PROTECTED]







[PEN-L:9767] Re: Globaloney

1997-05-01 Thread Doug Henwood

D Shniad wrote:

The growth in the speculative power of finance capital, the magnitude of
which dwarfs that of productive capital, has increased enormously over the
past 20+ years and undermined the mechanisms that were put in place
over the postwar period to prevent a recurrence of the disaster of the
speculative '20s followed by the deflationary '30s.

People say these things all the time without detailing the relations
between "speculative" and real activity - I think they assume that Keynes
was right about those links in chapter 12 of the GT, which he wasn't
really. Are you talking about pure financial speculation, the undermining
of the social safety net, the undermining of the financial safety net
(which happened in the 1980s, but I have my doubts about how weak it is in
the 1990s), the leveraging up of balance sheets (true of U.S. households in
the 1990s, but not of U.S. corporations, which have reduced debt since the
1980s), capital flight punishing any left-of-center government, or what?


Doug

--

Doug Henwood
Left Business Observer
250 W 85 St
New York NY 10024-3217 USA
+1-212-874-4020 voice  +1-212-874-3137 fax
email: mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
web: http://www.panix.com/~dhenwood/LBO_home.html







[PEN-L:9768] Essentialist humor

1997-05-01 Thread Wojtek Sokolowski

A panda walks into a restaurant, sits down, and orders a sandwich.  After
finishing the sandwich, the panda pulls out a gun and shoots the waiter dead.  

As the panda stands up to leave, the mangers shouts, "Hey! Where are you
going?  You just shot my waiter and you did not pay your bill!"

The panda yells back to the restaurant manager, "Hey buddy, I'm a panda!
Look it up!" And walks out.

Nonplussed, the manager opens his dictionary and finds the following definition:

   Panda: A tree dwelling mammal of Asian origin, characterised by distinct
  black and white coloring.  Eats shoots and leaves.

wojtek sokolowski 
institute for policy studies
johns hopkins university
baltimore, md 21218
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
voice: (410) 516-4056
fax:   (410) 516-8233


** REDUCE MENTAL POLLUTION - LOBOTOMIZE PUNDITS! **
+--+
|There is  no such thing as society,  only the individuals | 
|who constitute it. -Margaret Thatcher |
|  | 
|  | 
|There is  no  such thing  as  government or  corporations,|
|only  the  individuals  who  lust  for  power  and  money.|
|   -no apologies to Margaret Thatcher |
+--+
*DROGI KURWA BUDUJA, A NIE MA DOKAD ISC






[PEN-L:9770] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread Doug Henwood

[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

Several people on PEN-L were at the conference and will undoubtedly offer
different perspectives, but the bottom line is that a bunch of orthodox
marxists were upset that suggestions from speakers were not the same as the
answers offered by orthodox marxists. Because we know that orthodox marxism
has all the answers. oh well.

Now Blair, I knew you were a partisan, but I thought you were a fair guy.

First of all, the most prominent "orthodox Marxist" dissenters were not
quite the dinosaurs your use of that epithet implies - the most prominent
was a young Indian woman who's a grad student in English at Cornell, who,
among other things, argues that the picutre painted of "orthodox Marxists"
by pomos is highly inaccurate. She cites, for example, vigorous debates
within Indian Marxism about issues like nationality and gender of just the
sort that pomos flatter themselves into thinking they originated.

And second, there was a great deal of discontent about the makeup of the
plenary panels, which were *all* - to replicate this binary that we're all
playing with even though we're all too sophisticated to fall prey to such
devious dyads - partisan pomos. A panel inspired by Alan Sokal consisting
of Vandana Shiva and Sandra Harding isn't likely to offer any real exchange
of views, is it? Especially when you have Harding, who seems from what I've
read and heard of her to be a bit of a fool, flickering her fingers
ceilingward to evoke the "hole in the atmosphere, up there, you know." Or
Judith Butler, who is certainly no fool, denouncing "neoconservative
Marxists" in a mode of pure caricature. Or Roger Burbach slamming me,
without offering any evidence or argument in his support.

There was also a lot of discontent that Etienne Balibar, who was supposed
to be having an exchange on race with Cornel West, gassed on for about 90
minutes with no exchange in sight.

The one-sided makeup of the plenaries was proof, I think, that
postmodernism has hardened into the kind of, dare I say it, hegemonic
orthodoxy that it fancies itself a critique of. Fortunately, there were
enough dissenters in the audience and on the smaller panels to make the
conference an interesting one. Too bad the plenary organizers took any
criticism of their work as personal insults.


Doug

--

Doug Henwood
Left Business Observer
250 W 85 St
New York NY 10024-3217 USA
+1-212-874-4020 voice  +1-212-874-3137 fax
email: mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
web: http://www.panix.com/~dhenwood/LBO_home.html







[PEN-L:9774] Re: Barbara Ehrenreich on War

1997-05-01 Thread Wojtek Sokolowski

While I generally agree with Louis' argument, I also believe that his
argument would have gained from making a distinction between spontaneous and
institutionalised behaviour.  In essence, the bourgeois pundits argue that
bourgeois social institutions originate in the law of human nature.
Ehrenreich follows the suit, but adds: "let's change human nature (as if it
were a yuppie life style) to get rid of the institution.

Of course, similar arguments are raised re. any other institution.  Property
relations, we are told, originate in the "natural" desire to acquire useful
materila goods.  Racism originates in our "natural" propensity to stereotype
or fear people who are different than ourselves.  And so on, and so forth.

The appeal of this mythology is that the antecedent asserting that "people
tend to engage in conflicting, hoarding, or stereotypong behaviour" is
essentially true.  But despite that, the argument is a nonsequitur, because
it was constructed in a flawed manner.  In essence, it is a logical fallacy
known as confirming the antecedent; e.g. "if people are bellicose by nature,
then wars are frequent; "wars are freguent; ergo: people are bellicose in
nature."  According to the same logic "if Richard M. Nixon was assassinated,
then Richard M. Nixon is dead; Richard M. Nixon is dead, ergo: Richard M.
Nixon was assassinated."

Distinguishing between spontaneous and institutionalised behaviour, the
former falls on a continuum ranging between "good" and "bad", "selfish" and
"selfless" "rational" and irrational" and so forth.  In short, we are
capable of any sort of behaviour.  The role of social instituions is to
encourage some of those behaviours while discouraging others.  It is like a
bullhorn -- it amplifies only certain sounds (namely the speech of the
person who holds it), but it does not pick up (or even drowns) other sounds.

With that in mind, it is easy to see that social institutions, like war,
private property, division of labour, or racism, are maintained by those in
a position to do so, namely -- the ruling classes who also control the means
of mental production.  

There is another question, however, how these institutions are being
established and maintained.  Louis  suggests that they are being simply
imposed by the ruling class  -- but such a view simply does not hold water.
A more useful view is that while social institutions do serve the interests
of the elite, they also serve, in various ways (that may or may not
correspond with the interests of the elites), various interests and needs of
the ruled.  In other words, the ruled collaborate, willingly and
unadvertently, with the elites in the creation and maintenance of social
institutions.

Examples are abundant.  Michael Burawoy (_Manufacturing Consent_) shows how
workers in Chicago manufacturing plants use capitalist institutions
(competition) for their own purposes that have little to do with the
preservation of capitalism.  In the same vein, part of the Blach population
in South Africa (the Bantu-stan elites) were staunch supporters of the
appertheid, because it gave them a relatively privileged position over other
Blacks (something that they would not be able to maintain under a democratic
rule).  In the same vein, the nazis coopeted the women liberation movement
in Germany (see Klaudia Koontz, _Mothers in the Fatherland_).

I think a common mistake of the old day socialists is a belief that the
masses would revolt againts their rulers as soon as an opportunity arises
and, even more importantly,  the revolutionary vanguard will give a signal.
I am afraid it ain't so.  

One of the most frightening powers of the state and social institutions
(modern and ancient alike) is its capacity tor organize people against their
own interests, and even for their own destruction.  Diatribes denouncing
these institutions as a ploy serving the elite interests do little to help
us understand how they extert their influence on common people.  In the same
vein, the modern military and its weaponry is obviously a tool of the ruling
class to maintain their hegemony and keep the lower classes in line.  But
that fact does not yet explain why and how the lower classes are fascinated
with the military and weapons (cf. the militias) despite the fact that these
are the proverbial Damocles' sword hanging over their heads.

In that respect, Echrenreich's bourgeois morality play can offer more
insights into the process, than a conventional class analysis.

wojtek sokolowski 
institute for policy studies
johns hopkins university
baltimore, md 21218
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
voice: (410) 516-4056
fax:   (410) 516-8233


** REDUCE MENTAL POLLUTION - LOBOTOMIZE PUNDITS! **
+--+
|There is  no such thing as society,  only the individuals | 
|who constitute it. -Margaret Thatcher |
|  | 
| 

[PEN-L:9776] henwood

1997-05-01 Thread Ed Herman

Hi, hope no one minds, but I forwarded Doug's critique of Ed Herman's Z
article to Ed, and here's his reply.  Elaine
Original message
Dear Elaine: I've put up a few notes on Henwood's defense of his citation
of Larry Summers. Can you put it into circulation on Pen-L (if that's the
right web site)?

 Best, Ed Herman

PS: I did write to Robert and Ethel after last talking with you.
--
Reply to Doug Henwood's defense of his reliance on Larry Summers:

1. Henwood says that Summers is not always wrong and has "done a
lot of very useful academic work..."  But Henwood fails to note
that that academic work was many years ago--Henwood cites Summers
as of 1991, in his World Bank employment role that preceded his
phase as a Clinton administration official. So his academic work
would seem pretty much irrelevant; his commitment to the
principles--and principals--of the New World Order in 1991 and
after would seem obvious. A "political agenda" supportive of FDI
and globalization as beneficial would also seem a requirement for
the kind of work Summers has been doing. Would Henwood suggest that
Summers could take a position questioning free trade and FDI? If
not, is Henwood not neglecting "context" in citing Summers as a
presumably objective scholar?

2. Henwood says I rely on "assertion" and don't bother with the
substance of his argument or "evidence." But my article has more
"evidence" in it than Henwood's, and much of his evidence is a
quoting of qualitative opinions, notably by Summers. I give
evidence on financial flows that Henwood largely ignores, but which
are vastly more important than 30 years ago, and far more important
than in 1913 in effects on policy. Henwood's evidence is also dated
and backward, not forward looking. For example, his quote from the
1991 Summers statement asks whether the telecommunications
revolution has really had a major impact? But we are in the midst
of a telecom revolution that is advancing rapidly (and has gained
further strength from the recent WTO deal getting scores of
countries to agree to privatize). Furthermore, even if
manufacturing hasn't been "fundamentally altered" (whatever that
means), cross-border integration of production keeps growing in
importance. And while sellers have always tried to "locate
production at the lowest cost location," you would think a leftist
would recognize that the increased mobility of capital, greater
power of IMF and World Bank, and new agreements protecting
investment rights, are widening options for sellers and that a
"reserve army" that runs from China to Russia to Indonesia to
Mexico (etc.) represents something a bit different and worth
noting.

  The economist Richard DuBoff, who also wasn't too keen on
Henwood's analysis of globaloney, sent Henwood a detailed statement
with a lot of "evidence," to which Henwood hasn't yet replied.

3. Henwood says that globalization "is often held up as the reason
things can't get any better." But if it is an important fact, we
can't deny its reality because it is used is some particular way.
Furthermore, why do a Larry Summers and the conservative Martin
Wolf go along with Henwood in denying a powerful negative effect of
globalization? It is because if it were admitted to be having
damaging effects on the incomes of the majority and killing social
democratic policy there would be a political demand for bringing it
under control. I made this point in my Z article, but I haven't yet
heard Henwood come to grips with it.

4. He repeats his statement that the focus on globalization
"deflects attention away from the causes of globalization," etc.
This is not true--as I point out in my article, it focuses
attention on the particular forms of capitalism that are important
in the age of globalization, like the rise in power and spread of
TNCs, financial flows and speculation, the role of the IMF and
World Bank in serving the TNCs and the like. On the other hand, the
Henwood position, which denies the importance of globalization,
deflects attention away from globalization and its damaging
capitalist--institutional causes to vague generalities like "the
quest for higher profits and stock prices." Beyond that, if as
Summers and Henwood agree, "the revolution is merely incremental,
and not something all so fundamentally new," why worry about
transnationalization, global mergers, IMF rules, and the like?
"Natura non facit saltum" was the rule for neoclassical economist
Alfred Marshall and his successors as well, including Summers, and
apparently Henwood.

---Edward S. Herman





[PEN-L:9777] Re: tenure

1997-05-01 Thread Susan Pashkoff

For the sake of clarity, although there is no formal 'tenure'in the 
UK, there are permanent positions. If you are hired for a permanent 
track position, you are permanent usually after 6 months. The only 
way that you can be fired is if the department is dissolved and/or 
there is no work for you to do in the University. The UK has 
mandatory retirement. The situation here is the opposite of the 
manner in which the situation is going in the states: there is job 
security, but room for new people.

Susan Pashkoff


 Date:  Wed, 30 Apr 1997 15:14:08 -0700 (PDT)
 Reply-to:  [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 From:  James Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Subject:   [PEN-L:9761] tenure

 susan, any comments?
 
 Original message
 what experience do people in places like the UK have with the absense of
 tenure for professors? is it as bad as some people in the US fear? is there
 a lot of violation of academic freedom?
 
 
 
 
 in pen-l solidarity,
 
 Jim Devine   [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Econ. Dept., Loyola Marymount Univ.
 7900 Loyola Blvd., Los Angeles, CA 90045-8410 USA
 310/338-2948 (daytime, during workweek); FAX: 310/338-1950
 "It takes a busload of faith to get by." -- Lou Reed.
 





[PEN-L:9766] Re: Walras vs. Sraffa

1997-05-01 Thread Ajit Sinha

My response to Gil continues...


Gil continues:
Ajit continues:

So what does this mean? It means that the two
theoretical worlds are wide appart. The GE framework does not get away from
what Sraffa called a "one way avenue", ie. a linear theoretical structure
which goes from 'factors of production' to consumer goods production.

For reasons given above, this distinction is necessarily specious.
___
Ajit:

Where is the reason given above? As I have explained above, this is a
fundamental methodological difference between the two theories.
_
Gil:

Consumption is the final *goal* of the theory. So the theory is ahistorical
through and through. It is a solution to a problem generated by axiomatic
*nature* of man. The Sraffian theoretical framework is circular. It is
interested in the question of *reproduction*-- consumption is simply a
moment in the reproduction of the system.

Ajit's anthropomorphic wording, which suggests the bizarre notion that
theories, i.e. formal analytical structures, can somehow *themselves* have
"goals" and "interests" (as if my copy of _Production of Commodities by
Means of Commodities_ could express an "interest" in going out to lunch),
effectively illustrates my point that the differences he cites between the
two systems have mostly to do with the "goals" and "interests" of their
respective adherents, not with the systems themselves.  

It is nonsense to suggest that consumption is the "goal" of the Walrasian
framework,  since this suggests that "theories" can have thoughts and
feelings.  But even if they could, consumption is no more or less the "goal"
of the Walrasian framework itself than it is for the Sraffian.  It is true
in both cases that production takes place, and that production is necessary
for consumption.  It is true in both cases that if people did not consume,
production would be unnecessary.
___-
Ajit:

That's very smart of you Gil, and my hat's off to you for that! Any reader
with minimum sympathey would understand what I'm saying there; which is that
the GE theoretical paradigm is rooted in human subjectivity. The purpose of
production is considered to be consumption, and not accumulation. This is a
theoretical, and not just an ideological, difference between the two
theories. People produce in order to consume and people consume in order to
produce are not the same thing. As Marx said, accumulation for accumulation
sake; production for production sake is the reason behind capitalist
production. M-C-M' is necessarily a circular circuit. And this is what is
reflected in the title of Sraffa's book, 'Production of Commodities by means
of Commodities'.
_ 
Gil:

 Thus it is historical through and
through, since it does not allow the framework to be draged into a mythical
origin or the begining.

Again, there is nothing about the formal Sraffian framework *itself* which
is any more or less "historical" than the Walrasian system, with the
important difference that since the Sraffian framework ignores the operation
of time in market exchange (by Ajit's own advertisement), it ignores this
particular slice of "history."  And again, in no relevant sense does the
Walrasian system deal in "mythic origins".
___
Ajit:

What is this "formal Sraffian framework *itself*", which no Sraffian has
ever heard off? There is no such thing. In the very Preface of PCMC Sraffa
says: "The investigation is concerned exclusively with such properties of an
economic system as do not depend on changes in the scale of production or in
the proportions of 'factors'. This standpoint, which is that of the old
classical economists from Adam Smith to Ricardo, has been submerged and
forgotten since the advent of the 'marginal' method." Sraffa's reading of
classical theory suggested to him that classical theory divided itself into
three parts: a theory of distribution, a theory of value or prices, and a
theory of accumulation. He believed in Ricardo's dictum that the subject
matter of economics is so complex that it does not lend itself to a long
chain of deductive reasoning. Only short chains of deductive reasoning could
be applied. Thus the connections between the three departments of the theory
cannot be established by some functional relations of quantitative nature.
Their relationships are qualitative and overdetermined in nature, to use an
Althusserian term.

Sraffa's price system was designed to establish the classical theory of
prices, which was independent of human subjectivity, and dependent on
distribution determined in a socio-historical context. This price theory
also proved that the neoclassical theory based on long chain of deductive
reasoning was flawed. So your talk of a "formal Sraffian model" is simple
nonsense.
__
Gil:

 Now, my question is this: Gil, do you think that a
skilled man can always turn a straight line into a circle?

Ah, a riddle.  I can do no better than respond with riddles of equal meaning
and relevance 

[PEN-L:9782] The election in Britain

1997-05-01 Thread D Shniad

This says it all:

The Globe and Mail  Thursday, May 1, 1997


Lead editorial:


WHY BRITAIN IS VOTING LABOUR 

On the face of it, John Major and the Conservatives should win today's 
election in Great Britain. If the economy were the measure of performance, 
his government would do well. If personality were the measure of 
performance, Mr. Major would do well. The trouble is that neither the 
economy nor personality seems decisive in how Britons are judging this 
government, which is why it is likely to lose. 

From this perspective, Mr. Major has reason to think his compatriots 
ungrateful. It recalls the fate of Winston Churchill in 1945. Mr. Churchill 
had led Briton for five tumultuous years. He had rallied the nation, retooled 
the economy, won the war. For his Herculean labours he was summarily 
returned to opposition. 

It isn't that Britons disliked Sir Winston; they simply decided that he wasn't 
up to the socio-economic challenges of the new era. As they saw it then, he 
was more suited for war than for peace (even though they brought him back 
the next time). 

Mr. Major is no Mr. Churchill, but there is some of that logic in his 
diminishing prospects. After all, it is largely because of the Conservatives 
that Britain is prosperous. With unemployment around 6 per cent, Britain's 
level is half that of France and Germany, both of which are now 
contemplating some of the measures -- budget-cutting, privatization and 
deregulation -- that Britain adopted under Margaret Thatcher and Mr. 
Major. 

Britain now draws about 40 per cent of the new investment in the European 
Union. It has fuelled the revival of London, which has again become a 
centre of design, fashion, pop music, even cuisine, recalling the spirit of a 
generation ago. 

Then there is Mr. Major himself. While his party trails badly in the polls, 
his personal popularity remains high. It is hard to dislike the man, however 
one might disagree with him. He has humility and modesty. He has pluck 
and determination, so much so that had he refused to step aside when 
challenged for the leadership two years ago, he would have spared himself 
all this anguish. 

So what is it, then, which is propelling the Labour Party to victory? If it 
isn't a stagnant economy or an unpopular prime minister, is it the appeal of 
the opposition and its leader? Here, too, the answer is probably no. Labour 
is not demonstrably different on the main issues, and Tony Blair, the prime 
minister-in-waiting, offers competence more than charisma. 

Our guess is that this election is more about ennui than anger. Britons have 
had 18 years of the Conservatives, and now they have had enough. They are 
simply bored with the Tories, tired of their divisions and scandals. They 
want something new, even if it is less a matter of substance than style. 

Labour, or "New Labour" as it shrewdly calls itself, understands that. By 
adopting the government's economic policies, and raising sufficient 
skepticism about embracing Europe, it offers wary Britons a way to vote 
Labour and elect the Conservatives. With a no-risk solution that will change 
the players but keep the policies, they are free to vote Labour without fear.  

Yes, there are differences between the parties, but they are limited. On the 
constitutional questions -- home rule for Scotland and Wales, a freedom of 
information act, the abolition of hereditary peers -- Labour is more daring. 
But this is fussing on the fringes. 

At root, what makes the Labourites attractive is that they are conservatives 
without being Conservatives. This kind of imitation is supremely flattering 
to Mr. Major, but it is unlikely to be enough to save his weary government.






[PEN-L:9769] Re: IB Systems (was Globaloney)

1997-05-01 Thread Louis N Proyect

On Wed, 30 Apr 1997, Tavis Barr wrote:

 
 What amazes me is this: The system that I put together probably cut the 
 non-production workforce (people with the fairly mundane jobs of keeping 
 track of inventory and filling out and keeping track of purchase orders 
 and payments on bills) by a factor of three or four (no layoffs 
 necessary since it was a growing company though I'm sure I would have 
 been a hatchet boy in another situation).  This seems the natural 
 effect of any IB system. And yet it's the non-production workforce in 
 manufacturing that's been growing and the production  workforce that's 
 been shrinking.  Any thoughts?  Is it that most businesses simply haven't 
 implemented IB systems (I have this impression, or at least the 
 impression that they're not as fully implemented as they could be)?  Or 
 is there a really exploding ratio of non-production work that's simply 
 been tamed by the computer revolution?
 

Isn't it possible that the growth of a "non-production workforce" in
manufacturing simply reflects the transition from some of these companies
out of manufacturing into finance? Isn't the purpose of US Steel to
enhance the share value of its equity rather than make steel?

Louis Proyect






[PEN-L:9783] game theory torture

1997-05-01 Thread James Devine

(apologies ahead of time for this: I also walked out of the Mel Gibson
flick "Ransom" thinking about game theory.)

The L.A. TIMES today (May 1, 1997) published exerpts from the CIA manual on
how to torture prisoners (used at the notorious US Army School of the
Americas). This book should not be rejected out of hand, and instead should
be treated as serious social science, despite its moral depravity (and its
violation of current rules about experiments with human subjects): it
represents the thinking of bright people dealing with serious questions,
based on empirical evidence; it was a secret document and thus shows little
need to cover up what's being recommended with euphemisms.[*] It seems a
compendium of age-old wisdom about torture, used by the "torture
professionals" (the CIA, etc.) to enlighten the "torture amateurs" (a large
number of Latin American military officers) on how to torture efficiently
(e.g., holding actual physical torture in reserve rather than revealing
one's cards right away). In addition to being disgusting, it sheds a lot of
light on the standard textbook presentation of the "prisoners' dilemma" in
economics, or rather on the key assumption usually made in PD discussions,
i.e., that people are atomistic individuals with absolutely no
psychological depth. 

The CIA's prescriptions, in sum, are to mess with the prisoners' minds
(and, if need be, their bodies) in order to _create_ the textbook
prisoners' dilemma, to encourage each prisoner to "defect," to turn in his
or her comrades. The textbook treatment _assumes_ that the prisoners are
already atomistic individuals and there is _no need_ to plumb the depths of
their psyches in order to make them that way. In fact, the vast majority of
economists reject the need to study the depths of psychology at all;
instead, they simply assume that people "maximize utility," having no sense
of honor or morality, solidarity or self-esteem. It treats the fact that
many if not most prisoners do not defect as a "paradox" rather than as
showing up the severe limitations of the theory.

The CIA manual suggests that we reject the standard economics attitude
toward people. Further, if the prisoners' dilemma is something that has to
be _actively created_ by the captors (doing more than simply separating the
prisoners, preventing them from communcating) that the a priori presumption
in PD games should be that people do not "defect." 

Of course, just as with the experiments done at death camps by the Nazi
doctors, the validity of the CIA wisdom should not be tested via
replication. But I bet that experimental economics has already been done
for more moderate cases, showing the limits of the textbook presentation.
Of course, the power of ideology is such that such research does not show
up in the textbooks, where it would have the most influence. 

Happy May Day, International Workers' Day!

[*] Because of the way e-mail strips nuance from our prose, I must stress
that I do not admire the "bright" CIA social scientists. Rather, this shows
one of the big problems with social science. But maybe some of them will
turn out to be Daniel Ellsbergs. 




in pen-l solidarity,

Jim Devine   [EMAIL PROTECTED]
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
Econ. Dept., Loyola Marymount Univ.
7900 Loyola Blvd., Los Angeles, CA 90045-8410 USA
310/338-2948 (daytime, during workweek); FAX: 310/338-1950
"It takes a busload of faith to get by." -- Lou Reed.






[PEN-L:9779] Re: henwood

1997-05-01 Thread Doug Henwood

Ed Herman wrote:

1. Henwood says that Summers is not always wrong and has "done a
lot of very useful academic work..."  But Henwood fails to note
that that academic work was many years ago--Henwood cites Summers
as of 1991, in his World Bank employment role that preceded his
phase as a Clinton administration official. So his academic work
would seem pretty much irrelevant; his commitment to the
principles--and principals--of the New World Order in 1991 and
after would seem obvious. A "political agenda" supportive of FDI
and globalization as beneficial would also seem a requirement for
the kind of work Summers has been doing. Would Henwood suggest that
Summers could take a position questioning free trade and FDI? If
not, is Henwood not neglecting "context" in citing Summers as a
presumably objective scholar?

I brought up Summers' academic work because his positions, first with the
World Bank and then with the U.S. Treasury, were in themselves being used
to discredit his argument. Yeah, so Larry Summers is a bourgeois pig. But
that doesn't mean he's always wrong, does it? Especially when he's writing
a memo for intra-pen consumption by his comradely herd of piglets.

2. Henwood says I rely on "assertion" and don't bother with the
substance of his argument or "evidence." But my article has more
"evidence" in it than Henwood's, and much of his evidence is a
quoting of qualitative opinions, notably by Summers. I give
evidence on financial flows that Henwood largely ignores, but which
are vastly more important than 30 years ago, and far more important
than in 1913 in effects on policy.

I really don't want to get into a "my evidence is longer than your
evidence" debate, but this is a really preposterous claim. I've spent years
writing more articles with more numbers in them than just about anyone in
the field of left-wing economic journalism. On PEN-L the other day I quoted
from a longer piece, which was itself a sequel to an even longer one. I've
continued to analyze the figures behind the globalization mania, and the
issue of LBO that's going to press in a couple of days will have more.

Henwood's evidence is also dated
and backward, not forward looking.

Kind of hard to make a historical argument without looking backwards, isn't it?

For example, his quote from the
1991 Summers statement asks whether the telecommunications
revolution has really had a major impact? But we are in the midst
of a telecom revolution that is advancing rapidly (and has gained
further strength from the recent WTO deal getting scores of
countries to agree to privatize).

Oh, you mean the revolution in production has happened since 1991? Gosh,
time moves so fast these days!

Furthermore, even if
manufacturing hasn't been "fundamentally altered" (whatever that
means), cross-border integration of production keeps growing in
importance. And while sellers have always tried to "locate
production at the lowest cost location," you would think a leftist
would recognize that the increased mobility of capital, greater
power of IMF and World Bank, and new agreements protecting
investment rights, are widening options for sellers and that a
"reserve army" that runs from China to Russia to Indonesia to
Mexico (etc.) represents something a bit different and worth
noting.

Ed Herman subscribes to LBO, and I think he even reads it. So if he's been
reading my articles on this issue, he must know that I've been using BEA
figures on multinationals to show that the "cross-border integration of
production" hasn't progressed anywhere near as far as he claims. As I've
said almost every time I've made this point, you can challenge the figures
as inaccurate, but you'll have to do better than just make an
Aronowitz-style argument by assertion.

3. Henwood says that globalization "is often held up as the reason
things can't get any better." But if it is an important fact, we
can't deny its reality because it is used is some particular way.
Furthermore, why do a Larry Summers and the conservative Martin
Wolf go along with Henwood in denying a powerful negative effect of
globalization?

Here we go again, discrediting arguments by political association. If I
wanted to I could say, well here we have a Wharton professor who wrote a
book commissioned by the Twentieth Century Fund. Ooh can't trust him,
must be bourgeois!

Speaking of associations, I wonder if Herman has talked over globalization
with his sometime collaborator, Noam Chomsky. Chomsky holds a position
rather similar to mine, I think. In fact, here's what he wrote to me after
reading my ITT piece:

"I quite agree that the tales about "globalization" are mostly
devised to make people feel powerless, and have been trying to
make that point for a while.  And by now there is plenty in
print in highly respectable technical literature (e.g., Ruigrok
and von Tulder) to make it pretty clear that the story is mostly
a crock, and that by gross measures, at least, it's pretty much a
return to early in the 

[PEN-L:9781] Cyber Picket Line (fwd)

1997-05-01 Thread D Shniad

 From: STEPHEN DAVIES [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 To: Unions1 [EMAIL PROTECTED], Unions1 [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Date: Thu, 1 May 1997 15:44:50 GMT
 Subject: Cyber Picket Line
 
 NET NEWS RELEASE
 
 International Workers Day, 1 May 1997
 
 UNION FLYING PICKETS HEAD INTO CYBERSPACE
 
 1997's May Day is not only marked by the British General Election but
 also by the launch of the Cyber Picket Line - the world's biggest
 internet directory of trade union websites. Its address is:
 
  http://www.cf.ac.uk/ccin/union/
 
 With links to over 1000 trade union and trade union-related sites, the
 Cyber Picket Line shows the massive strides that the labour movement
 has taken in high tech communications over the last few years.
 
 The small group of pioneers who began it all a decade or more ago -
 primarily in Europe and North America - have now been joined by union
 internationals, national union centres, individual unions and hundreds
 of local union branches all over the world.
 
 The Cyber Picket Line features union sites from every continent in the
 world ranging from South African miners to Brazilian dockers; from
 council shop stewards in Sheffield to journalists in Hong Kong; from
 Croatian railworkers to Canadian loggers. 
 
 The effects are already being felt as workers build new links across
 continents and oceans. The Liverpool Dockers campaign, the Korean
 trade unionists battle against repressive laws and the US Firestone
 workers have all used the internet and the world wide web to organise
 solidarity action and to build support.
 
 Steve Davies, the co-ordinator of the new web site said:
 
 "For too long unions all over the world have been on the ropes. Now
 we're on the Net and its already beginning to pay off. It's now
 possible for workers to communicate effectively with each other as
 never before. 
 
 "It is also possible for rank and file stewards and branch activists
 to have access to the sort of information resource and research
 capacity that was previously only available to senior full time
 officers. It is potentially one of the most powerful and democratic
 weapons at the disposal of the labour movement.
 
 "I hope that this site helps local branches all over the world take
 advantage of the resources that exist, make the contacts that count,
 and use 21st century techniques  to rebuild international solidarity."
 
 
 ENDS
 
 NOTES FOR EDITORS
 
 The site co-ordinator is Steve Davies. He lives in Cardiff, and works
 at the University of Wales Cardiff in adult education where he's been
 since the beginning of 1996. Before that he spent 11 years working at
 the London headquarters of a British Civil Service union (now called
 PTC). He started as a research officer, later specialising in
 privatisation and contracting out, before becoming national press
 officer and Assistant to the General Secretary.
 
 A Spanish version of the site is under construction (translation being
 done by Companero David Jones of Pontypridd and Zaragoza). Eventually
 the site may appear in several other languages. All the tricky techie
 work for this site was done by Sioned Rogers of CapitalNet, the server
 for Cardiff, who have also provided the webspace.
 
 






[PEN-L:9771] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread Antonio Callari

I was at the conference (in fact, I was one of the organizers). There were
some conflicts. Most of the conflicts were around the question of
postmodernism. I don't want to enter again into the merits and demerits of
postmodernism. The positions are somewhat known about that. I would like to
say, however, that the impression that the conference did not address the
question of "what is to be done" that is of interest to activists is, in my
view, wrong. One of the plenaries was on the experiences of Latin American
socialism. Again, one might quarrel with whether postmodernist forms of
activism are valid, (and the discussion about a sociaslist strategy in
Latin America, including a glorifying and moving representation of the
Zapatista movement, did have a postmodernist tone), but that is quite
different from saying that activism was not part of the conference. I think
the gist of Blair Sandler's message was correct: that traditional,
orthodox, views of activism were not the dominant ones in the plenaries,
and in fact were not very welkl represented in the plenaries, and that
those who held those views mistook the non-dominance/presence of these
views as an absence of activism itself: which is simply incorrect. One
other point to be made is that, perhaps, the distinction between academics
and activists is sometimes overdrawn. The proper distinction should be
between activist academics and non-activist academics. Most of the people
who talk a lot about activism are themselves either academics (either
students or professors) or enmeshed in a network of academic discourses and
processes; just as people who are academics are often enmeshed in activist
discourses and practices, even if they do not advertise it=themselves, or
glamorize it=themselves, or romanticize it=themselves.

Antonio Callari

  I just heard a description of the "Rethinking Marxism" conference that
occurred in Amherst late last year. The reporter (Olga Celle de Bowman, a
sociologist from Peru) said that there was a tremendous amount of (verbal)
conflict between the audience and the speakers at the plenaries, something
I hadn't heard about before. She said that the activists in the audience
were objecting to the lack of answers to the key "what is to be done?"
question and the lack of any kind of orientation toward people outside of
academe. Was anyone on pen-l at the conference and has a different
perspective on the conflict?




in pen-l solidarity,

Jim Devine   [EMAIL PROTECTED]
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
Econ. Dept., Loyola Marymount Univ.
7900 Loyola Blvd., Los Angeles, CA 90045-8410 USA
310/338-2948 (daytime, during workweek); FAX: 310/338-1950
"It takes a busload of faith to get by." -- Lou Reed.

Antonio Callari
E-MAIL: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
POST MAIL:  Department of Economics
Franklin and Marshall College
Lancaster PA 17604-3003
PHONE:  717/291-3947
FAX:717/291-4369







[PEN-L:9784] Re: Globaloney

1997-05-01 Thread Doug Henwood

D Shniad wrote:

What follows is a response to Doug's call to specify a bit more what we're
talking about when we compare the relative magnitude of financial
speculation to that of trade and other economic activity.  (Caveat: I don't
work with or have access to trade stats; what follows is the seat-of-the-
pants calculation that I've done based on readings about speculation, etc. I
invite those with access to the stats to respond.)

The IMF estimates that foreign exchange transactions are more than $1
trillion daily, while trade volumes are in the $3.5 trillion ballpark
annually.

If trade volumes are 5% of the total of the world's domestic output (a
*very* conservative estimate), then the aggregate of the world's real output
would be in the neighbourhood of $70 trillion per year.

Actually, gross global product was around $25 trillion in 1994, according
to the World Bank, making trade around 14% of output.

Let's look at some export/GDP ratios for 1980 and 1994 for evidence of some
globalizing "revolution." Of course it's always possible the revolution
started after 1994; someone check with Ed Herman on this.

EXPORTS AS PERCENT OF GDP

 1980 1994
"developing" countries23%  22%
  Latin Amer/Caribb   16   15
Brazil 98
Mexico11   13
  S Africa36   24
  S Korea 34   36
Canada28   30
Japan 149
Norway47   33
Sweden29   33
UK27   25
U.S.  10   10

source: World Development Report 1996, table 13

(If trade volumes
are a somewhat larger portion of domestic production in the aggregate, then
the world's aggregate production is somewhat smaller.)  By comparison,
aggregate international financial transactions come in at more than $300
trillion per year.

By these calculations, the aggregate of international *financial*
transactions
are more than four times the dollar magnitude of *real* production.  It was
on the basis of this observation that I made the statement that speculative
activity had dwarfed the activity of productive capital.

No one disputes that there's lots of furious, pointless, even destructive
speculative activity going on. How, precisely, is it malignant, though?
Merely describing its magnitude is not to make the case.

Doug

--

Doug Henwood
Left Business Observer
250 W 85 St
New York NY 10024-3217 USA
+1-212-874-4020 voice  +1-212-874-3137 fax
email: mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
web: http://www.panix.com/~dhenwood/LBO_home.html







[PEN-L:9785] re: Environmental Economics

1997-05-01 Thread Robin Hahnel

I second Jim Devine's message about neoclassicals and the environment in
its entirety. The astounding misinterpretation of what the Coase theorem
actually tells any reasonable analyst about the likelihood of environmental
efficiency being achieved through voluntary and private negotiations of
polluters and pollution victims is an excellent case in point. A reasonable
reading of the theorem AND ITS INCREDIBLE LIST OF NECESSARY ASSUMPTIONS gives
more than enough theoretical reasons for anyone who cares about the environ-
ment to immediately embrace a government role!





[PEN-L:9786] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread Stephen Cullenberg

Just a brief response to Jim's initial question on the Rethinking Marxism
conference.  I was one of the co-organizers of the conference, and the one
mainly responsible for the conference program, of some 190 panels.

There is no question in my mind that the conference attracts mainly
academics doing all types of critical analysis, from radical political
economy to semiotic cultural studies, and often combining them both.  There
are very few "activists" who come.  Whether that is good or bad is not
obvious to me.  It seems to me that there is no one best way to organize on
the Left these days and we all need to do what we can, in whatever ways we
can. (BTW, I know that academics are also activists and activists are also
academics - I not concerned with this finer point).

In a similar way, the conference was both open and ecumenical, while also
rather partisan (which I suppose you can pejoratively call exclusionary, as
some have).  We found space for any and everyone who wanted to present a
paper, panel, performance, art, etc., to do so.  But, yes, the plenaries
were decided on by the organizers, and really why shouldn't it be this way?
 Afterall, the conference was organized and sponsored by Rethinking Marxism
and therefore might well reflect the ideas, positions, and biases of its
editors.  RM is a journal open to a wide array of ideas concerned with
Marxism and related fields, and we have published with a wide diversity. 
Yet, we are not, and never have pretended to be, as ecumenical as say URPE
and the RRPE.  We have been a journal with a partisan, yet always shifting
set of postionings, as new ideas push and pull Marxism in various
directions.  But one thing has remained a priority, and that is the RM's
interest in developing and fostering non-essentialist forms of discourse as
related to Marxism (whether you want to call that postmodernism or not).

So, as I have heard some criticize the conference for being exclusionary (I
prefer partisan), I remain a little puzzled.  The conference was extrememly
open with regard to conference program, but what exactly did people expect
coming to a conference sponsored by Rethinking Marxism???  Afterall, that
is what we are about, and we don't disguise our intentions as others on the
Left have recently felt the need to do.  

Instead, I would like to hear discussion or criticism about the quality of
the papers (and of course many have already commented on this), or was
there a poor turnout (which of course was the opposite case), what was the
sense of interest and excitement (extremely vigorous), did people make new
connections across disciplines and internationally (many), or even did
Balibar have anything to say, even though he (unfortunately) spoke too
long, and so on.

I am sorry the conference was not exactly what some people had hoped for,
or wanted, or even at times seem to demand.  We all do what we can and make
the types of intereventions we are able to and that we feel will have some
impact, however limited that might be.  I wish that we on the Left would
demand less of each other about how things should be, or feel the need to
entrap each other in faux pas's, and show a little more graciousness and
understanding, because we are all working very hard in these inauspicious
times and no one I know has yet found the unique way to change this world
for the better. 

Steve C.

p.s.  For a full description of our conference program, post-conference
reactions from the international press, and a lot about RM, check out our
new web site:  http://www.nd.edu/~remarx/


***
Stephen Cullenberg  office:  (909) 787-5037, ext. 1573
Department of Economics fax: (909) 787-5685
University of California[EMAIL PROTECTED]
Riverside, CA 92521
http://www.ucr.edu/CHSS/depts/econ/sc.htm







[PEN-L:9791] Re: Barbara Ehrenreich on War

1997-05-01 Thread Robert Saute, CUNY Grad Center

No, tell me Paul, what does it "say about the state of DSA's understanding
of class, etc. etc.!"?

In the best leninist tradition and always eager to receive knowledge from
on high, I remain,

Robert Saute

On Wed, 30 Apr 1997, Louis Proyect wrote:

 is this true! what does it say about the state of DSA's understanding
 of class, etc. etc.!
 -paul
 Original message
 I guess I have gotten used to how bad the Nation magazine has become, but
 every once in a while I run into something so rancid that I have to pause
 and catch my breath. This was the case with a review by DSA leader Barbara
 Ehrenreich of 3 books on war. This review was accompanied by a review by
 Susan Faludi of Ehrenreich’s new book on war titled "Blood Rites". All this
 prose is dedicated to the proposition that large-scale killing has been
 around as long as homo sapiens has been around and that it has nothing much
 to do with economic motives. Looking for an explanation why George Bush
 made war on Iraq? It wasn’t over oil, "democratic socialist" Ehrenreich
 would argue. It was instead related to the fact that we were once "preyed
 upon by animals that were initially far more skillful hunters than
 ourselves. In particular, the sacralization of war is not the project of a
 self-confident predator...but that of a creature which has learned only
 ‘recently,’ in the last thousand or so generations, not to cower at every
 sound in the night."
 
 In a rather silly exercise in cultural criticism, Ehrenreich speculates
 that the popularity of those nature shows depicting one animal attacking
 and eating another are proof of the predatory disposition we brutish human
 beings share. I myself have a different interpretation for what its worth.
 I believe that PBS sponsors all this stuff because of the rampant oil
 company sponsorship that transmits coded Social Darwinist ideology. Just as
 the Leopard is meant to eat the antelope, so is Shell Oil meant to kill
 Nigerians who stand in the way of progress.
 
 One of the books that Ehrenreich reviews is "War Before Civilization: The
 Myth of the Peaceful Savage" by Lawrence Keeley. Keeley argues that
 material scarcity does not explain warfare among Stone Age people. It is
 instead something in our "shared psychology" that attracts us to war.
 Keeley finds brutish behavior everywhere and at all times, including among
 the American Indian. If the number of casualties produced by wars among the
 Plains Indians was proportional to the population of European nations
 during the World Wars, then the casualty rates would have been more like 2
 billion rather than the tens of millions that obtained. Ehrenreich swoons
 over Keeley’s book that was published in 1996 to what seems like
 "insufficient acclaim".
 
 I suspect that Keeley’s book functions ideologically like some of the
 recent scholarship that attempts to show that Incas, Aztecs and Spaniards
 were all equally bad. They all had kingdoms. They all had slaves. They all
 despoiled the environment. Ad nauseum. It is always a specious practice to
 project into precapitalist societies the sort of dynamic that occurs under
 capitalism. For one thing, it is almost impossible to understand these
 societies without violating some sort of Heisenberg law of anthropology.
 The historiography of the North American and Latin American Indian
 societies is mediated by the interaction of the invading society with the
 invaded. The "view" is rarely impartial. Capitalism began to influence and
 overturn precapitalist class relations hundreds of years ago, so a
 laboratory presentation of what Aztec society looked like prior to the
 Conquistadores is impossible. Furthermore, it is regrettable that
 Ehrenreich herself is seduced by this methodology since she doesn’t even
 question Keeley’s claims about the Plains Indian wars. When did these wars
 occur? Obviously long after the railroads and buffalo hunters had become a
 fact of North American life.
 
 The reason all this stuff seems so poisonous is that it makes a political
 statement that war can not be eliminated through the introduction of
 socialism or political action. For Ehrenreich, opposing war is a
 psychological project rather than a political project:
 
 "Any anti-war movement that targets only the human agents of war -- a
 warrior elite or, on our own time, the chieftains of the
 ‘military-industrial complex’ – risks mimicking those it seeks to overcome
 .. So it is a giant step from hating the warriors to hating the war, and
 an even greater step to deciding that the ‘enemy’ is the abstract
 institution of war, which maintains its grip on us even in the interludes
 we know as peace."
 
 Really? The abstract institution of war maintains its grip on "us"? Who
 exactly is this "us"? Is it the average working person who struggles to
 make ends meet? Do they sit at home at night like great cats fantasizing
 about biting the throats out of Rwandans or 

[PEN-L:9792] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread Gerald Levy

By the way, isn't it important for Blair to identify himself as a member of
the collective that sponsored the Conference? This is highly scandalous
when people hide such information. Where's Jerry Levy when you need him?
Jerry, it's time for a crusade against Blair Sandler's dissembling before
the august body of PEN-L. The nerve of Blair to hide his connections. Oh,
perfidy.

Thank you for asking and bringing up that subject again, Louis. 

I know of no scandal that Blair Sandler is involved with. Certainly,
nothing he has done is so scandalous as when a Marxist journal in Germany
published a review of the RM conference by a person who months beforehand
-- before he had even seen a full copy of the schedule! -- trashed that
conference in public and in writing. 

Jerry 






[PEN-L:9793] Re: IB Systems (was Globaloney)

1997-05-01 Thread Tavis Barr



On Thu, 1 May 1997, Louis N Proyect wrote:


 Isn't it possible that the growth of a "non-production workforce" in
 manufacturing simply reflects the transition from some of these companies
 out of manufacturing into finance? Isn't the purpose of US Steel to
 enhance the share value of its equity rather than make steel?

That's one I hadn't thought of.  I don't know enough details to judge it, 
but on the face of it it seems unlikely.  Transferring into finance 
doesn't so much mean that firms transfer out of manufacturing.  After 
all, the best way to maximize share values is to produce good steel cheap.  
What's really happened is that these firms place their new investments in 
diverse portfolios, which can be taken care of by a handful of portfolio 
managers, instead of, say, steel.  The rising ratio of production workers 
comes from technological change, which produces more and more output with 
fewer and fewer production workers, but there hasn't been a similar trend 
in non-production work.

It was Braverman's theory that as production becomes more coordinated and 
deskilled, fewer workers are required on the shop floor and more workers 
are required to manage control processes.  But it's exactly these types 
of control processes (inventory, quality, orders, auditing) that the 
computer is supposed to be automating.  It seems like there's a missing 
piece of the puzzle somewhere.


Befuddled,
Tavis






[PEN-L:9794] Re: Cyber Picket Line (fwd)

1997-05-01 Thread Michael Eisenscher

On May Day no less, we are advised that it is no longer "Workers of the
World Unite!..." but rather "Workers of the World---log on!"

If that isn't postmodernism, what is?  Let's all reach out and digitize
someone.  (:-)  Can this Cyber Picket Line intercept cyber capital flows?
Are we ready for the virtual general strike?


At 10:56 AM 5/1/97 -0700, D Shniad wrote:
 From: STEPHEN DAVIES [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 To: Unions1 [EMAIL PROTECTED], Unions1 [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Date: Thu, 1 May 1997 15:44:50 GMT
 Subject: Cyber Picket Line
 
 NET NEWS RELEASE
 
 International Workers Day, 1 May 1997
 
 UNION FLYING PICKETS HEAD INTO CYBERSPACE
 
 1997's May Day is not only marked by the British General Election but
 also by the launch of the Cyber Picket Line - the world's biggest
 internet directory of trade union websites. Its address is:
 
  http://www.cf.ac.uk/ccin/union/
 
 With links to over 1000 trade union and trade union-related sites, the
 Cyber Picket Line shows the massive strides that the labour movement
 has taken in high tech communications over the last few years.
 
 The small group of pioneers who began it all a decade or more ago -
 primarily in Europe and North America - have now been joined by union
 internationals, national union centres, individual unions and hundreds
 of local union branches all over the world.
 
 The Cyber Picket Line features union sites from every continent in the
 world ranging from South African miners to Brazilian dockers; from
 council shop stewards in Sheffield to journalists in Hong Kong; from
 Croatian railworkers to Canadian loggers. 
 
 The effects are already being felt as workers build new links across
 continents and oceans. The Liverpool Dockers campaign, the Korean
 trade unionists battle against repressive laws and the US Firestone
 workers have all used the internet and the world wide web to organise
 solidarity action and to build support.
 
 Steve Davies, the co-ordinator of the new web site said:
 
 "For too long unions all over the world have been on the ropes. Now
 we're on the Net and its already beginning to pay off. It's now
 possible for workers to communicate effectively with each other as
 never before. 
 
 "It is also possible for rank and file stewards and branch activists
 to have access to the sort of information resource and research
 capacity that was previously only available to senior full time
 officers. It is potentially one of the most powerful and democratic
 weapons at the disposal of the labour movement.
 
 "I hope that this site helps local branches all over the world take
 advantage of the resources that exist, make the contacts that count,
 and use 21st century techniques  to rebuild international solidarity."
 
 
 ENDS
 
 NOTES FOR EDITORS
 
 The site co-ordinator is Steve Davies. He lives in Cardiff, and works
 at the University of Wales Cardiff in adult education where he's been
 since the beginning of 1996. Before that he spent 11 years working at
 the London headquarters of a British Civil Service union (now called
 PTC). He started as a research officer, later specialising in
 privatisation and contracting out, before becoming national press
 officer and Assistant to the General Secretary.
 
 A Spanish version of the site is under construction (translation being
 done by Companero David Jones of Pontypridd and Zaragoza). Eventually
 the site may appear in several other languages. All the tricky techie
 work for this site was done by Sioned Rogers of CapitalNet, the server
 for Cardiff, who have also provided the webspace.
 
 








[PEN-L:9796] US Steel and Finance Capital

1997-05-01 Thread Michael Perelman

Tavis and others brought up the case of U.S. Steel.

Many of the great industrial organizations were built by industrialists,
whose main interest was industry.  Carnegie was a sharper, but he was
still very interested in making steel at the lowest possible cost.  Over
time, many of these became more financially oriented, erasing the
distinction between finance and industrial capital.  Today U.S. Steel is
USX, you can guess what the x stands for.

Here is a short section from my End of Economics book dealing with the
transformation of U.S. Steel.

In the midst of the Great Depression, the editors of "Fortune• magazine
reported:
##Now there are two possible ways to look at a steel plant or an ore
mine.  One is as an investment that must be protected.  The other is as
an instrument of production, to be cherished only so long as it cannot
be replaced by a more efficient instrument.  The first may be called the
banker's point of view; the second, the industrialist's.  [Anon. 1936,
p. 170]
According to the investigators at Fortune, United States Steel "has
always been a management with a financial rather than an industrial turn
of mind" (Anon., p. 63).  This perspective reflected the origins of the
corporation.  "The Steel Corporation was founded by financiers, has been
dominated ever since by financially-minded men" (ibid., p. 170).
While many industries used the expansive conditions of the 1920s to
develop improved technologies, the management of United States Steel
chose a different track.  As a result:
##the chief energies of the men who guided the Corporation were directed
to preventing deterioration in the investment value of the enormous
properties confided to their care.  To achieve this, they consistently
tried to freeze the steel at present, or better yet, past levels  
Any radical change in steel technology would render worthless millions
of dollars of the Corporation's plant investment.  [ibid., pp. 170 and
173]
While firms in less concentrated industries attempted to rationalize
their operations and prune costs, the financially-oriented management of
United States Steel was intent on maintaining the status quo.  Perhaps
Hoover, the engineer, realized that protecting the corporate sector from
competitive forces would allow more firms to emulate United States
Steel, making an economic disaster inevitable.
Even the Great Depression was insufficient to make this firm change its
ways.  Over time, the firm's stodgy, hidebound management found itself
humbled both by foreign competition and aggressive mini-mills. 
Management changed the corporate name to USX and considered retreating
from the steel altogether.  Perhaps, United States Steel represented the
ultimate verdict on Morgan and the corporatists.

-- 
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929
 
Tel. 916-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]





[PEN-L:9798] Re: MAI and Foreign Control in Canada

1997-05-01 Thread Bill Burgess


Shawgi Tell noted a couple of days ago that foreign control of corporate
revenues in Canada rose by 1.3 points to 29.8% of the total in 1995, and
that this was the second largest yearly rise ever recorded. 

I don't know Shawgi's point of view on this question, but the implication
of his observation is consistant with the usual conception of Canada as a
semi-colony which is slipping further under US domination as a result of
'free' trade agreements. The **nationalist** opposition to MAI that I
questioned last week is also (partially) rooted in such approaches.

What does the data on foreign control really say about this issue? I
prefer to argue this using data on *assets* (a stock variable) rather than
*revenues* (a flow variable), since the latter is heavily influenced
by the business cycle and foreign controlled firms are concentrated in
sectors with higher revenue-to-asset ratios.   

Statistics Canada's figure for foreign control of all corporate assets
in Canada rose to 21% in 1995. This increase restored foreign control to
the 21% rate previously reached in 1990, and is only up 0.5 percentage
points since 1988 (the first year for which this data for *all*
industries is available). 

In other words there has not been much of a change. While foreign
control rose in *non-financial* sectors to 24.3%, this was partially
offset by a slight drop to 17.6% in *finance and insurance* sectors. 

Nor does the data on *US* control of *all* corporate assets indicate any great
increase attributable to the FTA or NAFTA, at least so far.  While the
11.4% US control of all corporate assets in Canada in 1995 is a
notable increase over 1994 (when it was 10.8%), it is only 0.4 points
higher than in 1988, the year before the FTA took effect. For most of this
period it has been lower than before 'free' trade. 

Perhaps most important, and  contrary to the usual assumptions, the
level of foreign control in Canada has **declined substantially** over the
last few decades. The data series on foreign control of *all* industries
only goes back to 1988, but if we assume the trend here has been
similar to that for the *non-financial* half of the corporate economy (for
which the earlier data is available), then the current range of foreign
(and US) control in Canada is lower than it has been for about half a
century! 

Foreign control of *non-financial* industries peaked in the early 1970s,
but Canadian capitalists have regained about one-third of all
non-financial assets in Canada since then, and they have retained the
decisive control they have always had over the *financial*  half of the
economy. One measure that highlights the strength of Canadian capital is
that Statistics Canada reports that in 1992 they controlled 96.5% of the
assets of the *25 largest enterprises* (corporations grouped under common
control) in Canada.

The rate of foreign control for *all* industries in Canada cited
above (and that for the largest 25 enterprises) is considerably lower
than the *non-financial* rates Canadian nationalists have
traditionally cited for their purposes. However, it is true foreign
control is higher in Canada than in most -  but not all - major OECD
countries.  Other countries do not collect data on foreign control
comparable to that cited above, but if we use OECD data on the ratio of
the stock of (inward) FDI to GDP as a basis, foreign control in
the UK (!!) and the Netherlands is **higher** than in Canada.  

Further, the level of inward FDI should be considered in tandem with that
of outward FDI. *Canadian* capitalists hold more FDI *abroad* per Canadian
than do their competitors in the US, Japan, Germany and France relative to
the latters' populations. In recent years, the flow of Canadian FDI to the
US has *exceeded* US FDI coming into Canada. 

I think this is a pretty impressive record, and to bring it back to the 
MAI issue, one that makes we wonder why we would want to offer Canadian 
capitalists national protection from their foreign competitors.  

I live in Canada so I've concentrated on the usual suggestion  that
protectionism is more appropriate here than in other imperialist
countries.  Since I'm working on a paper on this point I would appreciate
any comments and criticism on at least ***this aspect*** of the debate.
   
Bill Burgess
University of B.C.
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
home (604) 255-5957
fax c/o (604) 822-6150






[PEN-L:9797] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread blairs

What a romantic account!

I don't think anybody in their right mind came to the Amherst conference
looking for an activist focus. The conferences have been around long enough
for people to know what's up. Back in the late 1980s a friend of mine who
was active in Sister Cities Projects and who worked as a nurse went up to
the conference (it might have been the first) and returned with the
observation that she did not understand a single word that anybody was
saying. Pretty soon the word got out. Activists stayed home.

So as this filtering process started to take place, the people who did make
the trek *understood* what the conference was about. It was an academic
conference not that much different from MLA conferences, etc. This
conference was a gathering of the post-Marxist tribe. Every graduate
student in America who was into  Althusser, Zizek, Bourdieu, etc. would
have to consider putting money aside for hotel and transportation costs.
Later in hotel rooms people would drink Jack Daniels from the bottle and
gossip about goings-on in the groves of academe.

What happened in December 1996 was unexpected. A whole number of people,
possibly a majority of the conference attendees, came with a theoretical
approach to Marxism that was much more in line with what I call classical
Marxism. People like Ellen Meiksins Wood, John Bellamy Foster, Doug Henwood
and Meera Nanda have been carving out a space for this current for a few
years now. When graduate students and louts like me came up to the
conference with an identification with this current, we clashed with the
post-Marxists. The clash could have been avoided if the organizers had the
good sense to not have such lopsided plenaries. That they lacked such good
sense reminds me of the public relations failure of Social Text after the
Sokal Affair. It became tempting for Andrew Ross et al to label Sokal as an
enemy of multiculturalism rather than to engage with his ideas. Likewise,
it became easier for the Amherst conference organizers to view the
disruptions from the floor as evidence of intolerant behavior on the part
of others rather than their own exclusionary practices.

Louis Proyect






Blair Sandler
[EMAIL PROTECTED]







[PEN-L:9790] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread Doug Henwood

Stephen Cullenberg wrote:

Yet, we are not, and never have pretended to be, as ecumenical as say URPE
and the RRPE.

This then is Rethinking? My first reaction to the conference was too much
Re, not enough thinking, but now I'm even questioning the Re.

A nonecumenical group of people who agree on fundamental things and view
plenaries as a form of preaching to a mixed crowd of converted and
unconverted? Did the presence of a large critical minority seem something
worthy of ackknowledging as something other than a personal attack? This is
exactly what I meant by the plenaries having shown signs of hardening into
orthodoxy, which as the postmodernists have taught us well, is defined
through exclusion. Is the devotion to polyvocality just another empty
signifier?


Doug

--

Doug Henwood
Left Business Observer
250 W 85 St
New York NY 10024-3217 USA
+1-212-874-4020 voice  +1-212-874-3137 fax
email: mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
web: http://www.panix.com/~dhenwood/LBO_home.html







[PEN-L:9795] Re: game theory torture

1997-05-01 Thread HANLY


Recently Devine writes as follows:


The CIA's prescriptions, in sum, are to mess with the prisoners' minds
(and, if need be, their bodies) in order to _create_ the textbook
prisoners' dilemma, to encourage each prisoner to "defect," to turn in his
or her comrades. The textbook treatment _assumes_ that the prisoners are
already atomistic individuals and there is _no need_ to plumb the depths of
their psyches in order to make them that way. In fact, the vast majority of
economists reject the need to study the depths of psychology at all;
instead, they simply assume that people "maximize utility," having no sense
of honor or morality, solidarity or self-esteem. It treats the fact that
many if not most prisoners do not defect as a "paradox" rather than as
showing up the severe limitations of the theory.


COMMENT: There are two competing views of the non-repeating PD. While there is
a standard argument that concludes that the dominant and rational strategy is to
defect,(the Dominance argument)
 there is a so-called symmetry argument that can be traced back at least
to Anatol Rapoport in FIGHTS GAMES AND DEBATES (1960). This argument has been
elaborated by L Davis in Prisoners, Paradox, and Rationality. AMERICAN
PHILOSOPHICAL QUARTERLY 14: 319-27.) A somewhat different argument but equally
critical of the standard argument is McClennen E. Prisoners Dilemma and
Resolute Choice. In Campbell R. and Sowden L.(eds) PARADOXES OF RATIONALITY AND
CO-operation UBC Press 1985. The basic idea behind the symmetry argument
is that each prisoner being rational and in the same situation will see that
the dominance argument leads to a sub-optimal result FOR BOTH as contrasted
with their both remaining silent. THerefore
as rational agents they will resolutely choose, to use McLennen's term, not to
defect in order to improve the result for them both. This avoids the
paradoxical result of the traditional argument in which allegedly rational
choice leads to sub-optimal outcomes for both participants.
I agree with Davis and
McLennen but not with Rapoport because Rapoport thinks that somehow altruism is
involved. ALtruism is not involved at all. The argument works even for
rational egoists who have no interest per se in the welfare of others. However,
when it is necessary to co-operate to maximize the welfare of each it is
rational to do so. I have an unpublished (but presented) paper that argues
against the dominance argument, and also Parfit's(REASONS AND PERSONS 1984)
 critique of ethical egoism
as self-defeating as shown by the PD. I think the PD shows no such thing.
I also think that Gauthier(MORALS BY AGREEMENT 1986)
 is incorrect in thinking that unconstrained
maximisers would choose defection as the rational strategy in PD contexts.
Of course many of the things discussed in the literature as PD's have nothing
to do with PD's. For example the position of polluters who have no motive to
install pollution devices in a competitive market even though this might
advance the public welfare. In these cases all polluters defecting from the
welfare producing policy does not on the whole hurt them, so there is nothing
at all paradoxical involved. One case that is like that of the PD is that
involving manufacture of aerosols without fluorocarbon propellants.
 If everyone did it, it would
cheaper for all manufacturers, and in that sense in all their interests, but
no one manufacturer will do it because they do not want to give up the market
that still exists for the earlier propellant. Manufacturers did not oppose
a ban on fluorocarbon propellants since it would provide assurance that
no firm could defect and capture a market niche.
  CHeers, Ken Hanly
  Cheers, Ken Hanly






[PEN-L:9799] Re: US Steel and Finance Capital

1997-05-01 Thread Anthony P D'Costa

I have some queries since I am wriing a book on technology and the steel
industry (1950-1996).  See below.

Anthony P. D'Costa
Associate Professor Senior Fellow
Comparative International Development   Department of Economics
University of WashingtonNational University of Singapore
1103 A Street   10 Kent Ridge Crescent
Tacoma, WA 98402 USASingapore 119260

On Thu, 1 May 1997, Michael Perelman wrote:

 Tavis and others brought up the case of U.S. Steel.
 
 Many of the great industrial organizations were built by industrialists,
 whose main interest was industry.  Carnegie was a sharper, but he was
 still very interested in making steel at the lowest possible cost.  Over
 time, many of these became more financially oriented, erasing the
 distinction between finance and industrial capital.  Today U.S. Steel is
 USX, you can guess what the x stands for.
 
 Here is a short section from my End of Economics book dealing with the
 transformation of U.S. Steel.
 
 In the midst of the Great Depression, the editors of "Fortune• magazine
 reported:
 ##Now there are two possible ways to look at a steel plant or an ore
 mine.  One is as an investment that must be protected.  The other is as
 an instrument of production, to be cherished only so long as it cannot
 be replaced by a more efficient instrument.  The first may be called the
 banker's point of view; the second, the industrialist's.  [Anon. 1936,
 p. 170]
 According to the investigators at Fortune, United States Steel "has
 always been a management with a financial rather than an industrial turn
 of mind" (Anon., p. 63).  This perspective reflected the origins of the
 corporation.  "The Steel Corporation was founded by financiers, has been
 dominated ever since by financially-minded men" (ibid., p. 170).
 While many industries used the expansive conditions of the 1920s to
 develop improved technologies, the management of United States Steel
 chose a different track.  

Can you give me some specific examples of what technologies we are talking
about?  The basic argument is correct i.e. the attitude toward
technological change (something that happened in the 1950s, BOF versus
OHF).  But "sunk costs" are important to the direction of technological
change for a firm.

As a result:
 ##the chief energies of the men who guided the Corporation were directed
 to preventing deterioration in the investment value of the enormous
 properties confided to their care.  To achieve this, they consistently
 tried to freeze the steel at present, or better yet, past levels  
 Any radical change in steel technology would render worthless millions
 of dollars of the Corporation's plant investment.  [ibid., pp. 170 and
 173]
 While firms in less concentrated industries attempted to rationalize
 their operations and prune costs, the financially-oriented management of
 United States Steel was intent on maintaining the status quo.  Perhaps
 Hoover, the engineer, realized that protecting the corporate sector from
 competitive forces would allow more firms to emulate United States
 Steel, making an economic disaster inevitable.
 Even the Great Depression was insufficient to make this firm change its
 ways.  Over time, the firm's stodgy, hidebound management found itself
 humbled both by foreign competition and aggressive mini-mills. 
 Management changed the corporate name to USX and considered retreating
 from the steel altogether.  Perhaps, United States Steel represented the
 ultimate verdict on Morgan and the corporatists.
 
 -- 
 Michael Perelman
 Economics Department
 California State University
 Chico, CA 95929
  
 Tel. 916-898-5321
 E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 






[PEN-L:9788] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread blairs

[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

Several people on PEN-L were at the conference and will undoubtedly offer
different perspectives, but the bottom line is that a bunch of orthodox
marxists were upset that suggestions from speakers were not the same as the
answers offered by orthodox marxists. Because we know that orthodox marxism
has all the answers. oh well.

Now Blair, I knew you were a partisan, but I thought you were a fair guy.

Doug, I think it's fair to say my opinion and indicate clearly that it *is*
my opinion, that others will have other opinions. I was hoping you'd be one
of them; Louis Proyect was also there. I've read a number of pieces by
Nanda Meera and I stand by my opinion.

Personally, I agree about the Shiva/Harding panel, also that Balibar talked
too long (though I wouldn't say "gassed"). The dissenters impressed me
about as much as Shiva and Harding, which is to say, not at all.

Blair



_

Blair Sandler   "If I had to choose a reductionist paradigm,
[EMAIL PROTECTED]  Classical Marxism is a damned good one."
_







[PEN-L:9787] re: Environmental Economics

1997-05-01 Thread Rosser Jr, John Barkley

 Actually what I find useful and interesting about the 
Coase Theorem (not really a theorem, BTW) is that it shows 
how hard it is to have the conditions under which a free 
market will internalize externalities easily.  So, positive 
externalities between two neighboring parties, such as 
orchard owners and beekeepers, are easily negotiated, big 
whoop.  But most real world externalities involve lots of 
parties over larger areas with confused property 
situtations.  Coase says this is no go, and this appears to 
be the rule, not the exception.
Barkley Rosser
On Thu, 1 May 1997 13:14:12 -0700 (PDT) Robin Hahnel 
[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

 I second Jim Devine's message about neoclassicals and the environment in
 its entirety. The astounding misinterpretation of what the Coase theorem
 actually tells any reasonable analyst about the likelihood of environmental
 efficiency being achieved through voluntary and private negotiations of
 polluters and pollution victims is an excellent case in point. A reasonable
 reading of the theorem AND ITS INCREDIBLE LIST OF NECESSARY ASSUMPTIONS gives
 more than enough theoretical reasons for anyone who cares about the environ-
 ment to immediately embrace a government role!

-- 
Rosser Jr, John Barkley
[EMAIL PROTECTED]







[PEN-L:9789] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread blairs

Louis, there was nothing "snide" or "patronizing" about my private message
to you. I don't play games. When I like what people are doing I say so;
when I don't like it, I say so. Pretty straightforward, I think.

It's absurd to say I'm "dissembling" about my connections to RM (I had
nothing to do with the conference directly, though). PEN-L has had several
long series of discussions about modernist and postmodernist Marxism in
which I participated actively and openly as a post-modernist Marxist and
member of the RM editorial board. Yup. I'm counting on everyone having
forgotten those discussions from, what several months ago? Damn, guess it
didn't work with you, Louis, and now you've exposed me.

I don't understand your reference to "postmodernist/Althusserian/green
regionalism trip": how does "green regionalism" fit in there?

Blair

Yeah, this question of personal insults rings a bell with me. Blair sent me
some snide private mail shortly after I showed up on PEN-L giving me a
patronizing pat on the back for my AM posts, but slapping my wrist for
"boorish" behavior at the Amherst Conference. During the discussion period
following the first plenary with the ineffable Vandana Shiva, I charged
Richard Wolff with running an exclusionary panel and that in the future
such bullshit should not be allowed.

By the way, isn't it important for Blair to identify himself as a member of
the collective that sponsored the Conference? This is highly scandalous
when people hide such information. Where's Jerry Levy when you need him?
Jerry, it's time for a crusade against Blair Sandler's dissembling before
the august body of PEN-L. The nerve of Blair to hide his connections. Oh,
perfidy.

The problem with the Amherst school is that it has placed all of its eggs
in a rotting basket. This whole postmodernist/Althusserian/green
regionalism trip is getting very dated. We got a visitation from a group of
Teresa Morton's acolytes over on the Spoons Marxism list loaded for bear.
They were going to slay all postmodernists, including *Doug Henwood and
Ellen Meiksins Wood*. Yes, it does sound weird, but these are weird people.
A witty comrade from Portugal commented that postmodernism is dead as a
doornail and not worth the trouble of killing twice. He suggested that
Marxism's main opponent are the old-fashioned ones of pragmatism and idealism.

I think there's something to be said for that. It's getting harder and
harder to simply make the usual allegations against "orthodox" Marxism.
(Actually, classical Marxism is a much more descriptive term and is
embraced by the new journal "Historical Materialism" that just got founded
over in Great Britain.) The reason for this is that the objective
circumstances that led to the pomo doctrine have largely disappeared. 1997
looks a lot different than pre-crash 1987 when characters like Baudrillard
had the ability to captivate the thinking of humanities professors in America.

Louis Proyect




_

Blair Sandler   "If I had to choose a reductionist paradigm,
[EMAIL PROTECTED]  Classical Marxism is a damned good one."
_







[PEN-L:9765] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread blairs

I just heard a description of the "Rethinking Marxism" conference that
occurred in Amherst late last year. The reporter (Olga Celle de Bowman, a
sociologist from Peru) said that there was a tremendous amount of (verbal)
conflict between the audience and the speakers at the plenaries, something
I hadn't heard about before. She said that the activists in the audience
were objecting to the lack of answers to the key "what is to be done?"
question and the lack of any kind of orientation toward people outside of
academe. Was anyone on pen-l at the conference and has a different
perspective on the conflict?




in pen-l solidarity,

Jim Devine   [EMAIL PROTECTED]
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
Econ. Dept., Loyola Marymount Univ.
7900 Loyola Blvd., Los Angeles, CA 90045-8410 USA
310/338-2948 (daytime, during workweek); FAX: 310/338-1950
"It takes a busload of faith to get by." -- Lou Reed.

Several people on PEN-L were at the conference and will undoubtedly offer
different perspectives, but the bottom line is that a bunch of orthodox
marxists were upset that suggestions from speakers were not the same as the
answers offered by orthodox marxists. Because we know that orthodox marxism
has all the answers. oh well.






Blair Sandler
[EMAIL PROTECTED]







[PEN-L:9768] Essentialist humor

1997-05-01 Thread Wojtek Sokolowski

A panda walks into a restaurant, sits down, and orders a sandwich.  After
finishing the sandwich, the panda pulls out a gun and shoots the waiter dead.  

As the panda stands up to leave, the mangers shouts, "Hey! Where are you
going?  You just shot my waiter and you did not pay your bill!"

The panda yells back to the restaurant manager, "Hey buddy, I'm a panda!
Look it up!" And walks out.

Nonplussed, the manager opens his dictionary and finds the following definition:

   Panda: A tree dwelling mammal of Asian origin, characterised by distinct
  black and white coloring.  Eats shoots and leaves.

wojtek sokolowski 
institute for policy studies
johns hopkins university
baltimore, md 21218
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
voice: (410) 516-4056
fax:   (410) 516-8233


** REDUCE MENTAL POLLUTION - LOBOTOMIZE PUNDITS! **
+--+
|There is  no such thing as society,  only the individuals | 
|who constitute it. -Margaret Thatcher |
|  | 
|  | 
|There is  no  such thing  as  government or  corporations,|
|only  the  individuals  who  lust  for  power  and  money.|
|   -no apologies to Margaret Thatcher |
+--+
*DROGI KURWA BUDUJA, A NIE MA DOKAD ISC






[PEN-L:9771] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread Antonio Callari

I was at the conference (in fact, I was one of the organizers). There were
some conflicts. Most of the conflicts were around the question of
postmodernism. I don't want to enter again into the merits and demerits of
postmodernism. The positions are somewhat known about that. I would like to
say, however, that the impression that the conference did not address the
question of "what is to be done" that is of interest to activists is, in my
view, wrong. One of the plenaries was on the experiences of Latin American
socialism. Again, one might quarrel with whether postmodernist forms of
activism are valid, (and the discussion about a sociaslist strategy in
Latin America, including a glorifying and moving representation of the
Zapatista movement, did have a postmodernist tone), but that is quite
different from saying that activism was not part of the conference. I think
the gist of Blair Sandler's message was correct: that traditional,
orthodox, views of activism were not the dominant ones in the plenaries,
and in fact were not very welkl represented in the plenaries, and that
those who held those views mistook the non-dominance/presence of these
views as an absence of activism itself: which is simply incorrect. One
other point to be made is that, perhaps, the distinction between academics
and activists is sometimes overdrawn. The proper distinction should be
between activist academics and non-activist academics. Most of the people
who talk a lot about activism are themselves either academics (either
students or professors) or enmeshed in a network of academic discourses and
processes; just as people who are academics are often enmeshed in activist
discourses and practices, even if they do not advertise it=themselves, or
glamorize it=themselves, or romanticize it=themselves.

Antonio Callari

  I just heard a description of the "Rethinking Marxism" conference that
occurred in Amherst late last year. The reporter (Olga Celle de Bowman, a
sociologist from Peru) said that there was a tremendous amount of (verbal)
conflict between the audience and the speakers at the plenaries, something
I hadn't heard about before. She said that the activists in the audience
were objecting to the lack of answers to the key "what is to be done?"
question and the lack of any kind of orientation toward people outside of
academe. Was anyone on pen-l at the conference and has a different
perspective on the conflict?




in pen-l solidarity,

Jim Devine   [EMAIL PROTECTED]
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
Econ. Dept., Loyola Marymount Univ.
7900 Loyola Blvd., Los Angeles, CA 90045-8410 USA
310/338-2948 (daytime, during workweek); FAX: 310/338-1950
"It takes a busload of faith to get by." -- Lou Reed.

Antonio Callari
E-MAIL: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
POST MAIL:  Department of Economics
Franklin and Marshall College
Lancaster PA 17604-3003
PHONE:  717/291-3947
FAX:717/291-4369







[PEN-L:9774] Re: Barbara Ehrenreich on War

1997-05-01 Thread Wojtek Sokolowski

While I generally agree with Louis' argument, I also believe that his
argument would have gained from making a distinction between spontaneous and
institutionalised behaviour.  In essence, the bourgeois pundits argue that
bourgeois social institutions originate in the law of human nature.
Ehrenreich follows the suit, but adds: "let's change human nature (as if it
were a yuppie life style) to get rid of the institution.

Of course, similar arguments are raised re. any other institution.  Property
relations, we are told, originate in the "natural" desire to acquire useful
materila goods.  Racism originates in our "natural" propensity to stereotype
or fear people who are different than ourselves.  And so on, and so forth.

The appeal of this mythology is that the antecedent asserting that "people
tend to engage in conflicting, hoarding, or stereotypong behaviour" is
essentially true.  But despite that, the argument is a nonsequitur, because
it was constructed in a flawed manner.  In essence, it is a logical fallacy
known as confirming the antecedent; e.g. "if people are bellicose by nature,
then wars are frequent; "wars are freguent; ergo: people are bellicose in
nature."  According to the same logic "if Richard M. Nixon was assassinated,
then Richard M. Nixon is dead; Richard M. Nixon is dead, ergo: Richard M.
Nixon was assassinated."

Distinguishing between spontaneous and institutionalised behaviour, the
former falls on a continuum ranging between "good" and "bad", "selfish" and
"selfless" "rational" and irrational" and so forth.  In short, we are
capable of any sort of behaviour.  The role of social instituions is to
encourage some of those behaviours while discouraging others.  It is like a
bullhorn -- it amplifies only certain sounds (namely the speech of the
person who holds it), but it does not pick up (or even drowns) other sounds.

With that in mind, it is easy to see that social institutions, like war,
private property, division of labour, or racism, are maintained by those in
a position to do so, namely -- the ruling classes who also control the means
of mental production.  

There is another question, however, how these institutions are being
established and maintained.  Louis  suggests that they are being simply
imposed by the ruling class  -- but such a view simply does not hold water.
A more useful view is that while social institutions do serve the interests
of the elite, they also serve, in various ways (that may or may not
correspond with the interests of the elites), various interests and needs of
the ruled.  In other words, the ruled collaborate, willingly and
unadvertently, with the elites in the creation and maintenance of social
institutions.

Examples are abundant.  Michael Burawoy (_Manufacturing Consent_) shows how
workers in Chicago manufacturing plants use capitalist institutions
(competition) for their own purposes that have little to do with the
preservation of capitalism.  In the same vein, part of the Blach population
in South Africa (the Bantu-stan elites) were staunch supporters of the
appertheid, because it gave them a relatively privileged position over other
Blacks (something that they would not be able to maintain under a democratic
rule).  In the same vein, the nazis coopeted the women liberation movement
in Germany (see Klaudia Koontz, _Mothers in the Fatherland_).

I think a common mistake of the old day socialists is a belief that the
masses would revolt againts their rulers as soon as an opportunity arises
and, even more importantly,  the revolutionary vanguard will give a signal.
I am afraid it ain't so.  

One of the most frightening powers of the state and social institutions
(modern and ancient alike) is its capacity tor organize people against their
own interests, and even for their own destruction.  Diatribes denouncing
these institutions as a ploy serving the elite interests do little to help
us understand how they extert their influence on common people.  In the same
vein, the modern military and its weaponry is obviously a tool of the ruling
class to maintain their hegemony and keep the lower classes in line.  But
that fact does not yet explain why and how the lower classes are fascinated
with the military and weapons (cf. the militias) despite the fact that these
are the proverbial Damocles' sword hanging over their heads.

In that respect, Echrenreich's bourgeois morality play can offer more
insights into the process, than a conventional class analysis.

wojtek sokolowski 
institute for policy studies
johns hopkins university
baltimore, md 21218
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
voice: (410) 516-4056
fax:   (410) 516-8233


** REDUCE MENTAL POLLUTION - LOBOTOMIZE PUNDITS! **
+--+
|There is  no such thing as society,  only the individuals | 
|who constitute it. -Margaret Thatcher |
|  | 
| 

[PEN-L:9776] henwood

1997-05-01 Thread Ed Herman

Hi, hope no one minds, but I forwarded Doug's critique of Ed Herman's Z
article to Ed, and here's his reply.  Elaine
Original message
Dear Elaine: I've put up a few notes on Henwood's defense of his citation
of Larry Summers. Can you put it into circulation on Pen-L (if that's the
right web site)?

 Best, Ed Herman

PS: I did write to Robert and Ethel after last talking with you.
--
Reply to Doug Henwood's defense of his reliance on Larry Summers:

1. Henwood says that Summers is not always wrong and has "done a
lot of very useful academic work..."  But Henwood fails to note
that that academic work was many years ago--Henwood cites Summers
as of 1991, in his World Bank employment role that preceded his
phase as a Clinton administration official. So his academic work
would seem pretty much irrelevant; his commitment to the
principles--and principals--of the New World Order in 1991 and
after would seem obvious. A "political agenda" supportive of FDI
and globalization as beneficial would also seem a requirement for
the kind of work Summers has been doing. Would Henwood suggest that
Summers could take a position questioning free trade and FDI? If
not, is Henwood not neglecting "context" in citing Summers as a
presumably objective scholar?

2. Henwood says I rely on "assertion" and don't bother with the
substance of his argument or "evidence." But my article has more
"evidence" in it than Henwood's, and much of his evidence is a
quoting of qualitative opinions, notably by Summers. I give
evidence on financial flows that Henwood largely ignores, but which
are vastly more important than 30 years ago, and far more important
than in 1913 in effects on policy. Henwood's evidence is also dated
and backward, not forward looking. For example, his quote from the
1991 Summers statement asks whether the telecommunications
revolution has really had a major impact? But we are in the midst
of a telecom revolution that is advancing rapidly (and has gained
further strength from the recent WTO deal getting scores of
countries to agree to privatize). Furthermore, even if
manufacturing hasn't been "fundamentally altered" (whatever that
means), cross-border integration of production keeps growing in
importance. And while sellers have always tried to "locate
production at the lowest cost location," you would think a leftist
would recognize that the increased mobility of capital, greater
power of IMF and World Bank, and new agreements protecting
investment rights, are widening options for sellers and that a
"reserve army" that runs from China to Russia to Indonesia to
Mexico (etc.) represents something a bit different and worth
noting.

  The economist Richard DuBoff, who also wasn't too keen on
Henwood's analysis of globaloney, sent Henwood a detailed statement
with a lot of "evidence," to which Henwood hasn't yet replied.

3. Henwood says that globalization "is often held up as the reason
things can't get any better." But if it is an important fact, we
can't deny its reality because it is used is some particular way.
Furthermore, why do a Larry Summers and the conservative Martin
Wolf go along with Henwood in denying a powerful negative effect of
globalization? It is because if it were admitted to be having
damaging effects on the incomes of the majority and killing social
democratic policy there would be a political demand for bringing it
under control. I made this point in my Z article, but I haven't yet
heard Henwood come to grips with it.

4. He repeats his statement that the focus on globalization
"deflects attention away from the causes of globalization," etc.
This is not true--as I point out in my article, it focuses
attention on the particular forms of capitalism that are important
in the age of globalization, like the rise in power and spread of
TNCs, financial flows and speculation, the role of the IMF and
World Bank in serving the TNCs and the like. On the other hand, the
Henwood position, which denies the importance of globalization,
deflects attention away from globalization and its damaging
capitalist--institutional causes to vague generalities like "the
quest for higher profits and stock prices." Beyond that, if as
Summers and Henwood agree, "the revolution is merely incremental,
and not something all so fundamentally new," why worry about
transnationalization, global mergers, IMF rules, and the like?
"Natura non facit saltum" was the rule for neoclassical economist
Alfred Marshall and his successors as well, including Summers, and
apparently Henwood.

---Edward S. Herman





[PEN-L:9775] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread Louis Proyect

 I think
the gist of Blair Sandler's message was correct: that traditional,
orthodox, views of activism were not the dominant ones in the plenaries,
and in fact were not very welkl represented in the plenaries, and that
those who held those views mistook the non-dominance/presence of these
views as an absence of activism itself: which is simply incorrect. One
other point to be made is that, perhaps, the distinction between academics
and activists is sometimes overdrawn. The proper distinction should be
between activist academics and non-activist academics. Most of the people
who talk a lot about activism are themselves either academics (either
students or professors) or enmeshed in a network of academic discourses and
processes; just as people who are academics are often enmeshed in activist
discourses and practices, even if they do not advertise it=themselves, or
glamorize it=themselves, or romanticize it=themselves.

Antonio Callari


I don't think anybody in their right mind came to the Amherst conference
looking for an activist focus. The conferences have been around long enough
for people to know what's up. Back in the late 1980s a friend of mine who
was active in Sister Cities Projects and who worked as a nurse went up to
the conference (it might have been the first) and returned with the
observation that she did not understand a single word that anybody was
saying. Pretty soon the word got out. Activists stayed home.

So as this filtering process started to take place, the people who did make
the trek *understood* what the conference was about. It was an academic
conference not that much different from MLA conferences, etc. This
conference was a gathering of the post-Marxist tribe. Every graduate
student in America who was into  Althusser, Zizek, Bourdieu, etc. would
have to consider putting money aside for hotel and transportation costs.
Later in hotel rooms people would drink Jack Daniels from the bottle and
gossip about goings-on in the groves of academe.

What happened in December 1996 was unexpected. A whole number of people,
possibly a majority of the conference attendees, came with a theoretical
approach to Marxism that was much more in line with what I call classical
Marxism. People like Ellen Meiksins Wood, John Bellamy Foster, Doug Henwood
and Meera Nanda have been carving out a space for this current for a few
years now. When graduate students and louts like me came up to the
conference with an identification with this current, we clashed with the
post-Marxists. The clash could have been avoided if the organizers had the
good sense to not have such lopsided plenaries. That they lacked such good
sense reminds me of the public relations failure of Social Text after the
Sokal Affair. It became tempting for Andrew Ross et al to label Sokal as an
enemy of multiculturalism rather than to engage with his ideas. Likewise,
it became easier for the Amherst conference organizers to view the
disruptions from the floor as evidence of intolerant behavior on the part
of others rather than their own exclusionary practices.

Louis Proyect






[PEN-L:9777] Re: tenure

1997-05-01 Thread Susan Pashkoff

For the sake of clarity, although there is no formal 'tenure'in the 
UK, there are permanent positions. If you are hired for a permanent 
track position, you are permanent usually after 6 months. The only 
way that you can be fired is if the department is dissolved and/or 
there is no work for you to do in the University. The UK has 
mandatory retirement. The situation here is the opposite of the 
manner in which the situation is going in the states: there is job 
security, but room for new people.

Susan Pashkoff


 Date:  Wed, 30 Apr 1997 15:14:08 -0700 (PDT)
 Reply-to:  [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 From:  James Devine [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Subject:   [PEN-L:9761] tenure

 susan, any comments?
 
 Original message
 what experience do people in places like the UK have with the absense of
 tenure for professors? is it as bad as some people in the US fear? is there
 a lot of violation of academic freedom?
 
 
 
 
 in pen-l solidarity,
 
 Jim Devine   [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Econ. Dept., Loyola Marymount Univ.
 7900 Loyola Blvd., Los Angeles, CA 90045-8410 USA
 310/338-2948 (daytime, during workweek); FAX: 310/338-1950
 "It takes a busload of faith to get by." -- Lou Reed.
 





[PEN-L:9779] Re: henwood

1997-05-01 Thread Doug Henwood

Ed Herman wrote:

1. Henwood says that Summers is not always wrong and has "done a
lot of very useful academic work..."  But Henwood fails to note
that that academic work was many years ago--Henwood cites Summers
as of 1991, in his World Bank employment role that preceded his
phase as a Clinton administration official. So his academic work
would seem pretty much irrelevant; his commitment to the
principles--and principals--of the New World Order in 1991 and
after would seem obvious. A "political agenda" supportive of FDI
and globalization as beneficial would also seem a requirement for
the kind of work Summers has been doing. Would Henwood suggest that
Summers could take a position questioning free trade and FDI? If
not, is Henwood not neglecting "context" in citing Summers as a
presumably objective scholar?

I brought up Summers' academic work because his positions, first with the
World Bank and then with the U.S. Treasury, were in themselves being used
to discredit his argument. Yeah, so Larry Summers is a bourgeois pig. But
that doesn't mean he's always wrong, does it? Especially when he's writing
a memo for intra-pen consumption by his comradely herd of piglets.

2. Henwood says I rely on "assertion" and don't bother with the
substance of his argument or "evidence." But my article has more
"evidence" in it than Henwood's, and much of his evidence is a
quoting of qualitative opinions, notably by Summers. I give
evidence on financial flows that Henwood largely ignores, but which
are vastly more important than 30 years ago, and far more important
than in 1913 in effects on policy.

I really don't want to get into a "my evidence is longer than your
evidence" debate, but this is a really preposterous claim. I've spent years
writing more articles with more numbers in them than just about anyone in
the field of left-wing economic journalism. On PEN-L the other day I quoted
from a longer piece, which was itself a sequel to an even longer one. I've
continued to analyze the figures behind the globalization mania, and the
issue of LBO that's going to press in a couple of days will have more.

Henwood's evidence is also dated
and backward, not forward looking.

Kind of hard to make a historical argument without looking backwards, isn't it?

For example, his quote from the
1991 Summers statement asks whether the telecommunications
revolution has really had a major impact? But we are in the midst
of a telecom revolution that is advancing rapidly (and has gained
further strength from the recent WTO deal getting scores of
countries to agree to privatize).

Oh, you mean the revolution in production has happened since 1991? Gosh,
time moves so fast these days!

Furthermore, even if
manufacturing hasn't been "fundamentally altered" (whatever that
means), cross-border integration of production keeps growing in
importance. And while sellers have always tried to "locate
production at the lowest cost location," you would think a leftist
would recognize that the increased mobility of capital, greater
power of IMF and World Bank, and new agreements protecting
investment rights, are widening options for sellers and that a
"reserve army" that runs from China to Russia to Indonesia to
Mexico (etc.) represents something a bit different and worth
noting.

Ed Herman subscribes to LBO, and I think he even reads it. So if he's been
reading my articles on this issue, he must know that I've been using BEA
figures on multinationals to show that the "cross-border integration of
production" hasn't progressed anywhere near as far as he claims. As I've
said almost every time I've made this point, you can challenge the figures
as inaccurate, but you'll have to do better than just make an
Aronowitz-style argument by assertion.

3. Henwood says that globalization "is often held up as the reason
things can't get any better." But if it is an important fact, we
can't deny its reality because it is used is some particular way.
Furthermore, why do a Larry Summers and the conservative Martin
Wolf go along with Henwood in denying a powerful negative effect of
globalization?

Here we go again, discrediting arguments by political association. If I
wanted to I could say, well here we have a Wharton professor who wrote a
book commissioned by the Twentieth Century Fund. Ooh can't trust him,
must be bourgeois!

Speaking of associations, I wonder if Herman has talked over globalization
with his sometime collaborator, Noam Chomsky. Chomsky holds a position
rather similar to mine, I think. In fact, here's what he wrote to me after
reading my ITT piece:

"I quite agree that the tales about "globalization" are mostly
devised to make people feel powerless, and have been trying to
make that point for a while.  And by now there is plenty in
print in highly respectable technical literature (e.g., Ruigrok
and von Tulder) to make it pretty clear that the story is mostly
a crock, and that by gross measures, at least, it's pretty much a
return to early in the 

[PEN-L:9778] Re: Barbara Ehrenreich on War

1997-05-01 Thread Louis Proyect

Wojtek Sokolowski:


There is another question, however, how these institutions are being
established and maintained.  Louis  suggests that they are being simply
imposed by the ruling class  -- but such a view simply does not hold water.
A more useful view is that while social institutions do serve the interests
of the elite, they also serve, in various ways (that may or may not
correspond with the interests of the elites), various interests and needs of
the ruled.  In other words, the ruled collaborate, willingly and
unadvertently, with the elites in the creation and maintenance of social
institutions.


I guess I was bending the stick in my comments on Ehrenreich. There is
plenty of evidence of the ruling class ruling by means of the carrot rather
than the stick. One great cultural studies expert who went by the name of
Malcolm X (not affiliated with the Frankfurt school) had astute
observations on the tendency of black folks to mimic white behavior through
conked hair, etc. The desire to identify with elites and ultimately the
ruling class itself is as old as class society.

It would even be fair to say that this is normal behavior. Before the
Vietnam war started, Ivy League students had no reason to join Maoist or
Trotskyist groups. The issue, however, is what people do in *abnormal*
times. Ehrenreich's ideas point to the futility of ever resisting war,
which is in itself the most abnormal of situations.

History reassures us that in times of abnormality people tend to act
normal, that is they often reach revolutionary conclusions. I wouldn't
worry too much about people today staying away from revolutionary parties.
I myself wouldn't join one unless it had at least 50,000 members. What
would be a cause for concern is if during the next prolonged imperialist
war like Vietnam, people insisted on identifying with leopards or hyenas
rather than Martin Luther King Jr. or Vladimir Lenin.

Louis Proyect






[PEN-L:9782] The election in Britain

1997-05-01 Thread D Shniad

This says it all:

The Globe and Mail  Thursday, May 1, 1997


Lead editorial:


WHY BRITAIN IS VOTING LABOUR 

On the face of it, John Major and the Conservatives should win today's 
election in Great Britain. If the economy were the measure of performance, 
his government would do well. If personality were the measure of 
performance, Mr. Major would do well. The trouble is that neither the 
economy nor personality seems decisive in how Britons are judging this 
government, which is why it is likely to lose. 

From this perspective, Mr. Major has reason to think his compatriots 
ungrateful. It recalls the fate of Winston Churchill in 1945. Mr. Churchill 
had led Briton for five tumultuous years. He had rallied the nation, retooled 
the economy, won the war. For his Herculean labours he was summarily 
returned to opposition. 

It isn't that Britons disliked Sir Winston; they simply decided that he wasn't 
up to the socio-economic challenges of the new era. As they saw it then, he 
was more suited for war than for peace (even though they brought him back 
the next time). 

Mr. Major is no Mr. Churchill, but there is some of that logic in his 
diminishing prospects. After all, it is largely because of the Conservatives 
that Britain is prosperous. With unemployment around 6 per cent, Britain's 
level is half that of France and Germany, both of which are now 
contemplating some of the measures -- budget-cutting, privatization and 
deregulation -- that Britain adopted under Margaret Thatcher and Mr. 
Major. 

Britain now draws about 40 per cent of the new investment in the European 
Union. It has fuelled the revival of London, which has again become a 
centre of design, fashion, pop music, even cuisine, recalling the spirit of a 
generation ago. 

Then there is Mr. Major himself. While his party trails badly in the polls, 
his personal popularity remains high. It is hard to dislike the man, however 
one might disagree with him. He has humility and modesty. He has pluck 
and determination, so much so that had he refused to step aside when 
challenged for the leadership two years ago, he would have spared himself 
all this anguish. 

So what is it, then, which is propelling the Labour Party to victory? If it 
isn't a stagnant economy or an unpopular prime minister, is it the appeal of 
the opposition and its leader? Here, too, the answer is probably no. Labour 
is not demonstrably different on the main issues, and Tony Blair, the prime 
minister-in-waiting, offers competence more than charisma. 

Our guess is that this election is more about ennui than anger. Britons have 
had 18 years of the Conservatives, and now they have had enough. They are 
simply bored with the Tories, tired of their divisions and scandals. They 
want something new, even if it is less a matter of substance than style. 

Labour, or "New Labour" as it shrewdly calls itself, understands that. By 
adopting the government's economic policies, and raising sufficient 
skepticism about embracing Europe, it offers wary Britons a way to vote 
Labour and elect the Conservatives. With a no-risk solution that will change 
the players but keep the policies, they are free to vote Labour without fear.  

Yes, there are differences between the parties, but they are limited. On the 
constitutional questions -- home rule for Scotland and Wales, a freedom of 
information act, the abolition of hereditary peers -- Labour is more daring. 
But this is fussing on the fringes. 

At root, what makes the Labourites attractive is that they are conservatives 
without being Conservatives. This kind of imitation is supremely flattering 
to Mr. Major, but it is unlikely to be enough to save his weary government.






[PEN-L:9767] Re: Globaloney

1997-05-01 Thread Doug Henwood

D Shniad wrote:

The growth in the speculative power of finance capital, the magnitude of
which dwarfs that of productive capital, has increased enormously over the
past 20+ years and undermined the mechanisms that were put in place
over the postwar period to prevent a recurrence of the disaster of the
speculative '20s followed by the deflationary '30s.

People say these things all the time without detailing the relations
between "speculative" and real activity - I think they assume that Keynes
was right about those links in chapter 12 of the GT, which he wasn't
really. Are you talking about pure financial speculation, the undermining
of the social safety net, the undermining of the financial safety net
(which happened in the 1980s, but I have my doubts about how weak it is in
the 1990s), the leveraging up of balance sheets (true of U.S. households in
the 1990s, but not of U.S. corporations, which have reduced debt since the
1980s), capital flight punishing any left-of-center government, or what?


Doug

--

Doug Henwood
Left Business Observer
250 W 85 St
New York NY 10024-3217 USA
+1-212-874-4020 voice  +1-212-874-3137 fax
email: mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
web: http://www.panix.com/~dhenwood/LBO_home.html







[PEN-L:9769] Re: IB Systems (was Globaloney)

1997-05-01 Thread Louis N Proyect

On Wed, 30 Apr 1997, Tavis Barr wrote:

 
 What amazes me is this: The system that I put together probably cut the 
 non-production workforce (people with the fairly mundane jobs of keeping 
 track of inventory and filling out and keeping track of purchase orders 
 and payments on bills) by a factor of three or four (no layoffs 
 necessary since it was a growing company though I'm sure I would have 
 been a hatchet boy in another situation).  This seems the natural 
 effect of any IB system. And yet it's the non-production workforce in 
 manufacturing that's been growing and the production  workforce that's 
 been shrinking.  Any thoughts?  Is it that most businesses simply haven't 
 implemented IB systems (I have this impression, or at least the 
 impression that they're not as fully implemented as they could be)?  Or 
 is there a really exploding ratio of non-production work that's simply 
 been tamed by the computer revolution?
 

Isn't it possible that the growth of a "non-production workforce" in
manufacturing simply reflects the transition from some of these companies
out of manufacturing into finance? Isn't the purpose of US Steel to
enhance the share value of its equity rather than make steel?

Louis Proyect






[PEN-L:9783] game theory torture

1997-05-01 Thread James Devine

(apologies ahead of time for this: I also walked out of the Mel Gibson
flick "Ransom" thinking about game theory.)

The L.A. TIMES today (May 1, 1997) published exerpts from the CIA manual on
how to torture prisoners (used at the notorious US Army School of the
Americas). This book should not be rejected out of hand, and instead should
be treated as serious social science, despite its moral depravity (and its
violation of current rules about experiments with human subjects): it
represents the thinking of bright people dealing with serious questions,
based on empirical evidence; it was a secret document and thus shows little
need to cover up what's being recommended with euphemisms.[*] It seems a
compendium of age-old wisdom about torture, used by the "torture
professionals" (the CIA, etc.) to enlighten the "torture amateurs" (a large
number of Latin American military officers) on how to torture efficiently
(e.g., holding actual physical torture in reserve rather than revealing
one's cards right away). In addition to being disgusting, it sheds a lot of
light on the standard textbook presentation of the "prisoners' dilemma" in
economics, or rather on the key assumption usually made in PD discussions,
i.e., that people are atomistic individuals with absolutely no
psychological depth. 

The CIA's prescriptions, in sum, are to mess with the prisoners' minds
(and, if need be, their bodies) in order to _create_ the textbook
prisoners' dilemma, to encourage each prisoner to "defect," to turn in his
or her comrades. The textbook treatment _assumes_ that the prisoners are
already atomistic individuals and there is _no need_ to plumb the depths of
their psyches in order to make them that way. In fact, the vast majority of
economists reject the need to study the depths of psychology at all;
instead, they simply assume that people "maximize utility," having no sense
of honor or morality, solidarity or self-esteem. It treats the fact that
many if not most prisoners do not defect as a "paradox" rather than as
showing up the severe limitations of the theory.

The CIA manual suggests that we reject the standard economics attitude
toward people. Further, if the prisoners' dilemma is something that has to
be _actively created_ by the captors (doing more than simply separating the
prisoners, preventing them from communcating) that the a priori presumption
in PD games should be that people do not "defect." 

Of course, just as with the experiments done at death camps by the Nazi
doctors, the validity of the CIA wisdom should not be tested via
replication. But I bet that experimental economics has already been done
for more moderate cases, showing the limits of the textbook presentation.
Of course, the power of ideology is such that such research does not show
up in the textbooks, where it would have the most influence. 

Happy May Day, International Workers' Day!

[*] Because of the way e-mail strips nuance from our prose, I must stress
that I do not admire the "bright" CIA social scientists. Rather, this shows
one of the big problems with social science. But maybe some of them will
turn out to be Daniel Ellsbergs. 




in pen-l solidarity,

Jim Devine   [EMAIL PROTECTED]
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
Econ. Dept., Loyola Marymount Univ.
7900 Loyola Blvd., Los Angeles, CA 90045-8410 USA
310/338-2948 (daytime, during workweek); FAX: 310/338-1950
"It takes a busload of faith to get by." -- Lou Reed.






[PEN-L:9788] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread blairs

[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

Several people on PEN-L were at the conference and will undoubtedly offer
different perspectives, but the bottom line is that a bunch of orthodox
marxists were upset that suggestions from speakers were not the same as the
answers offered by orthodox marxists. Because we know that orthodox marxism
has all the answers. oh well.

Now Blair, I knew you were a partisan, but I thought you were a fair guy.

Doug, I think it's fair to say my opinion and indicate clearly that it *is*
my opinion, that others will have other opinions. I was hoping you'd be one
of them; Louis Proyect was also there. I've read a number of pieces by
Nanda Meera and I stand by my opinion.

Personally, I agree about the Shiva/Harding panel, also that Balibar talked
too long (though I wouldn't say "gassed"). The dissenters impressed me
about as much as Shiva and Harding, which is to say, not at all.

Blair



_

Blair Sandler   "If I had to choose a reductionist paradigm,
[EMAIL PROTECTED]  Classical Marxism is a damned good one."
_







[PEN-L:9789] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread blairs

Louis, there was nothing "snide" or "patronizing" about my private message
to you. I don't play games. When I like what people are doing I say so;
when I don't like it, I say so. Pretty straightforward, I think.

It's absurd to say I'm "dissembling" about my connections to RM (I had
nothing to do with the conference directly, though). PEN-L has had several
long series of discussions about modernist and postmodernist Marxism in
which I participated actively and openly as a post-modernist Marxist and
member of the RM editorial board. Yup. I'm counting on everyone having
forgotten those discussions from, what several months ago? Damn, guess it
didn't work with you, Louis, and now you've exposed me.

I don't understand your reference to "postmodernist/Althusserian/green
regionalism trip": how does "green regionalism" fit in there?

Blair

Yeah, this question of personal insults rings a bell with me. Blair sent me
some snide private mail shortly after I showed up on PEN-L giving me a
patronizing pat on the back for my AM posts, but slapping my wrist for
"boorish" behavior at the Amherst Conference. During the discussion period
following the first plenary with the ineffable Vandana Shiva, I charged
Richard Wolff with running an exclusionary panel and that in the future
such bullshit should not be allowed.

By the way, isn't it important for Blair to identify himself as a member of
the collective that sponsored the Conference? This is highly scandalous
when people hide such information. Where's Jerry Levy when you need him?
Jerry, it's time for a crusade against Blair Sandler's dissembling before
the august body of PEN-L. The nerve of Blair to hide his connections. Oh,
perfidy.

The problem with the Amherst school is that it has placed all of its eggs
in a rotting basket. This whole postmodernist/Althusserian/green
regionalism trip is getting very dated. We got a visitation from a group of
Teresa Morton's acolytes over on the Spoons Marxism list loaded for bear.
They were going to slay all postmodernists, including *Doug Henwood and
Ellen Meiksins Wood*. Yes, it does sound weird, but these are weird people.
A witty comrade from Portugal commented that postmodernism is dead as a
doornail and not worth the trouble of killing twice. He suggested that
Marxism's main opponent are the old-fashioned ones of pragmatism and idealism.

I think there's something to be said for that. It's getting harder and
harder to simply make the usual allegations against "orthodox" Marxism.
(Actually, classical Marxism is a much more descriptive term and is
embraced by the new journal "Historical Materialism" that just got founded
over in Great Britain.) The reason for this is that the objective
circumstances that led to the pomo doctrine have largely disappeared. 1997
looks a lot different than pre-crash 1987 when characters like Baudrillard
had the ability to captivate the thinking of humanities professors in America.

Louis Proyect




_

Blair Sandler   "If I had to choose a reductionist paradigm,
[EMAIL PROTECTED]  Classical Marxism is a damned good one."
_







[PEN-L:9791] Re: Barbara Ehrenreich on War

1997-05-01 Thread Robert Saute, CUNY Grad Center

No, tell me Paul, what does it "say about the state of DSA's understanding
of class, etc. etc.!"?

In the best leninist tradition and always eager to receive knowledge from
on high, I remain,

Robert Saute

On Wed, 30 Apr 1997, Louis Proyect wrote:

 is this true! what does it say about the state of DSA's understanding
 of class, etc. etc.!
 -paul
 Original message
 I guess I have gotten used to how bad the Nation magazine has become, but
 every once in a while I run into something so rancid that I have to pause
 and catch my breath. This was the case with a review by DSA leader Barbara
 Ehrenreich of 3 books on war. This review was accompanied by a review by
 Susan Faludi of Ehrenreich’s new book on war titled "Blood Rites". All this
 prose is dedicated to the proposition that large-scale killing has been
 around as long as homo sapiens has been around and that it has nothing much
 to do with economic motives. Looking for an explanation why George Bush
 made war on Iraq? It wasn’t over oil, "democratic socialist" Ehrenreich
 would argue. It was instead related to the fact that we were once "preyed
 upon by animals that were initially far more skillful hunters than
 ourselves. In particular, the sacralization of war is not the project of a
 self-confident predator...but that of a creature which has learned only
 ‘recently,’ in the last thousand or so generations, not to cower at every
 sound in the night."
 
 In a rather silly exercise in cultural criticism, Ehrenreich speculates
 that the popularity of those nature shows depicting one animal attacking
 and eating another are proof of the predatory disposition we brutish human
 beings share. I myself have a different interpretation for what its worth.
 I believe that PBS sponsors all this stuff because of the rampant oil
 company sponsorship that transmits coded Social Darwinist ideology. Just as
 the Leopard is meant to eat the antelope, so is Shell Oil meant to kill
 Nigerians who stand in the way of progress.
 
 One of the books that Ehrenreich reviews is "War Before Civilization: The
 Myth of the Peaceful Savage" by Lawrence Keeley. Keeley argues that
 material scarcity does not explain warfare among Stone Age people. It is
 instead something in our "shared psychology" that attracts us to war.
 Keeley finds brutish behavior everywhere and at all times, including among
 the American Indian. If the number of casualties produced by wars among the
 Plains Indians was proportional to the population of European nations
 during the World Wars, then the casualty rates would have been more like 2
 billion rather than the tens of millions that obtained. Ehrenreich swoons
 over Keeley’s book that was published in 1996 to what seems like
 "insufficient acclaim".
 
 I suspect that Keeley’s book functions ideologically like some of the
 recent scholarship that attempts to show that Incas, Aztecs and Spaniards
 were all equally bad. They all had kingdoms. They all had slaves. They all
 despoiled the environment. Ad nauseum. It is always a specious practice to
 project into precapitalist societies the sort of dynamic that occurs under
 capitalism. For one thing, it is almost impossible to understand these
 societies without violating some sort of Heisenberg law of anthropology.
 The historiography of the North American and Latin American Indian
 societies is mediated by the interaction of the invading society with the
 invaded. The "view" is rarely impartial. Capitalism began to influence and
 overturn precapitalist class relations hundreds of years ago, so a
 laboratory presentation of what Aztec society looked like prior to the
 Conquistadores is impossible. Furthermore, it is regrettable that
 Ehrenreich herself is seduced by this methodology since she doesn’t even
 question Keeley’s claims about the Plains Indian wars. When did these wars
 occur? Obviously long after the railroads and buffalo hunters had become a
 fact of North American life.
 
 The reason all this stuff seems so poisonous is that it makes a political
 statement that war can not be eliminated through the introduction of
 socialism or political action. For Ehrenreich, opposing war is a
 psychological project rather than a political project:
 
 "Any anti-war movement that targets only the human agents of war -- a
 warrior elite or, on our own time, the chieftains of the
 ‘military-industrial complex’ – risks mimicking those it seeks to overcome
 .. So it is a giant step from hating the warriors to hating the war, and
 an even greater step to deciding that the ‘enemy’ is the abstract
 institution of war, which maintains its grip on us even in the interludes
 we know as peace."
 
 Really? The abstract institution of war maintains its grip on "us"? Who
 exactly is this "us"? Is it the average working person who struggles to
 make ends meet? Do they sit at home at night like great cats fantasizing
 about biting the throats out of Rwandans or 

[PEN-L:9792] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread Gerald Levy

By the way, isn't it important for Blair to identify himself as a member of
the collective that sponsored the Conference? This is highly scandalous
when people hide such information. Where's Jerry Levy when you need him?
Jerry, it's time for a crusade against Blair Sandler's dissembling before
the august body of PEN-L. The nerve of Blair to hide his connections. Oh,
perfidy.

Thank you for asking and bringing up that subject again, Louis. 

I know of no scandal that Blair Sandler is involved with. Certainly,
nothing he has done is so scandalous as when a Marxist journal in Germany
published a review of the RM conference by a person who months beforehand
-- before he had even seen a full copy of the schedule! -- trashed that
conference in public and in writing. 

Jerry 






[PEN-L:9793] Re: IB Systems (was Globaloney)

1997-05-01 Thread Tavis Barr



On Thu, 1 May 1997, Louis N Proyect wrote:


 Isn't it possible that the growth of a "non-production workforce" in
 manufacturing simply reflects the transition from some of these companies
 out of manufacturing into finance? Isn't the purpose of US Steel to
 enhance the share value of its equity rather than make steel?

That's one I hadn't thought of.  I don't know enough details to judge it, 
but on the face of it it seems unlikely.  Transferring into finance 
doesn't so much mean that firms transfer out of manufacturing.  After 
all, the best way to maximize share values is to produce good steel cheap.  
What's really happened is that these firms place their new investments in 
diverse portfolios, which can be taken care of by a handful of portfolio 
managers, instead of, say, steel.  The rising ratio of production workers 
comes from technological change, which produces more and more output with 
fewer and fewer production workers, but there hasn't been a similar trend 
in non-production work.

It was Braverman's theory that as production becomes more coordinated and 
deskilled, fewer workers are required on the shop floor and more workers 
are required to manage control processes.  But it's exactly these types 
of control processes (inventory, quality, orders, auditing) that the 
computer is supposed to be automating.  It seems like there's a missing 
piece of the puzzle somewhere.


Befuddled,
Tavis






[PEN-L:9794] Re: Cyber Picket Line (fwd)

1997-05-01 Thread Michael Eisenscher

On May Day no less, we are advised that it is no longer "Workers of the
World Unite!..." but rather "Workers of the World---log on!"

If that isn't postmodernism, what is?  Let's all reach out and digitize
someone.  (:-)  Can this Cyber Picket Line intercept cyber capital flows?
Are we ready for the virtual general strike?


At 10:56 AM 5/1/97 -0700, D Shniad wrote:
 From: STEPHEN DAVIES [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 To: Unions1 [EMAIL PROTECTED], Unions1 [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Date: Thu, 1 May 1997 15:44:50 GMT
 Subject: Cyber Picket Line
 
 NET NEWS RELEASE
 
 International Workers Day, 1 May 1997
 
 UNION FLYING PICKETS HEAD INTO CYBERSPACE
 
 1997's May Day is not only marked by the British General Election but
 also by the launch of the Cyber Picket Line - the world's biggest
 internet directory of trade union websites. Its address is:
 
  http://www.cf.ac.uk/ccin/union/
 
 With links to over 1000 trade union and trade union-related sites, the
 Cyber Picket Line shows the massive strides that the labour movement
 has taken in high tech communications over the last few years.
 
 The small group of pioneers who began it all a decade or more ago -
 primarily in Europe and North America - have now been joined by union
 internationals, national union centres, individual unions and hundreds
 of local union branches all over the world.
 
 The Cyber Picket Line features union sites from every continent in the
 world ranging from South African miners to Brazilian dockers; from
 council shop stewards in Sheffield to journalists in Hong Kong; from
 Croatian railworkers to Canadian loggers. 
 
 The effects are already being felt as workers build new links across
 continents and oceans. The Liverpool Dockers campaign, the Korean
 trade unionists battle against repressive laws and the US Firestone
 workers have all used the internet and the world wide web to organise
 solidarity action and to build support.
 
 Steve Davies, the co-ordinator of the new web site said:
 
 "For too long unions all over the world have been on the ropes. Now
 we're on the Net and its already beginning to pay off. It's now
 possible for workers to communicate effectively with each other as
 never before. 
 
 "It is also possible for rank and file stewards and branch activists
 to have access to the sort of information resource and research
 capacity that was previously only available to senior full time
 officers. It is potentially one of the most powerful and democratic
 weapons at the disposal of the labour movement.
 
 "I hope that this site helps local branches all over the world take
 advantage of the resources that exist, make the contacts that count,
 and use 21st century techniques  to rebuild international solidarity."
 
 
 ENDS
 
 NOTES FOR EDITORS
 
 The site co-ordinator is Steve Davies. He lives in Cardiff, and works
 at the University of Wales Cardiff in adult education where he's been
 since the beginning of 1996. Before that he spent 11 years working at
 the London headquarters of a British Civil Service union (now called
 PTC). He started as a research officer, later specialising in
 privatisation and contracting out, before becoming national press
 officer and Assistant to the General Secretary.
 
 A Spanish version of the site is under construction (translation being
 done by Companero David Jones of Pontypridd and Zaragoza). Eventually
 the site may appear in several other languages. All the tricky techie
 work for this site was done by Sioned Rogers of CapitalNet, the server
 for Cardiff, who have also provided the webspace.
 
 








[PEN-L:9781] Cyber Picket Line (fwd)

1997-05-01 Thread D Shniad

 From: STEPHEN DAVIES [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 To: Unions1 [EMAIL PROTECTED], Unions1 [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Date: Thu, 1 May 1997 15:44:50 GMT
 Subject: Cyber Picket Line
 
 NET NEWS RELEASE
 
 International Workers Day, 1 May 1997
 
 UNION FLYING PICKETS HEAD INTO CYBERSPACE
 
 1997's May Day is not only marked by the British General Election but
 also by the launch of the Cyber Picket Line - the world's biggest
 internet directory of trade union websites. Its address is:
 
  http://www.cf.ac.uk/ccin/union/
 
 With links to over 1000 trade union and trade union-related sites, the
 Cyber Picket Line shows the massive strides that the labour movement
 has taken in high tech communications over the last few years.
 
 The small group of pioneers who began it all a decade or more ago -
 primarily in Europe and North America - have now been joined by union
 internationals, national union centres, individual unions and hundreds
 of local union branches all over the world.
 
 The Cyber Picket Line features union sites from every continent in the
 world ranging from South African miners to Brazilian dockers; from
 council shop stewards in Sheffield to journalists in Hong Kong; from
 Croatian railworkers to Canadian loggers. 
 
 The effects are already being felt as workers build new links across
 continents and oceans. The Liverpool Dockers campaign, the Korean
 trade unionists battle against repressive laws and the US Firestone
 workers have all used the internet and the world wide web to organise
 solidarity action and to build support.
 
 Steve Davies, the co-ordinator of the new web site said:
 
 "For too long unions all over the world have been on the ropes. Now
 we're on the Net and its already beginning to pay off. It's now
 possible for workers to communicate effectively with each other as
 never before. 
 
 "It is also possible for rank and file stewards and branch activists
 to have access to the sort of information resource and research
 capacity that was previously only available to senior full time
 officers. It is potentially one of the most powerful and democratic
 weapons at the disposal of the labour movement.
 
 "I hope that this site helps local branches all over the world take
 advantage of the resources that exist, make the contacts that count,
 and use 21st century techniques  to rebuild international solidarity."
 
 
 ENDS
 
 NOTES FOR EDITORS
 
 The site co-ordinator is Steve Davies. He lives in Cardiff, and works
 at the University of Wales Cardiff in adult education where he's been
 since the beginning of 1996. Before that he spent 11 years working at
 the London headquarters of a British Civil Service union (now called
 PTC). He started as a research officer, later specialising in
 privatisation and contracting out, before becoming national press
 officer and Assistant to the General Secretary.
 
 A Spanish version of the site is under construction (translation being
 done by Companero David Jones of Pontypridd and Zaragoza). Eventually
 the site may appear in several other languages. All the tricky techie
 work for this site was done by Sioned Rogers of CapitalNet, the server
 for Cardiff, who have also provided the webspace.
 
 






[PEN-L:9766] Re: Walras vs. Sraffa

1997-05-01 Thread Ajit Sinha

My response to Gil continues...


Gil continues:
Ajit continues:

So what does this mean? It means that the two
theoretical worlds are wide appart. The GE framework does not get away from
what Sraffa called a "one way avenue", ie. a linear theoretical structure
which goes from 'factors of production' to consumer goods production.

For reasons given above, this distinction is necessarily specious.
___
Ajit:

Where is the reason given above? As I have explained above, this is a
fundamental methodological difference between the two theories.
_
Gil:

Consumption is the final *goal* of the theory. So the theory is ahistorical
through and through. It is a solution to a problem generated by axiomatic
*nature* of man. The Sraffian theoretical framework is circular. It is
interested in the question of *reproduction*-- consumption is simply a
moment in the reproduction of the system.

Ajit's anthropomorphic wording, which suggests the bizarre notion that
theories, i.e. formal analytical structures, can somehow *themselves* have
"goals" and "interests" (as if my copy of _Production of Commodities by
Means of Commodities_ could express an "interest" in going out to lunch),
effectively illustrates my point that the differences he cites between the
two systems have mostly to do with the "goals" and "interests" of their
respective adherents, not with the systems themselves.  

It is nonsense to suggest that consumption is the "goal" of the Walrasian
framework,  since this suggests that "theories" can have thoughts and
feelings.  But even if they could, consumption is no more or less the "goal"
of the Walrasian framework itself than it is for the Sraffian.  It is true
in both cases that production takes place, and that production is necessary
for consumption.  It is true in both cases that if people did not consume,
production would be unnecessary.
___-
Ajit:

That's very smart of you Gil, and my hat's off to you for that! Any reader
with minimum sympathey would understand what I'm saying there; which is that
the GE theoretical paradigm is rooted in human subjectivity. The purpose of
production is considered to be consumption, and not accumulation. This is a
theoretical, and not just an ideological, difference between the two
theories. People produce in order to consume and people consume in order to
produce are not the same thing. As Marx said, accumulation for accumulation
sake; production for production sake is the reason behind capitalist
production. M-C-M' is necessarily a circular circuit. And this is what is
reflected in the title of Sraffa's book, 'Production of Commodities by means
of Commodities'.
_ 
Gil:

 Thus it is historical through and
through, since it does not allow the framework to be draged into a mythical
origin or the begining.

Again, there is nothing about the formal Sraffian framework *itself* which
is any more or less "historical" than the Walrasian system, with the
important difference that since the Sraffian framework ignores the operation
of time in market exchange (by Ajit's own advertisement), it ignores this
particular slice of "history."  And again, in no relevant sense does the
Walrasian system deal in "mythic origins".
___
Ajit:

What is this "formal Sraffian framework *itself*", which no Sraffian has
ever heard off? There is no such thing. In the very Preface of PCMC Sraffa
says: "The investigation is concerned exclusively with such properties of an
economic system as do not depend on changes in the scale of production or in
the proportions of 'factors'. This standpoint, which is that of the old
classical economists from Adam Smith to Ricardo, has been submerged and
forgotten since the advent of the 'marginal' method." Sraffa's reading of
classical theory suggested to him that classical theory divided itself into
three parts: a theory of distribution, a theory of value or prices, and a
theory of accumulation. He believed in Ricardo's dictum that the subject
matter of economics is so complex that it does not lend itself to a long
chain of deductive reasoning. Only short chains of deductive reasoning could
be applied. Thus the connections between the three departments of the theory
cannot be established by some functional relations of quantitative nature.
Their relationships are qualitative and overdetermined in nature, to use an
Althusserian term.

Sraffa's price system was designed to establish the classical theory of
prices, which was independent of human subjectivity, and dependent on
distribution determined in a socio-historical context. This price theory
also proved that the neoclassical theory based on long chain of deductive
reasoning was flawed. So your talk of a "formal Sraffian model" is simple
nonsense.
__
Gil:

 Now, my question is this: Gil, do you think that a
skilled man can always turn a straight line into a circle?

Ah, a riddle.  I can do no better than respond with riddles of equal meaning
and relevance 

[PEN-L:9770] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread Doug Henwood

[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

Several people on PEN-L were at the conference and will undoubtedly offer
different perspectives, but the bottom line is that a bunch of orthodox
marxists were upset that suggestions from speakers were not the same as the
answers offered by orthodox marxists. Because we know that orthodox marxism
has all the answers. oh well.

Now Blair, I knew you were a partisan, but I thought you were a fair guy.

First of all, the most prominent "orthodox Marxist" dissenters were not
quite the dinosaurs your use of that epithet implies - the most prominent
was a young Indian woman who's a grad student in English at Cornell, who,
among other things, argues that the picutre painted of "orthodox Marxists"
by pomos is highly inaccurate. She cites, for example, vigorous debates
within Indian Marxism about issues like nationality and gender of just the
sort that pomos flatter themselves into thinking they originated.

And second, there was a great deal of discontent about the makeup of the
plenary panels, which were *all* - to replicate this binary that we're all
playing with even though we're all too sophisticated to fall prey to such
devious dyads - partisan pomos. A panel inspired by Alan Sokal consisting
of Vandana Shiva and Sandra Harding isn't likely to offer any real exchange
of views, is it? Especially when you have Harding, who seems from what I've
read and heard of her to be a bit of a fool, flickering her fingers
ceilingward to evoke the "hole in the atmosphere, up there, you know." Or
Judith Butler, who is certainly no fool, denouncing "neoconservative
Marxists" in a mode of pure caricature. Or Roger Burbach slamming me,
without offering any evidence or argument in his support.

There was also a lot of discontent that Etienne Balibar, who was supposed
to be having an exchange on race with Cornel West, gassed on for about 90
minutes with no exchange in sight.

The one-sided makeup of the plenaries was proof, I think, that
postmodernism has hardened into the kind of, dare I say it, hegemonic
orthodoxy that it fancies itself a critique of. Fortunately, there were
enough dissenters in the audience and on the smaller panels to make the
conference an interesting one. Too bad the plenary organizers took any
criticism of their work as personal insults.


Doug

--

Doug Henwood
Left Business Observer
250 W 85 St
New York NY 10024-3217 USA
+1-212-874-4020 voice  +1-212-874-3137 fax
email: mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
web: http://www.panix.com/~dhenwood/LBO_home.html







[PEN-L:9797] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread blairs

What a romantic account!

I don't think anybody in their right mind came to the Amherst conference
looking for an activist focus. The conferences have been around long enough
for people to know what's up. Back in the late 1980s a friend of mine who
was active in Sister Cities Projects and who worked as a nurse went up to
the conference (it might have been the first) and returned with the
observation that she did not understand a single word that anybody was
saying. Pretty soon the word got out. Activists stayed home.

So as this filtering process started to take place, the people who did make
the trek *understood* what the conference was about. It was an academic
conference not that much different from MLA conferences, etc. This
conference was a gathering of the post-Marxist tribe. Every graduate
student in America who was into  Althusser, Zizek, Bourdieu, etc. would
have to consider putting money aside for hotel and transportation costs.
Later in hotel rooms people would drink Jack Daniels from the bottle and
gossip about goings-on in the groves of academe.

What happened in December 1996 was unexpected. A whole number of people,
possibly a majority of the conference attendees, came with a theoretical
approach to Marxism that was much more in line with what I call classical
Marxism. People like Ellen Meiksins Wood, John Bellamy Foster, Doug Henwood
and Meera Nanda have been carving out a space for this current for a few
years now. When graduate students and louts like me came up to the
conference with an identification with this current, we clashed with the
post-Marxists. The clash could have been avoided if the organizers had the
good sense to not have such lopsided plenaries. That they lacked such good
sense reminds me of the public relations failure of Social Text after the
Sokal Affair. It became tempting for Andrew Ross et al to label Sokal as an
enemy of multiculturalism rather than to engage with his ideas. Likewise,
it became easier for the Amherst conference organizers to view the
disruptions from the floor as evidence of intolerant behavior on the part
of others rather than their own exclusionary practices.

Louis Proyect






Blair Sandler
[EMAIL PROTECTED]







[PEN-L:9796] US Steel and Finance Capital

1997-05-01 Thread Michael Perelman

Tavis and others brought up the case of U.S. Steel.

Many of the great industrial organizations were built by industrialists,
whose main interest was industry.  Carnegie was a sharper, but he was
still very interested in making steel at the lowest possible cost.  Over
time, many of these became more financially oriented, erasing the
distinction between finance and industrial capital.  Today U.S. Steel is
USX, you can guess what the x stands for.

Here is a short section from my End of Economics book dealing with the
transformation of U.S. Steel.

In the midst of the Great Depression, the editors of "Fortune• magazine
reported:
##Now there are two possible ways to look at a steel plant or an ore
mine.  One is as an investment that must be protected.  The other is as
an instrument of production, to be cherished only so long as it cannot
be replaced by a more efficient instrument.  The first may be called the
banker's point of view; the second, the industrialist's.  [Anon. 1936,
p. 170]
According to the investigators at Fortune, United States Steel "has
always been a management with a financial rather than an industrial turn
of mind" (Anon., p. 63).  This perspective reflected the origins of the
corporation.  "The Steel Corporation was founded by financiers, has been
dominated ever since by financially-minded men" (ibid., p. 170).
While many industries used the expansive conditions of the 1920s to
develop improved technologies, the management of United States Steel
chose a different track.  As a result:
##the chief energies of the men who guided the Corporation were directed
to preventing deterioration in the investment value of the enormous
properties confided to their care.  To achieve this, they consistently
tried to freeze the steel at present, or better yet, past levels  
Any radical change in steel technology would render worthless millions
of dollars of the Corporation's plant investment.  [ibid., pp. 170 and
173]
While firms in less concentrated industries attempted to rationalize
their operations and prune costs, the financially-oriented management of
United States Steel was intent on maintaining the status quo.  Perhaps
Hoover, the engineer, realized that protecting the corporate sector from
competitive forces would allow more firms to emulate United States
Steel, making an economic disaster inevitable.
Even the Great Depression was insufficient to make this firm change its
ways.  Over time, the firm's stodgy, hidebound management found itself
humbled both by foreign competition and aggressive mini-mills. 
Management changed the corporate name to USX and considered retreating
from the steel altogether.  Perhaps, United States Steel represented the
ultimate verdict on Morgan and the corporatists.

-- 
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929
 
Tel. 916-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]





[PEN-L:9784] Re: Globaloney

1997-05-01 Thread Doug Henwood

D Shniad wrote:

What follows is a response to Doug's call to specify a bit more what we're
talking about when we compare the relative magnitude of financial
speculation to that of trade and other economic activity.  (Caveat: I don't
work with or have access to trade stats; what follows is the seat-of-the-
pants calculation that I've done based on readings about speculation, etc. I
invite those with access to the stats to respond.)

The IMF estimates that foreign exchange transactions are more than $1
trillion daily, while trade volumes are in the $3.5 trillion ballpark
annually.

If trade volumes are 5% of the total of the world's domestic output (a
*very* conservative estimate), then the aggregate of the world's real output
would be in the neighbourhood of $70 trillion per year.

Actually, gross global product was around $25 trillion in 1994, according
to the World Bank, making trade around 14% of output.

Let's look at some export/GDP ratios for 1980 and 1994 for evidence of some
globalizing "revolution." Of course it's always possible the revolution
started after 1994; someone check with Ed Herman on this.

EXPORTS AS PERCENT OF GDP

 1980 1994
"developing" countries23%  22%
  Latin Amer/Caribb   16   15
Brazil 98
Mexico11   13
  S Africa36   24
  S Korea 34   36
Canada28   30
Japan 149
Norway47   33
Sweden29   33
UK27   25
U.S.  10   10

source: World Development Report 1996, table 13

(If trade volumes
are a somewhat larger portion of domestic production in the aggregate, then
the world's aggregate production is somewhat smaller.)  By comparison,
aggregate international financial transactions come in at more than $300
trillion per year.

By these calculations, the aggregate of international *financial*
transactions
are more than four times the dollar magnitude of *real* production.  It was
on the basis of this observation that I made the statement that speculative
activity had dwarfed the activity of productive capital.

No one disputes that there's lots of furious, pointless, even destructive
speculative activity going on. How, precisely, is it malignant, though?
Merely describing its magnitude is not to make the case.

Doug

--

Doug Henwood
Left Business Observer
250 W 85 St
New York NY 10024-3217 USA
+1-212-874-4020 voice  +1-212-874-3137 fax
email: mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
web: http://www.panix.com/~dhenwood/LBO_home.html







[PEN-L:9787] re: Environmental Economics

1997-05-01 Thread Rosser Jr, John Barkley

 Actually what I find useful and interesting about the 
Coase Theorem (not really a theorem, BTW) is that it shows 
how hard it is to have the conditions under which a free 
market will internalize externalities easily.  So, positive 
externalities between two neighboring parties, such as 
orchard owners and beekeepers, are easily negotiated, big 
whoop.  But most real world externalities involve lots of 
parties over larger areas with confused property 
situtations.  Coase says this is no go, and this appears to 
be the rule, not the exception.
Barkley Rosser
On Thu, 1 May 1997 13:14:12 -0700 (PDT) Robin Hahnel 
[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

 I second Jim Devine's message about neoclassicals and the environment in
 its entirety. The astounding misinterpretation of what the Coase theorem
 actually tells any reasonable analyst about the likelihood of environmental
 efficiency being achieved through voluntary and private negotiations of
 polluters and pollution victims is an excellent case in point. A reasonable
 reading of the theorem AND ITS INCREDIBLE LIST OF NECESSARY ASSUMPTIONS gives
 more than enough theoretical reasons for anyone who cares about the environ-
 ment to immediately embrace a government role!

-- 
Rosser Jr, John Barkley
[EMAIL PROTECTED]







[PEN-L:9790] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread Doug Henwood

Stephen Cullenberg wrote:

Yet, we are not, and never have pretended to be, as ecumenical as say URPE
and the RRPE.

This then is Rethinking? My first reaction to the conference was too much
Re, not enough thinking, but now I'm even questioning the Re.

A nonecumenical group of people who agree on fundamental things and view
plenaries as a form of preaching to a mixed crowd of converted and
unconverted? Did the presence of a large critical minority seem something
worthy of ackknowledging as something other than a personal attack? This is
exactly what I meant by the plenaries having shown signs of hardening into
orthodoxy, which as the postmodernists have taught us well, is defined
through exclusion. Is the devotion to polyvocality just another empty
signifier?


Doug

--

Doug Henwood
Left Business Observer
250 W 85 St
New York NY 10024-3217 USA
+1-212-874-4020 voice  +1-212-874-3137 fax
email: mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
web: http://www.panix.com/~dhenwood/LBO_home.html







[PEN-L:9785] re: Environmental Economics

1997-05-01 Thread Robin Hahnel

I second Jim Devine's message about neoclassicals and the environment in
its entirety. The astounding misinterpretation of what the Coase theorem
actually tells any reasonable analyst about the likelihood of environmental
efficiency being achieved through voluntary and private negotiations of
polluters and pollution victims is an excellent case in point. A reasonable
reading of the theorem AND ITS INCREDIBLE LIST OF NECESSARY ASSUMPTIONS gives
more than enough theoretical reasons for anyone who cares about the environ-
ment to immediately embrace a government role!





[PEN-L:9799] Re: US Steel and Finance Capital

1997-05-01 Thread Anthony P D'Costa

I have some queries since I am wriing a book on technology and the steel
industry (1950-1996).  See below.

Anthony P. D'Costa
Associate Professor Senior Fellow
Comparative International Development   Department of Economics
University of WashingtonNational University of Singapore
1103 A Street   10 Kent Ridge Crescent
Tacoma, WA 98402 USASingapore 119260

On Thu, 1 May 1997, Michael Perelman wrote:

 Tavis and others brought up the case of U.S. Steel.
 
 Many of the great industrial organizations were built by industrialists,
 whose main interest was industry.  Carnegie was a sharper, but he was
 still very interested in making steel at the lowest possible cost.  Over
 time, many of these became more financially oriented, erasing the
 distinction between finance and industrial capital.  Today U.S. Steel is
 USX, you can guess what the x stands for.
 
 Here is a short section from my End of Economics book dealing with the
 transformation of U.S. Steel.
 
 In the midst of the Great Depression, the editors of "Fortune• magazine
 reported:
 ##Now there are two possible ways to look at a steel plant or an ore
 mine.  One is as an investment that must be protected.  The other is as
 an instrument of production, to be cherished only so long as it cannot
 be replaced by a more efficient instrument.  The first may be called the
 banker's point of view; the second, the industrialist's.  [Anon. 1936,
 p. 170]
 According to the investigators at Fortune, United States Steel "has
 always been a management with a financial rather than an industrial turn
 of mind" (Anon., p. 63).  This perspective reflected the origins of the
 corporation.  "The Steel Corporation was founded by financiers, has been
 dominated ever since by financially-minded men" (ibid., p. 170).
 While many industries used the expansive conditions of the 1920s to
 develop improved technologies, the management of United States Steel
 chose a different track.  

Can you give me some specific examples of what technologies we are talking
about?  The basic argument is correct i.e. the attitude toward
technological change (something that happened in the 1950s, BOF versus
OHF).  But "sunk costs" are important to the direction of technological
change for a firm.

As a result:
 ##the chief energies of the men who guided the Corporation were directed
 to preventing deterioration in the investment value of the enormous
 properties confided to their care.  To achieve this, they consistently
 tried to freeze the steel at present, or better yet, past levels  
 Any radical change in steel technology would render worthless millions
 of dollars of the Corporation's plant investment.  [ibid., pp. 170 and
 173]
 While firms in less concentrated industries attempted to rationalize
 their operations and prune costs, the financially-oriented management of
 United States Steel was intent on maintaining the status quo.  Perhaps
 Hoover, the engineer, realized that protecting the corporate sector from
 competitive forces would allow more firms to emulate United States
 Steel, making an economic disaster inevitable.
 Even the Great Depression was insufficient to make this firm change its
 ways.  Over time, the firm's stodgy, hidebound management found itself
 humbled both by foreign competition and aggressive mini-mills. 
 Management changed the corporate name to USX and considered retreating
 from the steel altogether.  Perhaps, United States Steel represented the
 ultimate verdict on Morgan and the corporatists.
 
 -- 
 Michael Perelman
 Economics Department
 California State University
 Chico, CA 95929
  
 Tel. 916-898-5321
 E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 






[PEN-L:9798] Re: MAI and Foreign Control in Canada

1997-05-01 Thread Bill Burgess


Shawgi Tell noted a couple of days ago that foreign control of corporate
revenues in Canada rose by 1.3 points to 29.8% of the total in 1995, and
that this was the second largest yearly rise ever recorded. 

I don't know Shawgi's point of view on this question, but the implication
of his observation is consistant with the usual conception of Canada as a
semi-colony which is slipping further under US domination as a result of
'free' trade agreements. The **nationalist** opposition to MAI that I
questioned last week is also (partially) rooted in such approaches.

What does the data on foreign control really say about this issue? I
prefer to argue this using data on *assets* (a stock variable) rather than
*revenues* (a flow variable), since the latter is heavily influenced
by the business cycle and foreign controlled firms are concentrated in
sectors with higher revenue-to-asset ratios.   

Statistics Canada's figure for foreign control of all corporate assets
in Canada rose to 21% in 1995. This increase restored foreign control to
the 21% rate previously reached in 1990, and is only up 0.5 percentage
points since 1988 (the first year for which this data for *all*
industries is available). 

In other words there has not been much of a change. While foreign
control rose in *non-financial* sectors to 24.3%, this was partially
offset by a slight drop to 17.6% in *finance and insurance* sectors. 

Nor does the data on *US* control of *all* corporate assets indicate any great
increase attributable to the FTA or NAFTA, at least so far.  While the
11.4% US control of all corporate assets in Canada in 1995 is a
notable increase over 1994 (when it was 10.8%), it is only 0.4 points
higher than in 1988, the year before the FTA took effect. For most of this
period it has been lower than before 'free' trade. 

Perhaps most important, and  contrary to the usual assumptions, the
level of foreign control in Canada has **declined substantially** over the
last few decades. The data series on foreign control of *all* industries
only goes back to 1988, but if we assume the trend here has been
similar to that for the *non-financial* half of the corporate economy (for
which the earlier data is available), then the current range of foreign
(and US) control in Canada is lower than it has been for about half a
century! 

Foreign control of *non-financial* industries peaked in the early 1970s,
but Canadian capitalists have regained about one-third of all
non-financial assets in Canada since then, and they have retained the
decisive control they have always had over the *financial*  half of the
economy. One measure that highlights the strength of Canadian capital is
that Statistics Canada reports that in 1992 they controlled 96.5% of the
assets of the *25 largest enterprises* (corporations grouped under common
control) in Canada.

The rate of foreign control for *all* industries in Canada cited
above (and that for the largest 25 enterprises) is considerably lower
than the *non-financial* rates Canadian nationalists have
traditionally cited for their purposes. However, it is true foreign
control is higher in Canada than in most -  but not all - major OECD
countries.  Other countries do not collect data on foreign control
comparable to that cited above, but if we use OECD data on the ratio of
the stock of (inward) FDI to GDP as a basis, foreign control in
the UK (!!) and the Netherlands is **higher** than in Canada.  

Further, the level of inward FDI should be considered in tandem with that
of outward FDI. *Canadian* capitalists hold more FDI *abroad* per Canadian
than do their competitors in the US, Japan, Germany and France relative to
the latters' populations. In recent years, the flow of Canadian FDI to the
US has *exceeded* US FDI coming into Canada. 

I think this is a pretty impressive record, and to bring it back to the 
MAI issue, one that makes we wonder why we would want to offer Canadian 
capitalists national protection from their foreign competitors.  

I live in Canada so I've concentrated on the usual suggestion  that
protectionism is more appropriate here than in other imperialist
countries.  Since I'm working on a paper on this point I would appreciate
any comments and criticism on at least ***this aspect*** of the debate.
   
Bill Burgess
University of B.C.
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
home (604) 255-5957
fax c/o (604) 822-6150






[PEN-L:9786] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-01 Thread Stephen Cullenberg

Just a brief response to Jim's initial question on the Rethinking Marxism
conference.  I was one of the co-organizers of the conference, and the one
mainly responsible for the conference program, of some 190 panels.

There is no question in my mind that the conference attracts mainly
academics doing all types of critical analysis, from radical political
economy to semiotic cultural studies, and often combining them both.  There
are very few "activists" who come.  Whether that is good or bad is not
obvious to me.  It seems to me that there is no one best way to organize on
the Left these days and we all need to do what we can, in whatever ways we
can. (BTW, I know that academics are also activists and activists are also
academics - I not concerned with this finer point).

In a similar way, the conference was both open and ecumenical, while also
rather partisan (which I suppose you can pejoratively call exclusionary, as
some have).  We found space for any and everyone who wanted to present a
paper, panel, performance, art, etc., to do so.  But, yes, the plenaries
were decided on by the organizers, and really why shouldn't it be this way?
 Afterall, the conference was organized and sponsored by Rethinking Marxism
and therefore might well reflect the ideas, positions, and biases of its
editors.  RM is a journal open to a wide array of ideas concerned with
Marxism and related fields, and we have published with a wide diversity. 
Yet, we are not, and never have pretended to be, as ecumenical as say URPE
and the RRPE.  We have been a journal with a partisan, yet always shifting
set of postionings, as new ideas push and pull Marxism in various
directions.  But one thing has remained a priority, and that is the RM's
interest in developing and fostering non-essentialist forms of discourse as
related to Marxism (whether you want to call that postmodernism or not).

So, as I have heard some criticize the conference for being exclusionary (I
prefer partisan), I remain a little puzzled.  The conference was extrememly
open with regard to conference program, but what exactly did people expect
coming to a conference sponsored by Rethinking Marxism???  Afterall, that
is what we are about, and we don't disguise our intentions as others on the
Left have recently felt the need to do.  

Instead, I would like to hear discussion or criticism about the quality of
the papers (and of course many have already commented on this), or was
there a poor turnout (which of course was the opposite case), what was the
sense of interest and excitement (extremely vigorous), did people make new
connections across disciplines and internationally (many), or even did
Balibar have anything to say, even though he (unfortunately) spoke too
long, and so on.

I am sorry the conference was not exactly what some people had hoped for,
or wanted, or even at times seem to demand.  We all do what we can and make
the types of intereventions we are able to and that we feel will have some
impact, however limited that might be.  I wish that we on the Left would
demand less of each other about how things should be, or feel the need to
entrap each other in faux pas's, and show a little more graciousness and
understanding, because we are all working very hard in these inauspicious
times and no one I know has yet found the unique way to change this world
for the better. 

Steve C.

p.s.  For a full description of our conference program, post-conference
reactions from the international press, and a lot about RM, check out our
new web site:  http://www.nd.edu/~remarx/


***
Stephen Cullenberg  office:  (909) 787-5037, ext. 1573
Department of Economics fax: (909) 787-5685
University of California[EMAIL PROTECTED]
Riverside, CA 92521
http://www.ucr.edu/CHSS/depts/econ/sc.htm







[PEN-L:9795] Re: game theory torture

1997-05-01 Thread HANLY


Recently Devine writes as follows:


The CIA's prescriptions, in sum, are to mess with the prisoners' minds
(and, if need be, their bodies) in order to _create_ the textbook
prisoners' dilemma, to encourage each prisoner to "defect," to turn in his
or her comrades. The textbook treatment _assumes_ that the prisoners are
already atomistic individuals and there is _no need_ to plumb the depths of
their psyches in order to make them that way. In fact, the vast majority of
economists reject the need to study the depths of psychology at all;
instead, they simply assume that people "maximize utility," having no sense
of honor or morality, solidarity or self-esteem. It treats the fact that
many if not most prisoners do not defect as a "paradox" rather than as
showing up the severe limitations of the theory.


COMMENT: There are two competing views of the non-repeating PD. While there is
a standard argument that concludes that the dominant and rational strategy is to
defect,(the Dominance argument)
 there is a so-called symmetry argument that can be traced back at least
to Anatol Rapoport in FIGHTS GAMES AND DEBATES (1960). This argument has been
elaborated by L Davis in Prisoners, Paradox, and Rationality. AMERICAN
PHILOSOPHICAL QUARTERLY 14: 319-27.) A somewhat different argument but equally
critical of the standard argument is McClennen E. Prisoners Dilemma and
Resolute Choice. In Campbell R. and Sowden L.(eds) PARADOXES OF RATIONALITY AND
CO-operation UBC Press 1985. The basic idea behind the symmetry argument
is that each prisoner being rational and in the same situation will see that
the dominance argument leads to a sub-optimal result FOR BOTH as contrasted
with their both remaining silent. THerefore
as rational agents they will resolutely choose, to use McLennen's term, not to
defect in order to improve the result for them both. This avoids the
paradoxical result of the traditional argument in which allegedly rational
choice leads to sub-optimal outcomes for both participants.
I agree with Davis and
McLennen but not with Rapoport because Rapoport thinks that somehow altruism is
involved. ALtruism is not involved at all. The argument works even for
rational egoists who have no interest per se in the welfare of others. However,
when it is necessary to co-operate to maximize the welfare of each it is
rational to do so. I have an unpublished (but presented) paper that argues
against the dominance argument, and also Parfit's(REASONS AND PERSONS 1984)
 critique of ethical egoism
as self-defeating as shown by the PD. I think the PD shows no such thing.
I also think that Gauthier(MORALS BY AGREEMENT 1986)
 is incorrect in thinking that unconstrained
maximisers would choose defection as the rational strategy in PD contexts.
Of course many of the things discussed in the literature as PD's have nothing
to do with PD's. For example the position of polluters who have no motive to
install pollution devices in a competitive market even though this might
advance the public welfare. In these cases all polluters defecting from the
welfare producing policy does not on the whole hurt them, so there is nothing
at all paradoxical involved. One case that is like that of the PD is that
involving manufacture of aerosols without fluorocarbon propellants.
 If everyone did it, it would
cheaper for all manufacturers, and in that sense in all their interests, but
no one manufacturer will do it because they do not want to give up the market
that still exists for the earlier propellant. Manufacturers did not oppose
a ban on fluorocarbon propellants since it would provide assurance that
no firm could defect and capture a market niche.
  CHeers, Ken Hanly
  Cheers, Ken Hanly






[PEN-L:9800] Trying to keep focused

1997-05-01 Thread D Shniad

Doug,

I started my part of this exchange by saying that the magnitude of activity 
of speculative capital had dwarfed the magnitude of productive capital.  
You challenged that statement.  In your latest response to my response, you 
provide information that confirms that that magnitude of speculative to 
productive activity is much larger than I had tentatively hypothesized.  Then 
you provide data on export/GDP ratios, presumably responding to an 
argument that someone else was raising.

Then you apply the coup de grace: "No one disputes that there's lots of 
furious, pointless, even destructive speculative activity going on. How, 
precisely, is it malignant, though? Merely describing its magnitude is not to 
make the case."

Forgive me, but aren't we quibbling a bit here?  What is the analytical 
importance of the difference between the terms "destructive" and 
"malignant"?

I was making what I thought was a rather straight forward point: that this 
manic speculative activity of such a huge magnitude was a symptom of the 
fact that the power of finance capital had overtaken that of productive 
capital, thanks at least in part to the breakdown of the internation regulatory 
mechanism that was Bretton Woods.

Quick question: are we in agreement or disagreement here?

Cheers,

Sid

The IMF estimates that foreign exchange transactions are more than $1
trillion daily, while trade volumes are in the $3.5 trillion ballpark
annually.

If trade volumes are 5% of the total of the world's domestic output (a
*very* conservative estimate), then the aggregate of the world's real 
output
would be in the neighbourhood of $70 trillion per year.

Actually, gross global product was around $25 trillion in 1994, according
to the World Bank, making trade around 14% of output.

Let's look at some export/GDP ratios for 1980 and 1994 for evidence of 
some
globalizing "revolution." Of course it's always possible the revolution
started after 1994; someone check with Ed Herman on this.

EXPORTS AS PERCENT OF GDP

 1980 1994
"developing" countries23%  22%
  Latin Amer/Caribb   16   15
Brazil 98
Mexico11   13
  S Africa36   24
  S Korea 34   36
Canada28   30
Japan 149
Norway47   33
Sweden29   33
UK27   25
U.S.  10   10

source: World Development Report 1996, table 13

(If trade volumes
are a somewhat larger portion of domestic production in the aggregate, 
then
the world's aggregate production is somewhat smaller.)  By comparison,
aggregate international financial transactions come in at more than $300
trillion per year.

By these calculations, the aggregate of international *financial*
transactions
are more than four times the dollar magnitude of *real* production.  It was
on the basis of this observation that I made the statement that speculative
activity had dwarfed the activity of productive capital.

No one disputes that there's lots of furious, pointless, even destructive
speculative activity going on. How, precisely, is it malignant, though?
Merely describing its magnitude is not to make the case.

Doug





[PEN-L:9780] Re: Globaloney

1997-05-01 Thread D Shniad

What follows is a response to Doug's call to specify a bit more what we're 
talking about when we compare the relative magnitude of financial 
speculation to that of trade and other economic activity.  (Caveat: I don't 
work with or have access to trade stats; what follows is the seat-of-the-
pants calculation that I've done based on readings about speculation, etc. I 
invite those with access to the stats to respond.)

The IMF estimates that foreign exchange transactions are more than $1 
trillion daily, while trade volumes are in the $3.5 trillion ballpark annually.  

If trade volumes are 5% of the total of the world's domestic output (a 
*very* conservative estimate), then the aggregate of the world's real output 
would be in the neighbourhood of $70 trillion per year. (If trade volumes 
are a somewhat larger portion of domestic production in the aggregate, then 
the world's aggregate production is somewhat smaller.)  By comparison, 
aggregate international financial transactions come in at more than $300 
trillion per year.  

By these calculations, the aggregate of international *financial* transactions 
are more than four times the dollar magnitude of *real* production.  It was 
on the basis of this observation that I made the statement that speculative 
activity had dwarfed the activity of productive capital.

Unless there is a hole in this reasoning, it should be possible to compare 
this ratio, which is more than 4:1, with the comparable ratio in the 1920s.

Sid Shniad

PS -- None of this takes into account the magnitude of speculative activity 
that occurs *within* borders.

 
 D Shniad wrote:
 
 The growth in the speculative power of finance capital, the magnitude of
 which dwarfs that of productive capital, has increased enormously over the
 past 20+ years and undermined the mechanisms that were put in place
 over the postwar period to prevent a recurrence of the disaster of the
 speculative '20s followed by the deflationary '30s.
 
 People say these things all the time without detailing the relations
 between "speculative" and real activity - I think they assume that Keynes
 was right about those links in chapter 12 of the GT, which he wasn't
 really. Are you talking about pure financial speculation, the undermining
 of the social safety net, the undermining of the financial safety net
 (which happened in the 1980s, but I have my doubts about how weak it is in
 the 1990s), the leveraging up of balance sheets (true of U.S. households in
 the 1990s, but not of U.S. corporations, which have reduced debt since the
 1980s), capital flight punishing any left-of-center government, or what?
 
 
 Doug
 
 --
 
 Doug Henwood
 Left Business Observer
 250 W 85 St
 New York NY 10024-3217 USA
 +1-212-874-4020 voice  +1-212-874-3137 fax
 email: mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
 web: http://www.panix.com/~dhenwood/LBO_home.html
 
 
 






[PEN-L:9802] May Day

1997-05-01 Thread PHILLPS

May I wish you all an affirmative May Day (a happy May Day would be
a bit much).  There are still so many out there that are suffering
from the ravages of capitalism that they deserve our sympathy, but
more than that, our organized help.
  At the moment we are battling the ravages of nature, the flood of
the century.  But when that battle is over, let us battle the
deprivations of inequality, poverty and homelessness!
Paul Phillips,
Economics,
University of Manitoba