[PEN-L:9803] Re: Walras vs. Sraffa

1997-05-02 Thread Ajit Sinha

My response to Gil continues...

Gil:

Ajit continues:

Gil Claims:
the claim that "[i]ncomes are determined by...socio-historical
factors (including class struggle" can be expressed with equal legitimacy in
the Walrasian framework.  Reason:  in that framework, income distribution
depends ultimately and primarily on the distribution of "endowments" of
private property, which is exogenous, or to use Ajit's words, " determined
from outside the market."  So let us agree that such property endowments are
determined by "socio-historical factors (including class struggle)" (as they
surely are in real-world capitalism), and Ajit's claims about the
determination of income distribution emerge with at least equal force from
the Walrasian framework.
_

One of the axioms of Arrow-Debreu model is that agents begin with initial
endowments, and these initial endowments are large enough so that the agents
could survive even if they could be deprived of all trading opportunities.
This is an essential axiom to the GE model, explicitly or implicitly,
because if it was not the case, then the agents would be *forced* to trade,
and the whole idea of trade as a voluntary activity cannot be upheld. 

I think this criticism is fundamentally misconceived, again for a number of
reasons.  To begin with, it is not true that the Arrow-Debreu framework
includes any such axiom, and appropriately so, since the connection between
endowments and the (in)voluntary status of trade is more tenuous than Ajit
suggests.  First, an individual may not be able to survive *either* on her
endowment *or* on the market basket 

Ajit:

My guess is that Gil has not read Arrow-Deberue, all his bravado
notwithstanding. Let me quote from Arrow-Debreue's most influencial paper
'Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy', Econometrica, 1954,
#22.

"II. The set of consumption vector Xi available to individual i (= 1,,m)
is a closed convex subset of R(L) which is bounded from below, i.e., there
is a vector Ei such that Ei(=) xi for all xi belonging to Xi.

The set Xi includes all consumption vectors among which the individual could
conceivably choose if there were no budgetary restrainsts. Impossible
combinations of commodities, such as the supplying of several types of labor
to a total amount of more than 24 hours a day or THE CONSUMPTION OF A BUNDLE
OF COMMODITIES INSUFFICIENT TO MAINTAIN LIFE, ARE REGARDED AS EXCLUDED FROM
Xi." (pp. 268-69).

So what do you say Gil? Isn't it a good idea to check the references before
saying other is wrong! wrong! wrong! all the time?  This is an important
assumption, as I explained above. Without it the idea of voluntary exchange
cannot be maintain.
 
Gil:

this endowment enables her to purchase; thus the presence or absence of
"force" is beside the point in this case.  Second, "force" is unavoidably a
matter of context (context which, of course, the Sraffian framework
necessarily omits as well).  On one hand, most people will not starve even
if they fail to earn labor income for a week--even if that means they have
to steal.  On the other, someone may feel "forced" to enter the labor market
to fund certain compulsive behaviors, even if all one's physiological needs
are met.   Third, and perhaps most to the point, there is no necessary
contradiction between "utility-maximizing exchange" and "necessary
exchange"--think of the latter as "utility-maximizing with an exclamation
point"--and  it is thus a distinction without a difference as far as the
formal analysis goes.

Ajit:

Gil thinks that "stuff happens" is bad theory, but "exclamation mark" is a
good solution to a theoretical problem. Now, we can characterize laying as
standing with a note of exclamation! Note of exclamation is the hotest
formula for solving theoretical problem going folks! The point I have been
making is much too serious for a note of exclamation to solve it. Survival
is an INSTINCT which all life forms has including bacteria. Once you
incorporate the instinct to survival as "utility maximization", then the
whole concept becomes vacuous. Would you say bacterias are also "utility
maximizers"? Of course, not. Then human subjectivity must be separated from
sheer instinct for survival. And once you do that my critique comes back
with full force.
__ 
Gil: 

This is in total contradiction to capitalist reality where the proletariat
does
not have the initial endowments big enough for its survival. The so-called
exchange between the capital and labor is a *forced* exchange. Is the
Sraffian system built on such axiom too, Gil?

This is another obvious case in which Ajit claims an advantage for the
Sraffian system on the basis of what it leaves out, since the Sraffian
framework says *nothing whatsoever* one way or another as to whether "the
proletariat [has] initial endowments big enough for its survival."  Of
course, *exponents* of the system may *presume* the relevant 

[PEN-L:9805] South Korea's Revised Labor Law Condemned: Workers Determined To Stage

1997-05-02 Thread SHAWGI TELL


The National Alliance for Democracy and Reunification, in a
statement on March 9, branded the reamendment of the labor law
agreed to by the ruling and opposition parties of south Korea as
the second retrogressive revision and declared it could not
accept it.
 According to Seoul radio reports, the organization said that
the amendment in which provisions for "flexible working hours,"
"layoffs" and other "poisonous articles" are not struck out is
the result of political negotiations which ignore the opinion of
the people. The organization urged the rewriting of the labor
law on democratic lines.
 The Korean Confederation of Trade Unions contended that the
reamendment of the labor law agreed to by the ruling and
opposition parties on March 8 is barely different than that which
was railroaded at the end of last year. The Confederation
declared that it would stage a general strike in May to have the
articles which threaten the basic rights of the workers
withdrawn.
 The Federation of Korean Trade Unions visited the buildings
of the opposition National Congress for New Politics and United
Liberal Democrats on March 10 and published a statement
denouncing the current reamendment of the labor law as a product
of backroom political negotiations.
 The organization warned that it would stage the third
general strike slated for May ahead of schedule unless the
reamendment of the labor law is immediately withdrawn and the
labor law is rewritten in line with international standards.


Shawgi Tell
University at Buffalo
Graduate School of Education
[EMAIL PROTECTED]








[PEN-L:9811] Re: Trying to keep focused

1997-05-02 Thread Doug Henwood

D Shniad wrote:

Then you apply the coup de grace: "No one disputes that there's lots of
furious, pointless, even destructive speculative activity going on. How,
precisely, is it malignant, though? Merely describing its magnitude is not to
make the case."

Forgive me, but aren't we quibbling a bit here?  What is the analytical
importance of the difference between the terms "destructive" and
"malignant"?

I was making what I thought was a rather straight forward point: that this
manic speculative activity of such a huge magnitude was a symptom of the
fact that the power of finance capital had overtaken that of productive
capital, thanks at least in part to the breakdown of the internation
regulatory
mechanism that was Bretton Woods.

Quick question: are we in agreement or disagreement here?

A bit of both, I think. I agree that financial activity can be destructive,
but I don't think that case can be made simply by citing figures about
turnover. I think it has to be made a lot more carefully than that (like
with a 382-page book on Wall Street, for example). More specifically, I
think the corporate indebtedness seen in the U.S. in the 1980s drained
resources from investment, and the priorities imposed by increasingly
assertive shareholders are inimical to long-term economic growth, not to
mention human well-being. But making that point requires looking at the
social/political institutions behind financial structures - not just
looking at volume numbers.

Another complicating example: the European monetary crisis of 1992. You
could argue that the commitment to monetary union, and with it the absurd
overvaluations of the currencies of the weaker countries, was a reflection
of financial interests. Speculators eventually undid this arrangement,
allowing the British economy some room for recovery. So, here "speculation"
was an act of angels, though in heavy disguise, while the initial
arrangement was a reflection of rentier-friendly institutional structures.



Doug

--

Doug Henwood
Left Business Observer
250 W 85 St
New York NY 10024-3217 USA
+1-212-874-4020 voice  +1-212-874-3137 fax
email: mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
web: http://www.panix.com/~dhenwood/LBO_home.html







[PEN-L:9813] Re: Globaloney

1997-05-02 Thread Marshall Feldman


From: Doug Henwood [EMAIL PROTECTED]

D Shniad wrote:

What follows is a response to Doug's call to specify a bit more what we're
talking about when we compare the relative magnitude of financial
speculation to that of trade and other economic activity.  (Caveat: I don't
work with or have access to trade stats; what follows is the seat-of-the-
pants calculation that I've done based on readings about speculation, etc. I
invite those with access to the stats to respond.)

The IMF estimates that foreign exchange transactions are more than $1
trillion daily, while trade volumes are in the $3.5 trillion ballpark
annually.

If trade volumes are 5% of the total of the world's domestic output (a
*very* conservative estimate), then the aggregate of the world's real output
would be in the neighbourhood of $70 trillion per year.

Actually, gross global product was around $25 trillion in 1994, according
to the World Bank, making trade around 14% of output.

Let's look at some export/GDP ratios for 1980 and 1994 for evidence of some
globalizing "revolution." Of course it's always possible the revolution
started after 1994; someone check with Ed Herman on this.

EXPORTS AS PERCENT OF GDP

 1980 1994
"developing" countries23%  22%
  Latin Amer/Caribb   16   15
Brazil 98
Mexico11   13
  S Africa36   24
  S Korea 34   36
Canada28   30
Japan 149
Norway47   33
Sweden29   33
UK27   25
U.S.  10   10

source: World Development Report 1996, table 13

(If trade volumes
are a somewhat larger portion of domestic production in the aggregate, then
the world's aggregate production is somewhat smaller.)  By comparison,
aggregate international financial transactions come in at more than $300
trillion per year.

By these calculations, the aggregate of international *financial*
transactions
are more than four times the dollar magnitude of *real* production.  It was
on the basis of this observation that I made the statement that speculative
activity had dwarfed the activity of productive capital.

No one disputes that there's lots of furious, pointless, even destructive
speculative activity going on. How, precisely, is it malignant, though?
Merely describing its magnitude is not to make the case.

Doug

1) Maybe we have to look at the composition of trade.  My sense of the
globalization thesis is that trade in manufactured goods has globalized
while trade in raw materials has declined relatively.

2) Perhaps one should go back before 1980.  Most arguments re. globalization
allude to a transition in the SSA/MSR c. 1969.  So comparing 1960 and
1997 might be more to the point.

Marsh Feldman   Phone: 401/874-5953
Community Planning, 204 Rodman Hall   FAX: 401/874-5511
The University of Rhode Island   Internet: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Kingston, RI 02881-0815





[PEN-L:9814] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-02 Thread Doug Henwood

Antonio Callari wrote:

Doug, your reaction to
Steve, in addition to being unfair to him--for I don't think he wrote what
he did in the sectarian spirit you imputed to him--is unfair and
problematic in that it turns into an attack on the journal as a whole. And
the level of your critique is simplistic. There is both thinking and
rethinking in the journal. For you to use the example of the plenaries to
typecast the journal is simply to give free reign to the instincts you, and
orthers, to attack! attack! attack! Attack who? us? for not having had
balanced plenaries?

Well, yes. But I'm really not doing this in the spirit of attack. I'm
saying that there should be a conversation happening that's not. The
plenaries were full of attacks: by Judith Butler, on (nonexistent)
"neoconservative Marxists"; by Sandra Harding, on intellectual rigor; by
Vandana Shiva, on Rene Descartes; by Roger Burbach, on me. And Antonio, I
believe you told one of the Indian rebels that her criticisms were
"disrespecting [your] labor." If that's the case, that's not my idea of how
political intellectuals should talk to each other. Did you talk to her
about Indian Marxism and the critique of postmodernism it's led her to?

Where is the public attack on other conferences that
also do not have balanced plenaries, or even as balanced programs as the RM
conference had?

I wasn't pleased at all with the way Monthly Review held panels on
postmodernism at the Socialist Scholars Conference with no postmodernists
present. I told Ellen Wood and the rest of the MR staff that that was very
bad. I didn't do that publicly because the subject never came up, but I'll
do it now.

One of the reasons the RM conference was a success, I think, was because of
all the interesting ferment at the margins. That should appeal to a
postmodernist, no? A rebellious, counterhegemonic movement constituted by
the exclusioary practices of the conference authorities?

So: let's be kind, let's be friends, let's build together instead of
tearing each other apart. Please!

Antonio, more tearing apart is done by people sitting on unitary panels, or
writing in univocal journals, criticizing people and texts who aren't
there, and maybe don't even exist, than when these conversations, rare as
they are, happen. As I remember Butler's talk, she denounced all sorts of
bad orthodox Marxists who seem to want to send women back to the kitchen
and queers back into the closet. That's tearing apart. The same things
happen in gatherings of the "orthodox" who caricature "postmodernism" (and
I know that it's a complex and diverse assemblage that sails under this
banner) as something sillier than it really is.


Doug

--

Doug Henwood
Left Business Observer
250 W 85 St
New York NY 10024-3217 USA
+1-212-874-4020 voice  +1-212-874-3137 fax
email: mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
web: http://www.panix.com/~dhenwood/LBO_home.html







[PEN-L:9815] Re: Keeping on track

1997-05-02 Thread Doug Henwood

Michael Perelman wrote:

Whether you agree with RM, postmodernism, Leninist,
Trostskyist, or Stalinist politics is not as important as getting
something real done when, as in the U.S., Clinton and the Republicans
can sit down in a room and negotiate a budget, leaving Dick Gephart to
represent the people.  We are in a sorry fix and need to get something
done.

Michael, I appreciate your call for comradely amity, but these are serious
issues that need to be discussed. Is this "sorry fix" we're in a function,
even in part, of a bad set of theories that have led to bad political
mistakes? Since a great deal of "postmodernism" has been about the denial
of political economy - Foucault said it was a 19th century concern, since
we've been transformed from beings who labor into beings who speak -
shouldn't political economists talk about that?


Doug

--

Doug Henwood
Left Business Observer
250 W 85 St
New York NY 10024-3217 USA
+1-212-874-4020 voice  +1-212-874-3137 fax
email: mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
web: http://www.panix.com/~dhenwood/LBO_home.html







[PEN-L:9818] Re: RM conference overdetermination

1997-05-02 Thread Marshall Feldman



Jim Devine writes:

This fits with an insight that Alan Freeman suggested as one part of a
longer paper he presented at the recent ASSA/URPE conference: when Marx (or
Freeman) talks about "objective conditions," he is not talking about "the
forces of production" (as the technological determinists do) or even "the
capitalist mode of production" as much as the left-overs, the hangovers,
from the past.


Jim,

I don't think this gets quite out of the woods.  First, your notion is
very much like Roy Bhaskar's argument for what he calls the transformative
mode of social activity.  Except for Roy, not only does the past haunt
the present, it also allows social institutions to have emergent properties
(their own causal efficacy) independent of any given individuals.  Second,
to say something is overdetermined does not necessarily mean everything
determines everything else -- including the present determining the past.
All it requires is multiple and contingent causes such that a given outcome
is neither necessary nor sufficient evidence of any given cause.  Here again
I find Bhaskar much better than RW.  RW seem to stop at overdetermination,
whereas Bhaskar seems to start there.  His critical realist theory has us
identifying specific causes and their contingent interaction to explain why
certain outcomes do or do not appear.  If, for example, we do not see a growing
reserve army of labor during a period of U.S. history, perhaps it's because
gender relations interact with class relations to undermine a tendency that
the latter, by itself, would foster.  This is a far cry from overdetermination
since it explains the "overdetermined" (contingent) outcome rather than hide it
behind a 7-syllable word.

Marsh Feldman   Phone: 401/874-5953
Community Planning, 204 Rodman Hall   FAX: 401/874-5511
The University of Rhode Island   Internet: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Kingston, RI 02881-0815





[PEN-L:9819] Re: Keeping on track

1997-05-02 Thread Louis Proyect

At 10:57 AM 5/2/97 -0700, you wrote:
"And another thing!," he hectored

In its mad search for mathematical rigor, economics as a discipline has
gotten horribly cut off from the rest of intellectual life. Shouldn't
radical economists do something about that? Try to engage with what's going
on in other social sciences and in culture? Cultural studies is too
important to be left to some of the people who are doing it now.

Doug




I think the reason that Michael Perleman is anxious to reach foreclosure on
the RM thread is that he is concerned about my tendency to flame people.
His anxiety is grounded in reality, so at this point I volunteer to ease
out of this thread and let cooler heads prevail.

I am tempted to make one final observation on the lingering impact of the
Sokal Affair whether or not it is related to interest rates. The editors of
Social Text have just come out with a new book called "The Science Wars"
which is the famous hoax issue minus Sokal's hoax. The introduction of the
book of course takes a swipe at Alan. As if that was not enough, they have
also hit the stands with the latest copy of Social Text which has a
postscript on the Sokal Affair. It's more or less what you'd expect: seven
articles taking Sokal apart. This Social Text issue by the way is devoted
to sports and includes an article on "Sport and Melodrama: The Case of
Mexican Professional Wrestling" by Heather Levi. Boy oh boy, I wish I could
see the expression on Stanley Aronowitz and Andrew Ross's face when they
see Heather's article in the next Lingua Franca.

Louis Proyect 






[PEN-L:9804] Over 650 Million Children In Extreme Poverty

1997-05-02 Thread SHAWGI TELL


According to the United Nations Children's Fund (UNICEF), over
650 million children are living in conditions of extreme poverty.
Releasing the report, UNICEF Executive Director Carol Bellamy
said: "Contrary to what the world might expect, the poor are
getting poorer, the number of poor is increasing, and the
disparity between rich and poor has never been greater."
 The estimate is based on statistics released by the World
Bank in its latest report on World Development Indicators which
show that more than 1.3 billion people currently live on less
than $1 a day, and a further 2 billion are only marginally better
off.
 UNICEF says children account for at least 50 per cent of the
total number of poor people.


Shawgi Tell
University at Buffalo
Graduate School of Education
[EMAIL PROTECTED]







[PEN-L:9822] Re: US Steel and Finance Capital

1997-05-02 Thread Tavis Barr


Michael--

Your piece on US Steel was interesting.  Thanks.  It raised a bunch of 
questions, though:

You describe one view of production (unit cost-minimizing) as "industrial" 
and the other (revenue maximizing through rents) as "financial."  While 
the classification has some aesthetic appeal (your industrial capitalist 
would spend more time in the shop cutting tools and your financial 
capitalist in the field analyzing and influencing markets), it seems to 
me that the difference really just reflects a difference between 
competitive and monopolistic behavior.  Both capitalists are maximizing 
markups times quantity over capital; the first one assumes little market 
power and the second one a lot.  They certainly adopt different choices 
of technique, and the "financial" capitalist adopts one that is grossly 
inefficient.  But the "financial" capitalist is still solving a 
profit-maximization problem based on steel production, not on speculative 
activity.  So it isn't necessarily an explanation of why the nature of 
work in the steel industry might have changed, unless there 
are huge numbers of market analysts, which I doubt.

Getting back to Louis' original point: It seems an interesting hypothesis 
that steel companies have switched their operations toward market control 
and away from production techniques.  Your case for the 1920s and 1930s 
seems clear.  In the 80s and 90s, though, the new rage is these 
mini-mills that produce as much output with a fraction (like a tenth) of 
the production workers of the previous mills.  As far as I am aware, 
there are a number of these mills and price-fixing has become much more 
difficult.  So we may be back to more "competitive" conditions.  Why, 
then, have firms not dropped non-production workers?  Is there more RD 
to do?  Have computer advancements not really been implemented in 
non-production work?  I'm just being pesky.

Cheers,
Tavis



On Thu, 1 May 1997, Michael Perelman wrote:

 In the extract I posted, the technology in question was from the 1920s and
 the charge came from Fortune magazine, writing only a few decades after
 the formation of U.S. Steel.
 
 Under Carnegie, new technology came at a furious pace, so much so that
 Morgan and others wanted to buy out Carnegie who was undermining the value
 of their invested assets.  At one point, he destroyed an unfinished
 factory because he had just learnt of a better technology.
 
 Under U.S. Steel, innovation more or less ceased.  Some of the Youngstown
 plants shut down in the early 70s predated World War I.
 
 My point was that the company ceased to have a productionist mentality and
 adopted a more banker-like mentality.
 
  -- 
 Michael Perelman
 Economics Department
 California State University
 Chico, CA 95929
 
 Tel. 916-898-5321
 E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 





[PEN-L:9823] Re: MAI and Foreign Control in Canada

1997-05-02 Thread Bill Burgess


On Fri, 2 May 1997 [EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote (**excerpts only** below):

   Isn't it important to look at specific sectors of the economy rather
 than just the overall amount of foreign control?

I agree, but the tendency has been to look only at sectors with high
foreign control and **ignore** how Canadian capital has overal control
(as I previously noted, four-fifths of the economy, by assets). In
particular, Canadian control in finance sectors has been downplayed
because of a long-standing myth that finance capital never developed in
Canada; that there are few links between financial and industrial sectors
in this country.

 What would be interesting would be to
 look at the relative changes in certain areas dominated by foreign control.
 For example what has happened in the following?:(from
 Rotstein INDEPENDENCE THE CANADIAN CHALLENGE Mclelland and Stewart 1972)
   Percentage of Non-Resident Ownership by:
   Assets  Profits
 Petroleum and Coal99.799.7
 Chemicals 81.388.9
 Tobacco   84.582.7
 

I don't have all the sector data at hand, and there have been several
changes in how they are defined. The point here is that the large decline
in foreign control in the 1970s and 1980s was ***across the board***, in
all major sectors, including those always cited, e.g.

manufacturing: 58.3% in 1971 to 44% in 1988
mining:69.4%41.9
utilities  8.4% 3.3
petroleum  94.4%65.0 (by revenues)
   89.6 59.8 (in 1980 by assets, last data I have)

Since it is the US that has always been the nationalists' target, it
is worth noting that during these years, US control declined **more** than
all foreign control, e.g. US control of manufacturing dropped from
the peak of 48.3% in 1970 to a low of 24.4% in 1987. I don't think this
can be explained by the mild nationalist measures like Trudeau's Foreign
Investment Review Agency. Canadian capitalists **never lost** control of
the economy; they accepted massive US FDI and then were able to regain
a good chuck of the **now much larger** base for further accumulation.

Stats Can reports foreign control under new categories after 1988, e.g:

-energy 23.3% in 1988 to 18.4% in 1994
-chemical and textiles  53.8 66.6  
-wood and paper 27.227.3
-minerals and metals22.323.2
-transport  5.7 6.7
-deposit accept inst.   12.911.

  Here is an illustration of the manner in which different measures give a
 vastly different picture. (Statistics Canada, 1969) 
COMPARISON OF PHARMACEUTICAL ESTABLISHMENTS OPERATING UNDER FOREIGN AND
 DOMESTIC CONTROL:   (%age)
   (1969)
   Under Foreign Control   Domestic Control
  US  European Total
 
 Number of establishments   34.7  842.757.3
  However a different measure gives a radically different picture:
 Number of production workers 61.210.5  71.7   28.5
 or total employees66.2 12.6 78.8  21.2
 or value added from
 manufacturing 74.5 13.1  87.5 12.5
 
 Surely it is these sorts of figures rather than gross percentages that give
 some idea what is coming down the line.
Cheers, Ken Hanly   

What I see from this data is that it seems like foreign firms in this
sector are larger and more capital intensive than domestic firms. This is
generally true; most foreign investments are fairly large scale. But what
is the point? Are you suggesting that what is "coming down the line" is
fewer jobs **because** foreign investors **create fewer jobs** than
Canadian investors?
 
 THe MAI is just a further
 step towards assuring that people cannot use the state in ways not approved by
 international capital. Is this not the case? Burgess seems to rail against
 bourgeois nationalism and the national bourgeoisie. However, it is not the
 national bourgeoisie per se that the new policies are directed against it
 is directed against people adopting a national policy that would conflict with
 the interests of international capital. 

We should not ignore that policies like NAFTA and MAI are ***also***
directed by imperialists against their rivals. My plea is to keep our eyes
on capitalism and not get drawn into supporting one bourgoisie against the 
other. And, unfortunately, capitalist governments currently
stand in the way of the "people adopting a national policy that would
conflict with the interests of international capital". The only place I
can think of where this is happening is Cuba.  

A national policy includes such things
  as using
 one's energy resources to serve the needs of one's citizens first and foremost
 and being able to charge others more if the demand is there or restricting
 export--all impossible for oil and gase resources under NAFTA if I understand
 

[PEN-L:9810] Keeping on track

1997-05-02 Thread Michael Perelman

The thread on globalization seems to be very valuable.  Much like the
debates about the mode of production in developing countries in the 60s,
it has important implications for political action.

The Rethinking Marxism debate, in contrast, seems to serve no other
purpose other than reopening old wounds.  We are weak enough that we do
not to fight each other.  Yes, I realize that bad tactics can also
fragment a movement.  Recall the repression that would follow Bakunin's
periodic announcements of revolutionary takeovers.

On a narrow U.S., note: I have been hearing the hoopla about FDR in
recent days.  I suspect that he was no more courageous nor visionary
than Clinton.  He had fewer money troubles, but was also a womanizer. 
FDR and Nixon, for that matter, had strong protest movements that pushed
them forward.  Clinton gets a free ride.  Let us keep our eye on the
real enemies.  Whether you agree with RM, postmodernism, Leninist,
Trostskyist, or Stalinist politics is not as important as getting
something real done when, as in the U.S., Clinton and the Republicans
can sit down in a room and negotiate a budget, leaving Dick Gephart to
represent the people.  We are in a sorry fix and need to get something
done.
--
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 916-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]





[PEN-L:9808] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-02 Thread Louis Proyect

Antonio Callari:

 For you to use the example of the plenaries to
typecast the journal is simply to give free reign to the instincts you, and
orthers, to attack! attack! attack! Attack who? us? for not having had
balanced plenaries? Where is the public attack on other conferences that
also do not have balanced plenaries, or even as balanced programs as the RM
conference had? 

I don't understand why there is such an adamant refusal to engage with the
political context which is the Sokal affair. This has opened up a big fault
line within academic Marxism. On one side you have a constellation of
thinkers like Sondra Harding, Vandana Shiva, Andrew Ross, yourself. On the
other you have Meera Nanda, Ellen Woods, et al. What is at stake is the
future of Marxism.

If the SSC organizing committee neglects to have Stephen Resnick address a
plenary, this has more to do I guess with rivalries within academia rather
than what the agenda of Marxism should be. But when you have a conference
in the name of Marxism, even if it is for "rethinking" Marxism, and have
Vandana Shiva as a keynote speaker, the issue is politics not professional
courtesy. 

What does Shiva have to do with Marxism anyway? What you were
communicating, especially given the background of the Sokal affair, is that
the big tent of Marxism should include her. I find this incomprehensible.
Shiva is an ideological opponent of Marxism. Not just "orthodox" Marxism
whatever that means, but Althusserite Marxism, post-Marxism, neo-Marxism,
or whatever else you want to call it. When she says that there is some link
between Rene Descartes and Mad Cow disease, somebody should have used the
kind of hook they used to use in vaudeville shows and pulled her off the
stage. Her offense was promoting idealistic obscurantism at a nominally
Marxist conference. (I guess a hook should have been used for St. Balibar
as well for the offense of self-love.)

The reason there is so much tension around these questions is that you no
longer face a docile audience at these conferences. Graduate students who I
have gotten to know on PEN-L and the Spoons Marxism lists absolutely
despise the idealist obscurantism of people like Vandana Shiva. Most of
them are very reluctant to speak up publicly because they are afraid of
getting blackballed when they are looking for a job. They rely on the
self-employed like Doug Henwood to speak for them. He doesn't have to worry
about tenure.

This fear is real. One of the young Indian graduate students who yelled at
St. Balibar came to me at the conference and urged me to defend her and her
comrades because she was worried that you were going to jeopardize her
academic career. As it turns out, her fears were probably an overreaction.
In any case, if a graduate student can't speak their mind, then it's not
really worth making a career in academia. They should follow the model of
Spinoza who knew that his philosophy would never get accepted in official
circles. He taught himself lens grinding and spoke truth to power on his
own time. If you can't make a living lens grinding nowadays, there is
always computer programming.

Louis Proyect






[PEN-L:9816] Re: Keeping on track

1997-05-02 Thread Doug Henwood

"And another thing!," he hectored

In its mad search for mathematical rigor, economics as a discipline has
gotten horribly cut off from the rest of intellectual life. Shouldn't
radical economists do something about that? Try to engage with what's going
on in other social sciences and in culture? Cultural studies is too
important to be left to some of the people who are doing it now.

Doug







[PEN-L:9817] Re: Globaloney

1997-05-02 Thread Doug Henwood

Marshall Feldman wrote:

Perhaps one should go back before 1980.  Most arguments re. globalization
allude to a transition in the SSA/MSR c. 1969.  So comparing 1960 and
1997 might be more to the point.

What then becomes the non-globalized Other of this model? The crisis years
1929-45? The period of nonglobalization ran from 1945, or 1950, to 1969?

Doug








[PEN-L:9821] Re: Workers' interests

1997-05-02 Thread rakesh bhandari

Question:

What are the classic/standard references on the question
"What are workers' interests"? (That is, beyond work
of Lukacs, Gramsci, Poulantzas) Is there any good recent
discussion of this question?

Thanks.
Eric

Revolutionary workers are most interested in the abolition of wage labor
or, to put it as Marx did in the German Ideology, the self-abolition of the
proletariat; that answer you will get in Moishe Postone's Time, Labor and
Social Domination:a reinterpretation of Marx's critical theory.

The recent discussion is at the end of the list. But some of the older
stuff is really not to be missed.

Max Adler, 1933. "Metamorphasis of the Working Class?" In Austro Marxism, ed.
   Tom Bottomore (1978)
Paul Crosser, 1941. Ideologies and American Labor
Henryk Frankel, 1970. Capitalist Society and Modern Sociology
Paul Mattick, 1983. Marxism: last refuge of the bourgeoisie?
Roy Eyerman, 1981. False Consciousness and Ideology in Marxist Theory
Guglielmo Carchedi, 1987. Class Analysis and Social Research
Rosemary Crompton, 1993. Class and Stratification: An Introduction to
  Contemporary Debates
Stephen Perkins, 1993. Marxism and the Proletariat: A Lukascian Perspective
Stanley Aronowitz, 1995. The Jobless Future
John F. Sitton, 1996. Recent Marxian Theory: Class Formation and Conflict in
  Contemporary Capitalism.

Rakesh
Ethnic Studies







[PEN-L:9806] Workers' interests

1997-05-02 Thread Eric Nilsson

Question:

What are the classic/standard references on the question 
"What are workers' interests"? (That is, beyond work
of Lukacs, Gramsci, Poulantzas) Is there any good recent
discussion of this question?

Thanks.
Eric
..

Eric Nilsson
Department of Economics
California State University
San Bernardino, CA 92407
[EMAIL PROTECTED]





[PEN-L:9812] RM conference overdetermination

1997-05-02 Thread James Devine

I'm sorry that I started a discussion of the Rethinking Marxism conference.
Not having been there, I didn't know that people were so sensitive about
it. Worse, I didn't realize that it would open the Jerry vs. Louis debate.
Anyway, I think that pen-l has said enough about that conference -- because
there's not much more (or anything) left to say!

I agree that we need to avoid sectarian attitudes in the discussion between
the RM school and the various non-RM schools of Marxism. (Among other
things, the discussion of whether or not a school is truly  "Marxist" or
not is a pretty sterile one.) It's also good to _welcome_ criticism from
others on the left (though without automatically accepting it as true) as a
way of clarifying or even revising one's ideas. No-one knows the truth, so
getting someone else's perspective on an issue can help one get closer to
an understanding of the truth. Even bourgeois critiques of Marxism can help
sometimes. 

So why not keep the discussion at a theoretical level? let's all make an
effort to avoid attaching any personal emotions to the discussion. I am NOT
attacking any individual below. Rather, I am trying to "rethink Marxism"
(to coin a phrase ;-)).

Here goes: as I said in a pen-l missive awhile back (picking up on one of
Robin Hahnel's points about Walrasianism), it's important to know the
limits of any theory, i.e., where it does not apply. One problem with
people like Gary Becker is that he has little or no idea of where he should
stop applying his economic theory and so applies it to issues like
marriage. The same applies to some (though by no means all) versions of 
what the RM school terms "orthodox Marxism," which were indeed
"essentialist," seeing class as the be-all and end-all of all social
phenomena. Ignoring the limits of a theory encourages tautological
thinking, among other things (in which, for example, all of society is a
class phenomenon by definition). 

So what are the limits of overdetermination? I accept the idea of
overdetermination, for example as Resnick and Wolff  [1987:4] define it,
under which: "Each entity only exists as -- or is caused by or constituted
by -- the totality of these different relations with all other entities. "
If I understand RW accurately, this means (for example) that class
relations  in society interacts with gender relations, so that the
character of class phenomena is  partly determined by gender phenomena and
vice-versa. (Of course, class and gender are only two of many social
phenomena that seem relevant, so the overdetermination process is more
complex.)

That sounds fine by me (in fact, it sounds a lot like Heidi Hartmann's
excellent article a few years back in CAPITAL  CLASS, which didn't spring
from the RM school). I've complained in the past that this vision doesn't
help us decide which phenomena are more important than others (capitalism
vs. the Rotarians), but that doesn't concern me here. 

Rather, the issue is that of cases where overdetermination does not -- and
cannot -- apply (which I didn't see when reading RW). Specifically,
phenomena ("entities" or social processes) in the PAST cannot be
overdetermined in their relationships with phenomena in the PRESENT or the
FUTURE.  The arrow of causation _has to_ go only one way, from past
phenomena to present and future ones. We cannot talk about the present
determining, causing or constituting, the past -- until a time machine is
invented. 

This fits with an insight that Alan Freeman suggested as one part of a
longer paper he presented at the recent ASSA/URPE conference: when Marx (or
Freeman) talks about "objective conditions," he is not talking about "the
forces of production" (as the technological determinists do) or even "the
capitalist mode of production" as much as the left-overs, the hangovers,
from the past. 

For pen-l's experts on the RM school, is this an accurate statement of the
theory of overdetermination and its limits? are there other limits? 

BTW, one of the nice things about having tenure is that I don't have to
teach myself lens-grinding the way Spinoza did in order to speak (what I
perceive to be) the truth. 

in pen-l solidarity,

Jim Devine





[PEN-L:9820] Re: Subscribe

1997-05-02 Thread Richard Weisskoff

At 09:47 AM 4/28/97 -0700, you wrote:
subscribe










[PEN-L:9807] Re: Rethinking Marxism conference

1997-05-02 Thread Antonio Callari

There we go again! One of the points Steve Cullenberg made was that we can
hardly afford to be fighting about these things. For example, we in RM,
both personally and as a group notice when other conferences exclude us, or
are not balanced in their plenaries, etc. Yet, as far as I know, none of us
has ever attacked them for this, certainly not publicly, and not even
privately--Doug Henwood knows that, for example, we discussed the socialist
scholars conference in these terms. If there are mistakes made, on all
sides, they should be occasions for discussions, not threats, public
condemnations, and demonizing strategies. But I see signs of this type of
stuff emerging again, in the context of this latest round of postings. A
plea: stop this. The left has a tendency to behave as a group of Hyper
people who, unable to find ways of putting their energies into productive
and effective social change practices, turn their frustation inward and
take up the favorite sport of sectarianism. This is not very productive.
(Steve Cullenberg was speaking for himself, not for the organizing group as
a whole, just as I speak for myself; the views about RM, etc. expressed by
people are individual views, and a group, a project, a journal is always
more than the positions, the merits, the mistakes, etc. of any one
individual, steve cullenberg, or me, or anyone else. Doug, your reaction to
Steve, in addition to being unfair to him--for I don't think he wrote what
he did in the sectarian spirit you imputed to him--is unfair and
problematic in that it turns into an attack on the journal as a whole. And
the level of your critique is simplistic. There is both thinking and
rethinking in the journal. For you to use the example of the plenaries to
typecast the journal is simply to give free reign to the instincts you, and
orthers, to attack! attack! attack! Attack who? us? for not having had
balanced plenaries? Where is the public attack on other conferences that
also do not have balanced plenaries, or even as balanced programs as the RM
conference had? Not that I want to see this happen--but it seems to me that
the criticism that the RM conference was bad because the plenaries were not
balanced is more a cover for an attack on RM than a criticism about the
lack of balance itself. And by the way, one simple reason for the lack of
balance that I don't think anybody has yet explained, is the quite simple
fact that we had some organizational difficulties. I would think people
would appreciate the amount of work we did to have this, and other,
conferences, and not use a disagreement with us, or a mistake by us, as a
jumping basis for attacking us--or worse!)

So: let's be kind, let's be friends, let's build together instead of
tearing each other apart. Please!

Antonio Callari


Stephen Cullenberg wrote:

Yet, we are not, and never have pretended to be, as ecumenical as say URPE
and the RRPE.

This then is Rethinking? My first reaction to the conference was too much
Re, not enough thinking, but now I'm even questioning the Re.

A nonecumenical group of people who agree on fundamental things and view
plenaries as a form of preaching to a mixed crowd of converted and
unconverted? Did the presence of a large critical minority seem something
worthy of ackknowledging as something other than a personal attack? This is
exactly what I meant by the plenaries having shown signs of hardening into
orthodoxy, which as the postmodernists have taught us well, is defined
through exclusion. Is the devotion to polyvocality just another empty
signifier?


Doug

--

Doug Henwood
Left Business Observer
250 W 85 St
New York NY 10024-3217 USA
+1-212-874-4020 voice  +1-212-874-3137 fax
email: mailto:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
web: http://www.panix.com/~dhenwood/LBO_home.html

Antonio Callari
E-MAIL: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
POST MAIL:  Department of Economics
Franklin and Marshall College
Lancaster PA 17604-3003
PHONE:  717/291-3947
FAX:717/291-4369







[PEN-L:9809] Re: MAI and Foreign Control in Canada

1997-05-02 Thread HANLY

Isn't it important to look at specific sectors of the economy rather
than just the overall amount of foreign control?
In the late sixties and early seventies there was a concerted effort by
the left nationalists such as Watkins and Laxer to call attention to the
degree of US and foreign control of the Canadian economy. It may very well
be that the nationalist policies that developed as a result of the Watkins and
Gray report and pressure by those such as the Wafflers in the NDP resulted in
a decline in US and foreign ownership. What would be interesting would be to
look at the relative changes in certain areas dominated by foreign control.
For example what has happened in the following?:(from
Rotstein INDEPENDENCE THE CANADIAN CHALLENGE Mclelland and Stewart 1972)
Percentage of Non-Resident Ownership by:
Assets  Profits
Petroleum and Coal  99.799.7
Chemicals   81.388.9
Tobacco 84.582.7

Obviously some key sectors are dominated by foreign ownership. This
may have considerable policy effects. The National Energy programme for example
has been completely gutted and would be impossible under the terms of
NAFTA. I realise the data I use is more than 25 years old, but I would like to
know what is the situation now in sectors such as I cite.
While assets may be a reasonable measure of concentration of
foreign ownership, other measures may be revealing as well. Take the
pharmaceutical industry. This industry has been successful in lobbying for
legislation that benefits TNC drug giants at the expense both of generic
manufacturers and of our medicare programme. You surely are aware of some of
this. It is not just a question of protecting Canadian generic manufacturers
(or foreign ones) it is of assuring that TNC drug giants
 don't use patent protection
to drive drug prices through the roof.
 Here is an illustration of the manner in which different measures give a
vastly different picture. (Statistics Canada, 1969) 
   COMPARISON OF PHARMACEUTICAL ESTABLISHMENTS OPERATING UNDER FOREIGN AND
DOMESTIC CONTROL:   (%age)
(1969)
Under Foreign Control   Domestic Control
 US  European Total

Number of establishments   34.7  842.7  57.3
 However a different measure gives a radically different picture:
Number of production workers 61.210.5  71.7 28.5
or total employees  66.2 12.6 78.8  21.2
or value added from
manufacturing   74.5 13.1  87.5 12.5

Surely it is these sorts of figures rather than gross percentages that give
some idea what is coming down the line.
   Cheers, Ken Hanly   

PS I agree that there is no reason to protect Cdn Capitalists just because
they are Canadian. As even the gbourgeois Trudeau recognised he had to 
nationalise a large oil enterprise (PEtroCan) as part of a rational national
energy programme. We need a similar significant state presence in drugs
gas etc. Now Petro Can is gone and the very possibility of a national energy
policy is threatened by the terms of NAFTA. THe MAI is just a further
step towards assuring that people cannot use the state in ways not approved by
international capital. Is this not the case? Burgess seems to rail against
bourgeois nationalism and the national bourgeoisie. However, it is not the
national bourgeoisie per se that the new policies are directed against it
is directed against people adopting a national policy that would conflict with
the interests of international capital. A national policy includes such things
 as using
one's energy resources to serve the needs of one's citizens first and foremost
and being able to charge others more if the demand is there or restricting
export--all impossible for oil and gase resources under NAFTA if I understand
it correctly. We now have
such things as control of marketing such as the Canadian Wheat Board, marketing
boards etc. but new rules and agreements attempt to dismantle them.
 National policies might involve subsidies
if it were thought to be in the public interest etc. and protection from
foreign imports etc.etc. But all this is being eroded.
I hear nothing from Burgess about
such matters or nationalisation.
 In fact nationalisation and taking into public ownership seems to be the
last bloody thing the left ever talks about nowadays. A fucking disgrace.
  By the way Canadian farmers voted in favor of retaining monopoly marketing of
barley just recently. Some light in the gloom. 








To Cheryl from Gainsville

1997-05-02 Thread Nathan Henderson-James

I am sorry to clutter the entire list with what is a personal message, but
I do not have Cheryl from Ganisville's e-mail address, nor was I smart
enough to writer down her last name before I carelessly erased the e-mail
message she left me.

So Cheryl, I am not ignoring you.  I was just technologically incompetant
today. I invite you to please contact me again either by phone at
202-547-2500 or by e-mail at resgeneral@acorn and we can discuss
welfare/workfare research for the City of Ganisville.  Thank you.

Nathan


_
Nathan Henderson-James, Research Coordinator
ACORN (Association of Community Organizations for Reform Now)
[EMAIL PROTECTED]   202-547-2500 voice   202-546-2483 fax
  http://www.acorn.org/community
**
Our job is to comfort the afflicted, and afflict the comfortable.
-- Mother Jones
**
This Week in History: 4/27/94: South Africa's first all-race elections.
5/1/1830: Birth of Mary Harris (Mother Jones).








[PEN-L:9831] Re: US Steel and Finance Capital

1997-05-02 Thread Eugene P. Coyle

Michael addressed the 20s and 30s and Tavis jumped to the 80s and 90s.  I
want to insert the 60s.

In the mid 1960s European steel makers, and I think the Japanese,
were building capacity with new technology, the BOF.  US steel companies --
and as I recall, specifically United States Steel as it was still named at
the time --  were also adding capacity, but adding what was well accepted
as obsolete technology.  So the issue wasn't industrial vs. finance, they
WERE adding capacity, but obsolete.  Just dumb?  Unaware?  No, not unaware,
a lot of people questioned the choice of technology at the time.

Michael--

Your piece on US Steel was interesting.  Thanks.  It raised a bunch of
questions, though:

You describe one view of production (unit cost-minimizing) as "industrial"
and the other (revenue maximizing through rents) as "financial."  While
the classification has some aesthetic appeal (your industrial capitalist
would spend more time in the shop cutting tools and your financial
capitalist in the field analyzing and influencing markets), it seems to
me that the difference really just reflects a difference between
competitive and monopolistic behavior.  Both capitalists are maximizing
markups times quantity over capital; the first one assumes little market
power and the second one a lot.  They certainly adopt different choices
of technique, and the "financial" capitalist adopts one that is grossly
inefficient.  But the "financial" capitalist is still solving a
profit-maximization problem based on steel production, not on speculative
activity.  So it isn't necessarily an explanation of why the nature of
work in the steel industry might have changed, unless there
are huge numbers of market analysts, which I doubt.

Getting back to Louis' original point: It seems an interesting hypothesis
that steel companies have switched their operations toward market control
and away from production techniques.  Your case for the 1920s and 1930s
seems clear.  In the 80s and 90s, though, the new rage is these
mini-mills that produce as much output with a fraction (like a tenth) of
the production workers of the previous mills.  As far as I am aware,
there are a number of these mills and price-fixing has become much more
difficult.  So we may be back to more "competitive" conditions.  Why,
then, have firms not dropped non-production workers?  Is there more RD
to do?  Have computer advancements not really been implemented in
non-production work?  I'm just being pesky.

Cheers,
Tavis



On Thu, 1 May 1997, Michael Perelman wrote:

 In the extract I posted, the technology in question was from the 1920s and
 the charge came from Fortune magazine, writing only a few decades after
 the formation of U.S. Steel.

 Under Carnegie, new technology came at a furious pace, so much so that
 Morgan and others wanted to buy out Carnegie who was undermining the value
 of their invested assets.  At one point, he destroyed an unfinished
 factory because he had just learnt of a better technology.

 Under U.S. Steel, innovation more or less ceased.  Some of the Youngstown
 plants shut down in the early 70s predated World War I.

 My point was that the company ceased to have a productionist mentality and
 adopted a more banker-like mentality.

  --
 Michael Perelman
 Economics Department
 California State University
 Chico, CA 95929

 Tel. 916-898-5321
 E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]








[PEN-L:9833] Re: US Steel and Finance Capital

1997-05-02 Thread Michael Perelman

I understand that, in part, the steel companies stuck with their old
technology to avoid having to scrap existing equipment.  I don't think
that there were few greenfield investments.
 -- 
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 916-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]





[PEN-L:9826] Re: US Steel and Finance Capital

1997-05-02 Thread Michael Perelman

Tavis Barr wrote:
 
 Michael--
 
 Your piece on US Steel was interesting.  Thanks.  It raised a bunch of
 questions, though:
 
 You describe one view of production (unit cost-minimizing) as "industrial"
 and the other (revenue maximizing through rents) as "financial."  While
 the classification has some aesthetic appeal (your industrial capitalist
 would spend more time in the shop cutting tools and your financial
 capitalist in the field analyzing and influencing markets), it seems to
 me that the difference really just reflects a difference between
 competitive and monopolistic behavior. 

Yes, indeed.  The industrialsts did too much competing for the financial
types, so they remade the economy at the turn of the century through
trust, cartels and outright monopolies.  In many cases, it took a
different mentality to succeed at the productionist side than to win at
the finance side. 

 Getting back to Louis' original point: It seems an interesting hypothesis
 that steel companies have switched their operations toward market control
 and away from production techniques.  Your case for the 1920s and 1930s
 seems clear.  In the 80s and 90s, though, the new rage is these
 mini-mills that produce as much output with a fraction (like a tenth) of
 the production workers of the previous mills.  

Yes, the minimills came in nearly 3/4 of a century after the formation
of U.S. Steel.  The company maintained control, as did most of the
cartels, by directing their investment to buying up potential
competitors.

As far as I am aware,
 there are a number of these mills and price-fixing has become much more
 difficult.  So we may be back to more "competitive" conditions.

Yes. Bethlehem Steel Corporation, the nation's second largest
steel producer in 1956, employed eleven of the eighteen best-paid
executives in the U.S.  Every vice president had his own dining
room with linen tablecloths and full waiter service.  Each
Bethlehem plant had its own golf course, and the company employed
three individuals whose only job was playing golf with clients.


 then, have firms not dropped non-production workers?  

But they have.


Is there more RD
 to do?  Have computer advancements not really been implemented in
 non-production work?  I'm just being pesky.

There is a great debate over the degree to which computers have and will
increase efficiency in the production side.  Ed Wolff has recently shown
that much of the increase in competitiveness in manufacturing has come
via contracting out business services.


--
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 916-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]





[PEN-L:9837] whose consumption

1997-05-02 Thread J. Zaccone

I have been wondering why consumption has kept up so well despite
stagnant or falling wages for the overwhelming majority of workers. (Of
course, rising debt ratios have helped.) An interesting insight comes from
the Chase Financial Digest:
 
 "Overall, it's the higher-income families that make or break the
spending totals--two thirds of which originates with the one in three
families with annual incomes in excess of $50,000."
 
June Zaccone, 90 La Salle St., Apt.21A, NYC 10027; 864-4493
 [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 
National Jobs for All Coalition, 475 Riverside Dr., Suite 832, NY, NY
10115-0050 212-870-3449; Fax 870-3341 [EMAIL PROTECTED] 





[PEN-L:9830] Re: US Steel and Finance Capital

1997-05-02 Thread Michael Perelman

D Shniad wrote:
 
 Michael, isn't your example a definitive refutation of the notion that
 tech change is incremental?  (Seems that way to me.)  This is consistent
 with my experience.

Generally, you are correct.  As Doug's old buddy, Larry Summers, noted,
at this point in time, technical change was fast and furious, more
dramatic than what we are seeing today.  The US was being wrenched from
an agrarian economy to an industrialized one.

For Standard Oil, the costs of producing a gallon of kerosene fell from
1.5 cents before reorganization to 0.54 cents in 1884 and 0.45 cents in
1885.

The Bessemer process reduced the price of steel rails by 88 percent
from the early 1870s to the late 1880s.  During the same period,
electrolytic refining reduced aluminum prices by 96 percent and
synthetic blue dye production costs fell by 95 percent 

I am not aware of any debates over a productivity paradox at the time.
--
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 916-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]





[PEN-L:9840] Re: What are the questions?

1997-05-02 Thread MScoleman

Enough to keep wages down.
In a message dated 97-05-02 20:30:44 EDT, you write:

 What is 
the correct number of idle workers?

It is interesting that in the first year following the raise in minimum wage
unemployment is at its lowest level in decades.  maggie coleman
[EMAIL PROTECTED]







[PEN-L:9836] globalization

1997-05-02 Thread J. Zaccone

It seems to me there are some significant differences in the global
economy, though the data are probably somewhat unreliable.  For example,
the World Bank (1995) reports the following percentages for exports of
goods and nonfactor services as a fraction of GDP:
 
1970   1993
 
Low income   7%   20%
Lower middle income  NA   22
Upper middle income  15   21
High income  14   20
 
Further, in 1995, with 20-25% of the stock of FDI, developing countries 
received 40% of new flows, concentrated in the ones with a relatively
educated but low-paid workforce. Prior to the trade agreements of the
postwar era, poorer countries were coerced into becoming and remaining
raw materials exporters and FDI reflected that. They are now sometimes
getting the equipment, technology, and foreign markets to produce
sophisticated manufactured goods that compete with industrial country
workers. This must make a difference to their bargaining power, and to the
strategies necessary to winning strikes.  June
 
June Zaccone, 90 La Salle St., Apt.21A, NYC 10027; 864-4493
 [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 
National Jobs for All Coalition, 475 Riverside Dr., Suite 832, NY, NY
10115-0050 212-870-3449; Fax 870-3341 [EMAIL PROTECTED] 

ps I didn't choose 1970--the WB did.





[PEN-L:9827] NAFTA Nightmare, MAI's potential (fwd)

1997-05-02 Thread D Shniad

 What follows is a 1600 word briefing paper on the $251 million lawsuit 
 filed by the Ethyl Corporation against the Canadian government. Ethyl used 
 its right to sue national governments established in NAFTA (and included in 
 the proposed Multilateral Agreement on Investment (MAI)) to sue Canada for 
 imposing an ban on the toxic gasoline additive MMT. This case will be a 
 test of whether investor rights in agreements like NAFTA and MAI can be 
 used to overturn environmental regulations or other safeguards.
 
 Preamble Collaborative/Preamble Center For Public Policy Briefing Paper
 1737 21st Street, N.W., Washington, D.C., 20009   202/265-3263 phone
   202/265-3647 fax
 
 
 Ethyl Corporation v. Government of Canada:
  Chemical Firm Uses Trade Pact to Contest Environmental Law
   
   Ethyl Corporation's $251 million lawsuit against a new Canadian 
 environmental law is sure to set off alarm bells throughout the public 
 interest world.  The suit, brought under the terms of the North American 
 Free Trade Agreement, demonstrates how present and future international 
 economic pacts could pose a danger to environmental regulations and other 
 safeguards.
   In early April, the Canadian Parliament acted to ban the import and 
 interprovincial transport of an Ethyl product -the gasoline additive MMT- 
 which Canada considers to be a dangerous toxin. Ethyl (the company that 
 invented leaded gasoline) responded on April 14 by filing a lawsuit against 
 the Canadian government under NAFTA.  Ethyl claims that the Canadian ban on 
 MMT violates various provisions of NAFTA and seeks restitution of $251 
 million to cover losses resulting from the "expropriation" of both its MMT 
 production plant and its "good reputation."   MMT is a manganese-based 
 compound that is added to gasoline to enhance octane and reduce engine 
 "knocking." Canadian legislators are concerned that the manganese in MMT 
 emissions poses a significant public health risk.  In addition, automobile 
 manufacturers have long argued that MMT damages emissions diagnostics and 
 control equipment in cars, thus increasing fuel emissions in general. Ethyl 
 is the product's only manufacturer.1
   The Environmental Defense Fund (EDF), which tracks the use of MMT, 
 reports that the additive is used only in Canada. The United States EPA has 
 banned its use in the formulated gasoline, which includes approximately 1/3 
 of the U.S. gasoline market. An EDF survey of the remaining producers 
 reports that none use the additive.2 California has imposed a total ban on 
 MMT.
   Canadian legislators wanted to ban the use of MMT in order to protect the 
 Canadian public. Because they could not do so under Canadian Environmental 
 Protection Act (CEPA) provisions, they chose the best available 
 alternative: banning MMT's import and transport.3 NAFTA requires member 
 countries to compensate investors when their property is "expropriated" or 
 when governments take measures "tantamount to expropriation."  Ethyl claims 
 that the MMT ban constitutes such an expropriation.  The company argues 
 that the ban will reduce the value of Ethyl's MMT manufacturing plant, hurt 
 its future sales and harm its corporate reputation. The case will be an 
 important test of how expropriation is to be defined in NAFTA and future 
 agreements.
   A key provision of NAFTA makes the lawsuit possible. Under NAFTA's 
 investment chapter, for the first time in a multilateral trade or 
 investment agreement, corporations are granted "private legal standing" - 
 or the ability to sue governments directly and to seek monetary damages. 
 This "investor-to-state" dispute resolution mechanism diverges from dispute 
 resolution systems in previous international economic agreements in two 
 ways: First, previous agreements allow only national governments to bring 
 suits. Second, these agreements do not allow for monetary compensation. The 
 most a government can do if it is successful in a suit is impose tarriffs 
 on the violating nation.
   This lawsuit is the third, and largest, under NAFTA's investor-to-state 
 dispute mechanism. According to an official at the International Centre for 
 the Settlement of Investment Disputes (ICSID), the institution that 
 arbitrates most of the world's investment complaints, the $251 million 
 Ethyl seeks is higher than any amount requested in an ICSID 
 investor-to-state proceeding.4
   The Ethyl suit raises a host of issues that should be of concern to 
 policymakers- particularly since the U.S. is negotiating the expansion of 
 NAFTA as well as a new multilateral investment agreement (MAI) that would 
 apply NAFTA-like standards worldwide.
 
 The Ethyl case could set a precedent where, under NAFTA and similar 
 agreements,  a government would have to compensate investors when it wishes 
 to regulate them or their products for public health or environmental 
 reasons.  If Ethyl wins its 

[PEN-L:9832] What are the questions?

1997-05-02 Thread John Pool

There's an old joke about the professor who always gave the same 
questions on exams. When asked about this he said "The questions are 
always the same; it's only the answers that change."
My question: What are the questions?
Cheers,
John Charles Pool
PS: For starters the unemployment rate hit 4.9 percent the lowest since 
1973. Rueters quoted a broker as saying "all the news was good expept the 
unemployment rate." That left only 6.7 million "idle workers." What is 
the correct number of idle workers?








[PEN-L:9838] Re: May Day

1997-05-02 Thread MScoleman

Speaking of which, I went to see "Children of the Revolution" for May Day.
 Did anyone else see it?  If so--what did you think?  maggie coleman
[EMAIL PROTECTED]

In a message dated 97-05-02 04:09:49 EDT, you write:

Subj:  [PEN-L:9802] May Day
Date:  97-05-02 04:09:49 EDT
From:  [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Sender:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
Reply-to:  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

May I wish you all an affirmative May Day (a happy May Day would be
a bit much).  There are still so many out there that are suffering
from the ravages of capitalism that they deserve our sympathy, but
more than that, our organized help.
  At the moment we are battling the ravages of nature, the flood of
the century.  But when that battle is over, let us battle the
deprivations of inequality, poverty and homelessness!
Paul Phillips,
Economics,
University of Manitoba


--- Headers 
Return-Path: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Received: from anthrax.ecst.csuchico.edu (anthrax.ecst.csuchico.edu
[132.241.9.84])
 by mrin62.mail.aol.com (8.8.5/8.8.5/AOL-1.0.1)
 Fri, 2 May 1997 00:27:47 -0400 (EDT)
Received: from anthrax (localhost [127.0.0.1])
   Thu, 1 May 1997 21:27:23 -0700 (PDT)
Date: Thu, 1 May 1997 21:27:23 -0700 (PDT)
Message-Id: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Reply-To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Originator: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Sender: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Precedence: bulk
From: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Subject: [PEN-L:9802] May Day
X-Listprocessor-Version: 6.0c -- ListProcessor by Anastasios Kotsikonas
X-Comment: Progressive Economics







[PEN-L:9834] BOOK PARTY

1997-05-02 Thread mreview

On Wednesday, May 7th, 5:30pm, the editors and staff of Monthly Review Press
will host a reception for Doug Dowd to celebrate the publication of his new
book, BLUES FOR AMERICA: A CRITIQUE, A LAMENT, AND SOME MEMORIES. Please
join us at 122 West 27th Street, 10th floor, NYC, (212) 691-2555.


Advance Praise for BLUES FOR AMERICA:

"BLUES FOR AMERICA is a scholar's deft survey of everything that happened
between the 1920s and the 1990s related with surprising wit and an amazingly
gracious turn of phrase ..."--BARBARA EHRENREICH

"A vivid, witty, moving account of much of the history of this century by
someone who was there when it mattered ..."--NOAM CHOMSKY

"Personal, provocative, and elegantly written, BLUES FOR AMERICA ought to be
widely read, and relished ..."--JONATHAN KOZOL

"It is rare to find a book written with style and loaded with substance, an
education in itself, and a pleasure to read."--HOWARD ZINN


In BLUES FOR AMERICA, Doug Dowd has written a narrative filled with incisive
observations and biting humor that is at once autobiography and an economic
history of the perplexing "American Century."


DOUG DOWD is a distinguished economist and professorial lecturer in
International Economics at the Bologna Center, Johns Hopkins University,
Bologna, Italy. A national figure in the movement to end the Vietnam War,
Dowd has taught at the University of California, Berkeley; the University of
California, Santa Cruz; San Jose State and San Francisco State Universities;
and Cornell University, where he was Chair of the Economics Department. He
has received Guggenheim and Fulbright Fellowships, and is the author of
several books.







[PEN-L:9843] Re: MAI and Foreign Control in Canada, Globaloney

1997-05-02 Thread Rosenberg, Bill

Sid Schniad's and Doug Henwood's figures on speculation
and foreign investment in the world economy, and Bill
Burgess's on Canada were interesting. I'd always had the
impression Canada was more neo-colonised than New
Zealand. However you might like to consider these figures
for New Zealand:

A New Zealand Reserve Bank survey in 1996 [1] showed
*daily* New Zealand foreign exchange market turnover in
1992 of US$4.2 billion, which had risen to US$7.2 billion
by 1995. In 1995 only 56% involved the NZ$.

By way of comparison, New Zealand's GDP in the March 1993
year was about US$41 billion and in the March 1996 year
about US$59 billion. The *annual* New Zealand Stock
Exchange turnover is about US$8.5 billion. Merchandise
exports in the year to March 1993 were about US$10
billion, and to March 1996 about US$13 billion, so
exports accounted for about 0.9% and 0.7% of currency
turnover in the two years. The New Zealand dollar is said
to be the 7th most traded currency in the world!

To add to Doug's table, New Zealand exports have gone
from 24.8% of GDP in 1980 to 23.8% in 1994. The ratio
rose more or less steadily from 1961 to 1980 and 81, then
began falling until 1990, when it began rising again,
peaking in 1993.

However, the picture is considerably different in foreign
investment, to the extent it can be estimated. The last
official figures for foreign ownership of assets (a la
Bill Burgess) were in 1982-83, which indicated foreign
companies had 25.6% of the paid-up capital of the
companies in the survey (which was not complete). 36.8%
of tax-assessable income and 32.4% of dividends paid went
to these foreign companies. In a paper I completed
recently [2], using data from the New Zealand Top 230
companies (including financial institutions) and
elsewhere, I concluded that in 1995, over half of company
operating surplus (earnings before interest and tax) went
to foreign companies in New Zealand. There are no asset
figures available for such a comparison. However it
appears there has been a substantial increase in foreign
control of the New Zealand economy in that period.

Since 1989 there have been official statistics on New
Zealand's International Investment Position, which shows
assets held in New Zealand by foreigners and overseas
assets held by New Zealand residents. Foreign investment
in New Zealand (including portfolio) has risen from NZ$51
billion to NZ$97 billion from 1989 to 1995 and New
Zealand investment abroad from NZ$7.2 billion to NZ$23.4
billion. The net position has gone from -NZ$44.1 billion
to -NZ$73.3 billion. By this measure, the ratio of inward
FDI to GDP was 14.4% in 1989 and 46.7% in 1995. Outward
FDI to GDP was 1.3% in 1989 and 13.4% in 1995, though one
wonders whether some of these increases are simply
because Statistics New Zealand have got better at
measuring.

Almost the entire New Zealand financial sector is foreign
owned. In 1996, 24 out of the "Management" magazine top
30 institutions, including almost all the biggest ones,
were foreign, as were 122 out of the top 200 non-
financial companies.

Some of the effects:
- when the economy "booms" to the extent that company
profits increase, the current account goes worse into
deficit because of the increasing dividend and interest
payments abroad.
- a dysfunctional exchange rate. It is set by interest
rates attracting foreign investors and foreign investor
"confidence" in the New Zealand government rather than
"real" transactions.
- hence New Zealand has a chronic, worsening, current
account deficit (currently 4.2% of GDP) and steadily
increasing foreign debt. Private foreign debt has risen
from 9.8% to 54.6% of GDP between 1983 and 1996, though
government foreign debt has fallen, offsetting the rise.
Total foreign debt has risen from 46.7% to 79.1% of GDP
in the same period.
- funnily enough, it wrecks the monetarist Reserve Bank's
attempts to control inflation using the exchange rate
(encouraging it to rise to reduce internal prices) and
interest rates. Higher interest rates increase the
exchange rate because they attract foreign investors,
threatening inflation targets and damaging exporters.
Importers of course don't reduce their prices when the
exchange rate rises.
- craven foreign-investor-friendly policies by New
Zealand governments, with which you'll be familiar.

Why should we protect national capitalists via opposing
the MAI, etc, asked Bill Burgess. In New Zealand's case,
primarily to reduce dependence on foreign capital, which
is demonstrably leading government policy. But a few
other figures I calculated from the Top 200 are
interesting:
- after-tax profit per employee was $20,000 for New
Zealand companies, and $29,800 for foreign companies
- though they took half the operating surplus, they
employed only 18% of the full-time workforce.
- turnover per employee was lower for foreign than New
Zealand companies in most industrial classifications. New
Zealand's overall rate of growth in labour productivity
has fallen since 

[PEN-L:9839] Re: Keeping on track

1997-05-02 Thread MScoleman

I agree: (buut):
In a message dated 97-05-02 13:57:57 EDT, you write:

"And another thing!," he hectored

In its mad search for mathematical rigor, economics as a discipline has
gotten horribly cut off from the rest of intellectual life. Shouldn't
radical economists do something about that? Try to engage with what's going
on in other social sciences and in culture? 

If we are going to engage in cultural studies aren't we going to have to work
with the people already doing the work?
Cultural studies is too
important to be left to some of the people who are doing it now.

Doug
maggie coleman [EMAIL PROTECTED]






[PEN-L:9835] Re: US Steel and Finance Capital

1997-05-02 Thread Anthony P D'Costa

This financial and industrial distiction is somewhat simplistic, even
though the verdict appears to be the former for US Steel.  True US Steel
was dominant but there were other big players.  True USS led oligopoly was
more effective in price stability (upward rigid) and high financial
returns, but any historical analysis shows that US firms did innovate.
See Gold et al, Paskoff, among a few.  Otherwise you cannot explain the US
dominance in the industry (including technology transfers worldwide).  If
you believe in path-dependence then there is plenty to say about why US
firms have been slow in adopting new innovations (the BOF for example) in
the postwar period relative to the Japanese.  The structure of the
industry is important but so were the actions (and idiosncratic factors
like sudden jumps in war-related demand and therefore investment in true
and tried technology, the OHF).

The assessment of minimills development is largely correct.  But higher
labor productivity has to do with different technology and therefore
different products.  scale of operations is about a 10th of the
large-scale mills (though there are few in the US).  They are mostly in
Japan, Korea, etc.  The US integrated industry is relatively
labor-intensive (although that has been changed quite a bit from the
1980s) whereas the minimill is capital intensive, using state of the art
electric furnaces, continuous casting, high-tech process controls.
Internal organizational structures and work practices are also very
different (more flexible if you will) because of smaller scale.  So in
some products integrated production cannot compete with minimills.

But price fixing still possible even if competition has increased.  steel
supplies are not that elastic.  After getting rid of obsolete capacity the
overall supply situation is somewhat belanced but around the world demand
is increasing and periodic shortages are common.  Price gouging is more
common and US steel companies (the large ones are notorious for that).
There will be supply shortages in South East Asia, hence the Japanese are
reluctant to put out the blast furnaces.  

Anthony P. D'Costa
Associate Professor Senior Fellow
Comparative International Development   Department of Economics
University of WashingtonNational University of Singapore
1103 A Street   10 Kent Ridge Crescent
Tacoma, WA 98402 USASingapore 119260

On Fri, 2 May 1997, Tavis Barr wrote:

 
 Michael--
 
 Your piece on US Steel was interesting.  Thanks.  It raised a bunch of 
 questions, though:
 
 You describe one view of production (unit cost-minimizing) as "industrial" 
 and the other (revenue maximizing through rents) as "financial."  While 
 the classification has some aesthetic appeal (your industrial capitalist 
 would spend more time in the shop cutting tools and your financial 
 capitalist in the field analyzing and influencing markets), it seems to 
 me that the difference really just reflects a difference between 
 competitive and monopolistic behavior.  Both capitalists are maximizing 
 markups times quantity over capital; the first one assumes little market 
 power and the second one a lot.  They certainly adopt different choices 
 of technique, and the "financial" capitalist adopts one that is grossly 
 inefficient.  But the "financial" capitalist is still solving a 
 profit-maximization problem based on steel production, not on speculative 
 activity.  So it isn't necessarily an explanation of why the nature of 
 work in the steel industry might have changed, unless there 
 are huge numbers of market analysts, which I doubt.
 
 Getting back to Louis' original point: It seems an interesting hypothesis 
 that steel companies have switched their operations toward market control 
 and away from production techniques.  Your case for the 1920s and 1930s 
 seems clear.  In the 80s and 90s, though, the new rage is these 
 mini-mills that produce as much output with a fraction (like a tenth) of 
 the production workers of the previous mills.  As far as I am aware, 
 there are a number of these mills and price-fixing has become much more 
 difficult.  So we may be back to more "competitive" conditions.  Why, 
 then, have firms not dropped non-production workers?  Is there more RD 
 to do?  Have computer advancements not really been implemented in 
 non-production work?  I'm just being pesky.
 
 Cheers,
 Tavis
 
 
 
 On Thu, 1 May 1997, Michael Perelman wrote:
 
  In the extract I posted, the technology in question was from the 1920s and
  the charge came from Fortune magazine, writing only a few decades after
  the formation of U.S. Steel.
  
  Under Carnegie, new technology came at a furious pace, so much so that
  Morgan and others wanted to buy out Carnegie who was undermining the value
  of their invested assets.  At one point, he destroyed an unfinished
  factory because he had just learnt of a better technology.
  
  Under 

[PEN-L:9824] Re: Keeping on track

1997-05-02 Thread Michael Perelman

Doug Henwood wrote:
 
 
 Michael, I appreciate your call for comradely amity, but these are serious
 issues that need to be discussed. Is this "sorry fix" we're in a function,
 even in part, of a bad set of theories that have led to bad political
 mistakes? Since a great deal of "postmodernism" has been about the denial
 of political economy - Foucault said it was a 19th century concern, since
 we've been transformed from beings who labor into beings who speak -
 shouldn't political economists talk about that?
 

Yes, I agree.  During the first great debates on postmodernism, at one
point we touched basis about how to apply postmodernism in practice. 
Antonio gave a response but the thread did not go very far.

I am not convinced by postmodernism, but I see some good people working
on it.  My concern would be how could we use their energies to fight
welfare deform, racism, and most of all capitalism.

Cultural studies are very important in the sense that the victor in
recent political events seems to have been the side that could define
the language.  Maybe I am wrong.  Maybe the strength from the political
side carried over into language, but at least some of the force went the
other way.

Shiva's work on patenting nature seems very important.  What we need to
do is to pick up on the strong parts and discard the dross.


---

Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 916-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]





[PEN-L:9842] Canadian unemployment rate question

1997-05-02 Thread tscarth

I seem to remember reading that the official Canadian unemployment
statistics do not take into account certain groups; specifically, I believe
that either 'status Indians' or people living on reserves are not included
in the unemployment rate. Is this true? If it is, why is it done like that?
Finally, does anyone know what the unemployment rate would be if these
people were included? (I tried-not very hard-to find the necessary numbers
at Stats. Canada but couldn't) I imagine it would be quite a bit higher; is
this just a way oof keeping the rate artificially low?
Thanks very much,
T. Scarth
[EMAIL PROTECTED]






[PEN-L:9825] overdetermination -- a sidetrack

1997-05-02 Thread James Devine

after quoting my remark on something Alan Freeman said, Marsh Feldman writes 
I don't think this gets quite out of the woods.

Marsh, I didn't know I was in the woods. More importantly, which woods am I
in (or do you think I'm in)? the overdeterminist/pomo woods? the
anti-overdeterminist/determinist woods? (the Evelyn woods? ;-)) 

First, your notion [or Alan's?] is very much like Roy Bhaskar's argument
for what he calls the transformative mode of social activity. Except for
Roy, not only does the past haunt the present, it also allows social
institutions to have emergent properties 
(their own causal efficacy) independent of any given individuals. 

I guess I agree with Bhaskar, but I was _not_ presenting anything but a
proposed limit on the role of overdetermination in understanding social
processes rather trying to present a _complete_ alternative to the RM
school. (Frankly, I find most of Bhaskar's stuff to be opaque, so I rely on
secondary sources like Dick Walker and Rajani Kanth.) 

BTW, I don't think that the idea that "social institutions to have emergent
properties 
(their own causal efficacy) independent of any given individuals"
contradicts the RM school. They reject methodological individualism, if my
memory serves me well. 

Second, to say something is overdetermined does not necessarily mean
everything
determines everything else -- including the present determining the past.

I was simply describing what I thought was RW's usage of the concept of
"overdetermination." My point was simply that there were clear limits to
that concept -- because the present cannot determine the past.  I was
hoping to get some insight into the RM school's response to this proposed
limit. 

All it [overdetermination] requires is multiple and contingent causes
such that a given outcome is neither necessary nor sufficient evidence of
any given cause. Here again I find Bhaskar much better than RW.

I would agree that critical realism thinking is superior to that of RW.
But again, I wasn't aiming to present a complete alternative to RW as much
as to have a civilized dialogue about one crucial detail of RW's vision of
social processes (I wasn't getting into their epistemology, for example).
It seemed a good time to have such a discussion because the organizers of
the RM conference on pen-l didn't want to dwell on that event any more. 

 RW seem to stop at overdetermination, whereas Bhaskar seems to start
there. His critical realist theory has us identifying specific causes and
their contingent interaction to explain why certain outcomes do or do not
appear. If, for example, we do not see a growing reserve army of labor
during a period of U.S. history, perhaps it's because gender relations
interact with class relations to undermine a tendency that
the latter, by itself, would foster. This is a far cry from
overdetermination since it explains the "overdetermined" (contingent)
outcome rather than hide it behind a 7-syllable word.

If I understand what you're saying correctly, I agree. Maybe we should have
a discussion of the limits of critical realism instead of discussing the
limits of overdetermination. I would like to know why the RM school is
critical of Bhaskar. (If I remember correctly, the footnote that mentions
Bhakskar in RW's KNOWLEDGE AND CLASS was merely dismissive.) But that
seems a much larger subject, one that is hard to discuss over pen-l. 

I think that the concept of overdetermination is important and useful for
understanding society, whether it comes from a RM or Bhaskarian direction.
But what are its limits?


in pen-l solidarity,

Jim Devine   [EMAIL PROTECTED]
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
Econ. Dept., Loyola Marymount Univ.
7900 Loyola Blvd., Los Angeles, CA 90045-8410 USA
310/338-2948 (daytime, during workweek); FAX: 310/338-1950
"Segui il tuo corso, e lascia dir le genti." (Go your own way
and let people talk.) -- K. Marx, paraphrasing Dante A.






[PEN-L:9829] ICFTU and Nike

1997-05-02 Thread D Shniad

 INTERNATIONAL CONFEDERATION OF FREE TRADE UNIONS (ICFTU)
 
 ICFTU ONLINE...
 110/970425
 
 INDONESIA AND VIETNAM: MORE ACCUSATIONS AGAINST NIKE
 
 Brussels, April 30, 1997 (ICFTU OnLine):  In a factory in the 
 outskirts of Jakarta which makes shoes for the US multinational 
 Nike, 10,000 workers demonstrated last Tuesday to demand an 
 immediate pay rise to reach to the minimum wage. The management 
 at the factory (PT Hardaya Aneka Shoes Industri) initially 
 refused, which led to stronger action by the workers.  The 
 factory was forced to close at the weekend and the management 
 finally agreed to pay the monthly minimum wage.
 In Vietnam, some 800 workers, mainly women, at the Korean Sam Yan 
 Co. factory, which also makes shoes for Nike, went on strike last 
 week to protest at their working conditions and wages.  
 In recent months several independent sources have denounced the 
 serious violations of workers' rights by the five Nike factories 
 in Vietnam (three South Korean and two Taiwanese).  Wages below 
 the legal minimum for the first three months, strictly controlled 
 access to toilet facilities,  a maximum of two glasses of water 
 per working day, verbal abuse, sexual harassment and corporal 
 punishment are all practices denounced in these factories.  A 
 supervisor at the Taiwanese factory Pou Chen Corp. found himself 
 before a Vietnamese tribunal at the end of March for forcing 56 
 women workers to run 4km around the factory for not wearing 
 regulation work shoes.  Twelve of the women workers had to be 
 taken to hospital.  It is the second time that a manager at a 
 factory working for Nike in Vietnam has been charged with 
 ill-treating women workers.  Last year, a supervisor at the 
 Korean Sam Yang Co. factory, a Nike sub-contractor, was convicted 
 for hitting his Vietnamese women employees over the head with a 
 shoe.
 Following the latest accusations, the Nike management simply 
 stated that it could not confirm the events but that it was 
 prepared to work with independent observers to examine and 
 improve working conditions in its overseas factories.  In 1992, 
 Nike adopted its own code of conduct, but did not agree to 
 independent monitoring.  Last year, Nike created its own 
 department responsible for supervising the application of its 
 code of conduct and charged former US ambassador Andrew Young 
 with studying and evaluating improvements to be made to the code 
 of conduct and supervisory mechanisms.  The Nike code of conduct 
 makes no mention of the freedom of association and the right to 
 collective bargaining.
 Only two weeks ago, Nike finally complied with the code of 
 conduct drawn up by the Clinton administration aimed at 
 eliminating exploitation in clothing factories.  The initiative 
 received a cautious welcome from the international trade union 
 movement, which points to the absence of monitoring mechanisms.  
 The latest revelations in the Nike factories in Vietnam and 
 Indonesia have underlined the need for such caution.
 "Given the increasing number of workers' rights violations by 
 Nike sub-contractors in recent months, it is hard to avoid the 
 conclusion that that the code of conduct policy is just a public 
 relations exercise" says Neil Kearney, General Secretary of the 
 international textile workers (ITGLWF).
 Nike's abundant profits (four billion dollars are forecast for 
 1997) are based on the huge profit marge between the cost of 
 producing the shoes and their sale price on the market.  To 
 safeguard its profit margin at all costs, Nike has transferred 
 production to the lowest wage coufntries and to those where 
 legislation gives the least protection for workers' rights.  Nike 
 wins every time.  Workers and consumers are the losers.
 For details contact ICFTU Press at ++322 224 02 12 or the 
 International Textile, Garment and Leather Workers' Federation 
 (ITGLWF) Tel.:++32-2-512-26-02. Other OnLine news on Poptel 
 Bulletin Board ICFTU-Online for geonet users and on the WWW 
 at:http://www.icftu.org