Re: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-23 Thread Marty Lederman
Apologies for the shameless self-promotion --

My contribution to the SCOTUSblog symposium is here:

http://www.scotusblog.com/2014/02/symposium-how-to-understand-hobby-lobby/

I also have a couple of recent new posts up on Balkinization, concerning
various matters in Hobby Lobby's brief; links to all my posts can be found
here:

http://balkin.blogspot.com/2014/02/compendium-of-posts-on-hobby-lobby-and.html




On Wed, Feb 19, 2014 at 10:32 PM, Marty Lederman
wrote:

> I have some further posts up on Balkinization.  More importantly, both
> Chip Lupu/Bob Tuttle and Doug Laycock have excellent posts up as part of
> the SCOTUSblog symposium, which I commend to all of you:
>
> Chip/Bob:
> http://www.scotusblog.com/2014/02/symposium-religious-questions-and-saving-constructions/
>
> Doug:
> http://www.scotusblog.com/2014/02/symposium-congress-answered-this-question-corporations-are-covered/
>
>
>
___
To post, send message to Religionlaw@lists.ucla.edu
To subscribe, unsubscribe, change options, or get password, see 
http://lists.ucla.edu/cgi-bin/mailman/listinfo/religionlaw

Please note that messages sent to this large list cannot be viewed as private.  
Anyone can subscribe to the list and read messages that are posted; people can 
read the Web archives; and list members can (rightly or wrongly) forward the 
messages to others.

RE: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-21 Thread Gaubatz, Derek
I don't find the proposition to be particularly comforting that religious 
liberty concerns must take a back seat in areas "highly regulated" by the 
government as opposed to "lightly regulated" ones.Instead, it seems to me 
that the need to vigorously protect free exercise of religion is of greater 
importance in those areas of life where government intrusion is higher.   More 
fundamentally, the view that the free exercise of religion matters less when 
the government has already occupied the regulatory space raises the question of 
where does the right to free exercise of religion come from at all.Is the 
protection of religious exercise just a gift of a positivist state that sees 
some utilitarian benefit in providing some of its citizens a right to practice 
religion?   (E.g., wouldn't it be quaint if our government allowed a few 
Mennonites-so long as they don't take their faith too seriously).Or does 
the government protect the free exercise of religion because it recognizes that 
following one's conscience in religious matters is something that is in the 
very nature of its people and is therefore a fundamental right that exists in 
all people prior to the state even existing?   Under the first view, what the 
state gives, the state can take away.   Under the second view, the power of the 
state is necessarily constrained by the existence of fundamental rights that 
inhere in the very nature of the people.   Yes, the government can limit 
exercise of religion in the second view, but only where it truly satisfies 
strict scrutiny; if the government exercises its power more broadly to limit 
free exercise of religion, it loses its legitimacy by denying its people the 
ability to live and act in accordance with something that makes them human in 
the first place-the ability to live and act in accordance with their 
religiously informed conscience.

On the substance, I would also disagree that Hobby Lobby and Conestoga have 
"ignored" the so-called Caldor / Establishment Clause problem of needing to 
avoid harm to 3rd parties.To the contrary, the briefs deal extensively with 
whether the alleged harm to 3rd parties-i.e., increasing the number of women 
who won't get free abortifacients /contraceptives--qualifies as a compelling 
government interest.   The briefs convincingly demonstrates that this doesn't 
qualify as a compelling government interest because the regulatory regime 
established by the government already allows for large numbers of women not to 
get free abortifacients /contraceptives from their employers (i.e., women in 
grandfathered plans, plans with employers who employ less than 50 employees, 
and plans with those employers the Administration (grudgingly) conceded were 
sufficiently religious).   Where so many exceptions to this interest already 
exist, this doesn't rise to the level of a compelling government interest.  
Moreover, the fact that other exceptions are given for non-religious reasons 
means that this is not a case in which an exception has been given for uniquely 
religious reasons, thereby further avoiding an Establishment Clause concern.

Grace and peace to you,
Derek L. Gaubatz
IMB General Counsel

Our vision is a multitude from every language, people, tribe and nation knowing 
and worshipping our Lord Jesus Christ.

From: religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu 
[mailto:religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu] On Behalf Of Ira Lupu
Sent: Thursday, February 20, 2014 8:27 PM
To: Law & Religion issues for Law Academics
Subject: Re: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

Mark Scarberry writes "We are on a slippery slope when we refer to someone as 
seeking to have "the government[] ... authorize [it] to act on religious 
beliefs in ways that harm others," when what is at stake is whether the 
government can force that person to do something for others in violation of 
religious conscience. This comes very close to saying that the government 
authorizes whatever it does not prohibit."

Mark's concern is very apt in a world of lightly regulated relationships 
between people who are not in a legally constructed relationship.  The 
government does not "authorize" me to be rude to my neighbors when it fails to 
prohibit the rudeness.  But the employment relation is a highly regulated 
contractual one, with all sorts of legal duties imposed on parties, especially 
on employers.  So if government prescribes terms for that relationship -- e.g., 
provide a safe workplace -- then an exemption from those terms is 
"authorization" to behave differently and alter the contract to the detriment 
of the other party.
The minimum coverages -- contraceptive and otherwise -- are now effectively 
part of the employment contract in firms with 50+ employees, and the only ways 
out are 1) keep your pre-ACA plan, or 2) pay the assessable payment for 
dropping or not obtaining cover

Re: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-21 Thread Ira Lupu
ndiana 46556-0780
>
> 574-631-6981 (w)
>
> 574-276-2252 (cell)
>
> rgarn...@nd.edu
>
>
>
> To download my scholarly papers, please visit my SSRN 
> page<http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/cf_dev/AbsByAuth.cfm?per_id=342235>
>
>
>
> Blogs:
>
>
>
> Prawfsblawg <http://prawfsblawg.blogs.com/>
>
> Mirror of Justice <http://mirrorofjustice.blogs.com/>
>
>
>
> Twitter:  @RickGarnett <https://twitter.com/RickGarnett>
>
>
>
> *From:* religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu [mailto:
> religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu] *On Behalf Of *Alan Brownstein
> *Sent:* Friday, February 21, 2014 1:22 AM
>
> *To:* Law & Religion issues for Law Academics
> *Subject:* RE: recommended Hobby Lobby posts
>
>
>
> These are very helpful responses, Chip. Let me try to use them to identify
> and clarify where I think we agree and disagree.
>
>
>
> 1. I agree that Religion is different and the Establishment Clause is part
> of what makes it different. The fact that free speech doctrine requires
> government to allow the exercise of a right even when doing so imposes
> substantial costs on third parties or the public does not mean that
> religious accommodations can impose a similar magnitude of costs on third
> parties or the public without violating the Establishment Clause. I also
> agree that the Establishment Clause limit is hard to identify, but it is
> certainly there and operates as a constraint on accommodations. But my
> example wasn't intended to suggest that the magnitude of costs acceptable
> in free speech cases parallels the magnitude of permissible costs for
> Establishment Clause purposes. My point was that the way we measure costs
> should operate the same way for both free speech and Establishment Clause
> purposes. In both cases, harm should be evaluated by determining the cost
> of mitigation, not by evaluating the cost of unmitigated consequences. If a
> religious group was going to engage in an unpopular ritual -- an animal
> sacrifice, for example -- and the state wanted to prohibit it from doing so
> to avoid disorder, property damage etc. caused by people who wanted to stop
> the ritual from happening, the state's interest in a RFRA type case should
> be measured in the same way it would be measured in a free speech case --
> by determining the cost of providing sufficient police to maintain order.
> Costs that are tolerated under the free speech clause may violate the
> Establishment Clause, but we ought to measure them the same way.
>
>
>
> 2. Here is where we disagree. I don't think the fact that the government
> is unwilling (or is too politically dysfunctional) to adopt a less
> restrictive alternative allows the state to satisfy strict scrutiny review
> by insisting that otherwise feasible less restrictive alternatives are not
> politically available. Consider my prior example about an unpopular
> speaker. Suppose the state asserts that it has a compelling state interest
> in avoiding the disorder that will result from the speaker's public speech.
> Assume further that a court determines that a less restrictive way to
> further that interest without silencing the speaker is to provide
> adequate police protection to the unpopular speaker to maintain order. I
> don't think the state's attorney can insist that it has to be allowed to
> silence the speaker because the city council would never authorize police
> overtime to protect a speaker with such odious views. I just don't see how
> a less restrictive alternative test can be meaningfully applied if
> political unwillingness to adopt a less restrictive alternative will be
> taken to mean that the less restrictive alternative is unavailable and
> should not be considered by courts.
>
>
>
> If the Court finds in favor of Hobby Lobby, I think it basically holds
> that if government wants to provide contraceptive insurance coverage for
> the employees of religious employers, it has to choose some way to do that
> other than by substantially burdening the religious liberty of the
> religious employers. I don't think that application of RFRA violates the
> Establishment Clause. I think it leaves the government with several policy
> choices that avoid violating the Establishment Clause. From a policy
> perspective, there is only one good choice -- providing an alternative
> source of insurance coverage. I think the other choices range from bad to
> terrible -- amending RFRA to exclude the contraceptive mandate, expanding
> RFRA to include non-religious objectors (which might mitigate Establishment
> Clause concerns), repealing the contraceptive mandate etc.  But I don't see
> how applying RFRA in a way that leaves the gover

RE: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-21 Thread Rick Garnett
Dear Alan and Chip -

Your conversation is (natch!) insightful and helpful.  For what it's worth, it 
is not clear to me (putting aside things the Supreme Court may or may not have 
said or meant) that either the Establishment Clause or whatever theories of 
church-state relations and religious-freedom-under-law our Constitution 
reflects disallow accommodations that "impose[] substantial costs on . . . the 
public."

Why should we regard it as an "establishment" of religion for the government to 
decide - that is, for (a majority-ish of) "us" to decide that it is "worth it" 
to structure an otherwise generally applicable regulatory-and-spending regime 
in such a way that its operation does not impose avoidable burdens on religious 
exercise, even when the "expense" the community is real?  (To ask this is 
different, it seems to me, than to ask about accommodations that take the form 
of lifting a burden from A and moving it, directly and particularly, to B.  I 
had understood the Gedicks et al. objection to Hobby Lobby's RFRA claim to be 
asking about these.)

I agree, certainly, that "religion is different" but it seems to me that this 
difference is reflected *both* through the rule against "establishments" (and I 
know we would disagree about precisely what constitutes an "establishment" and 
what does not) *and* through an admittedly not-uniform tradition (even if not 
through Free Exercise Clause doctrine) of accommodating religion, religious 
objections, and religious exercise when it's possible to do so.  In our 
tradition, I think, "religious freedom" is not just a private benefit - 
something that is conferred on particular beneficiaries - but also a public 
good - something we are, as a political community, allowed and even encouraged 
to pursue, promote, and if necessary pay for.  Do you disagree, or am I reading 
too much into Alan's mention of "the public"?

All the best,

Rick

Richard W. Garnett
Professor of Law and Concurrent Professor of Political Science
Director, Program on Church, State & Society
Notre Dame Law School
P.O. Box 780
Notre Dame, Indiana 46556-0780
574-631-6981 (w)
574-276-2252 (cell)
rgarn...@nd.edu<mailto:rgarn...@nd.edu>

To download my scholarly papers, please visit my SSRN 
page<http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/cf_dev/AbsByAuth.cfm?per_id=342235>

Blogs:

Prawfsblawg<http://prawfsblawg.blogs.com/>
Mirror of Justice<http://mirrorofjustice.blogs.com/>

Twitter:  @RickGarnett<https://twitter.com/RickGarnett>

From: religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu 
[mailto:religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu] On Behalf Of Alan Brownstein
Sent: Friday, February 21, 2014 1:22 AM
To: Law & Religion issues for Law Academics
Subject: RE: recommended Hobby Lobby posts


These are very helpful responses, Chip. Let me try to use them to identify and 
clarify where I think we agree and disagree.



1. I agree that Religion is different and the Establishment Clause is part of 
what makes it different. The fact that free speech doctrine requires government 
to allow the exercise of a right even when doing so imposes substantial costs 
on third parties or the public does not mean that religious accommodations can 
impose a similar magnitude of costs on third parties or the public without 
violating the Establishment Clause. I also agree that the Establishment Clause 
limit is hard to identify, but it is certainly there and operates as a 
constraint on accommodations. But my example wasn't intended to suggest that 
the magnitude of costs acceptable in free speech cases parallels the magnitude 
of permissible costs for Establishment Clause purposes. My point was that the 
way we measure costs should operate the same way for both free speech and 
Establishment Clause purposes. In both cases, harm should be evaluated by 
determining the cost of mitigation, not by evaluating the cost of unmitigated 
consequences. If a religious group was going to engage in an unpopular ritual 
-- an animal sacrifice, for example -- and the state wanted to prohibit it from 
doing so to avoid disorder, property damage etc. caused by people who wanted to 
stop the ritual from happening, the state's interest in a RFRA type case should 
be measured in the same way it would be measured in a free speech case -- by 
determining the cost of providing sufficient police to maintain order. Costs 
that are tolerated under the free speech clause may violate the Establishment 
Clause, but we ought to measure them the same way.



2. Here is where we disagree. I don't think the fact that the government is 
unwilling (or is too politically dysfunctional) to adopt a less restrictive 
alternative allows the state to satisfy strict scrutiny review by insisting 
that otherwise feasible less restrictive alternatives are not politically 
available. Consider my prior examp

RE: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-20 Thread Alan Brownstein
agree, I don't really 
consider the contraceptive mandate to be a regulation of employer-employee 
relations, like the employment discrimination provisions of Title VII or 
various labor law statutes.  I think the Affordable Care Act is a health 
insurance law, not an employer-employee relations law. Both the goal and the 
operational design of the Affordable Care Act are directed toward providing 
affordable health insurance to all Americans whether they are employed or not. 
Employers are used as a conduit to achieve that health insurance objective for 
some Americans-- but that is incidental to the ultimate purpose of the 
legislation which is aimed at all Americans, not just employees. If the 
contraceptive mandate is viewed as a part of the massive government involvement 
in arranging for the provision of affordable health care, at least some of 
which -- through the expansion of Medicaid -- involves the government providing 
health care coverage directly, it doesn't seem particularly assymetrical to me 
to suggest that the government itself should shoulder the burden of providing 
contraceptive insurance coverage to the employees of religious employers.



Alan





From: religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu [religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu] 
on behalf of Ira Lupu [icl...@law.gwu.edu]
Sent: Thursday, February 20, 2014 3:44 PM
To: Law & Religion issues for Law Academics
Subject: Re: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

Very good questions, Alan. Three replies (in reverse order of your questions):

1.  Other rights contexts (like free speech) where third party costs are 
present -- Religion is different.  The Establishment Clause is a limit on the 
government's power to authorize one party to act on religious beliefs in ways 
that harm others.   Government vigorously protects labor speech in the 
workplace, even though it may lead workers to unionize and cost employers money 
(way more than de minimis in some cases).   But Thornton v. Caldor explicitly, 
and the Title VII line of cases about religious accommodation (in these, 
implicitly) impose limits on the power of A to shift costs to B to protect A's 
religious commitments.

2.  Less restrictive means (and the power of government to provide 
contraceptive services directly to employees of firms that refuse to insure for 
coverage of those services).  If Hobby Lobby wins, its female employees, and 
the female dependents of all employees, will lose the controverted coverage.  
For some of them, that will mean they cannot afford the safest and most 
effective contraception (perhaps a hormonal IUD, close to $1000 initial 
outlay).  That the government can/might/should fill the gap for these employees 
cannot be a sufficient reason to accept Hobby Lobby's RFRA claim, because the 
government may very well NOT fill the gap. Imagine the politics of the 
gap-filling legislation -- a public option, government financed, for 
contraceptives that some people believe are abortifacients.  Likely to be 
enacted sometime soon?  And if government does not fill that gap, then these 
women and others similarly situated take the full brunt of the loss.   They 
will not have the coverage that, within a few years, almost every woman in the 
U.S. will have. That consequence presents a serious Establishment Clause 
problem, and RFRA should be construed to avoid it.

3.  Why de minimis?  Why not allow even more than de minimis cost-shifting when 
the burden on the objecting company or its owners is substantial?  As we know 
from Caldor, Cutter, Texas Monthly, and Amos, the lines here are not bright.  
How much cost-shifting is more than the Establishment Clause will tolerate is a 
matter of degree.  The beauty of "de minimis" as the line is 1) it comes from a 
relevant body of law, related to employer-employee relations,  2) it therefore 
arrives with legal momentum and quantitative precedent; and 3) it offers 
symmetry between employees and employers re: how much cost each can impose on 
the other.  (Alan, you might prefer the Title VII standard for religious 
accommodation to be more generous to employees than "de minimis."  But that's 
not the law.)

Chip


On Thu, Feb 20, 2014 at 4:26 PM, Alan Brownstein 
mailto:aebrownst...@ucdavis.edu>> wrote:
With regard to Jim’s post (and Chip and Bob’s piece), I appreciate the argument 
that in employment cases RFRA should be interpreted the same way that Title VII 
has been interpreted  --- essentially denying all RFRA claims that would impose 
more than  de minimis costs on third parties or the public. But I have several 
questions about it.

First, if we accept Chip and Bob’s argument that accommodating Hobby Lobby 
would impose significant and serious costs on third parties, resolving this 
case against Hobby Lobby doesn’t require an interpretation of RFRA that is as 
limiting as the one that they propose.  Aren’t there harms that are more th

Re: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-20 Thread Ira Lupu
Mark Scarberry writes "We are on a slippery slope when we refer to someone
as seeking to have "the government[] ... authorize [it] to act on religious
beliefs in ways that harm others," when what is at stake is whether the
government can force that person to do something for others in violation of
religious conscience. This comes very close to saying that the government
authorizes whatever it does not prohibit."

Mark's concern is very apt in a world of lightly regulated relationships
between people who are not in a legally constructed relationship.  The
government does not "authorize" me to be rude to my neighbors when it fails
to prohibit the rudeness.  But the employment relation is a highly
regulated contractual one, with all sorts of legal duties imposed on
parties, especially on employers.  So if government prescribes terms for
that relationship -- e.g., provide a safe workplace -- then an exemption
from those terms is "authorization" to behave differently and alter the
contract to the detriment of the other party.
The minimum coverages -- contraceptive and otherwise -- are now effectively
part of the employment contract in firms with 50+ employees, and the only
ways out are 1) keep your pre-ACA plan, or 2) pay the assessable payment
for dropping or not obtaining coverage. (If you do the latter, your
employees can buy coverage on the exchanges, and they will get all the
coverages.)  An exemption from these minimum coverages "authorizes"
employers to do something different, and thereby deprive their employees of
the minimum coverages through either employment or purchase on the
exchanges.  The "grandfather" exemption, whatever else we say about it
(such as its design as a transition rule), also authorizes deprivation of
coverages, but NOT as a result of religious belief.  The Establishment
Clause limits the power of government to authorize employers to deprive
employees of minimum coverages (or other statutorily mandatory terms of the
employment relation) for reasons of employer religious belief.  (Maybe Mark
and others think Caldor is wrong; but if it's right, there is an
Establishment Clause problem here, and it doesn't go away just because
Hobby Lobby and Conestoga Wood have ignored it in the litigation thus far.)


On Thu, Feb 20, 2014 at 7:01 PM, Scarberry, Mark <
mark.scarbe...@pepperdine.edu> wrote:

> Two quick points before I have to prepare for class:
>
>
>
> We are on a slippery slope when we refer to someone as seeking to have
> "the government[] ... authorize [it] to act on religious beliefs in ways that
> harm others," when what is at stake is whether the government can force
> that person to do something for others in violation of religious
> conscience. This comes very close to saying that the government authorizes
> whatever it does not prohibit.
>
>
>
> Political considerations should play no role when we ask whether the
> government has another way to advance its interests. Regardless of whether
> the people or their representatives would choose to use that other way, it
> must be treated as available for purposes of constitutional analysis. The
> choice not to use it may show that the government is not terribly committed
> to advancing the particular interest that is at stake, but in any event a
> refusal of the government (a government by the people, right?) to utilize a
> means of furthering its interests is not a reason for limiting the freedoms
> of those who do not want to be used to advance that interest. The costs of
> using the alternative may be relevant, but the refusal of the people to
> authorize its use is not.
>
>
>
> Mark
>
>
>
> Mark S. Scarberry
>
> Professor of Law
>
> Pepperdine Univ. School of Law
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
> *From:* religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu [mailto:
> religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu] *On Behalf Of *Ira Lupu
> *Sent:* Thursday, February 20, 2014 3:44 PM
>
> *To:* Law & Religion issues for Law Academics
> *Subject:* Re: recommended Hobby Lobby posts
>
>
>
> Very good questions, Alan. Three replies (in reverse order of your
> questions):
>
>
>
> 1.  Other rights contexts (like free speech) where third party costs are
> present -- Religion is different.  The Establishment Clause is a limit on
> the government's power to authorize one party to act on religious beliefs
> in ways that harm others.   Government vigorously protects labor speech in
> the workplace, even though it may lead workers to unionize and cost
> employers money (way more than de minimis in some cases).   But Thornton v.
> Caldor explicitly, and the Title VII line of cases about religious
> accommodation (in these, implicitly) impose limits on the power of A to
> shif

Re: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-20 Thread Greg Lipper
I agree with Chip about the political realities of a public option. Even if 
that option were politically viable, I don’t see how the public option can be 
considered a less restrictive alternative in cases dealing with exemptions from 
regulations.

Employers have previously brought free exercise challenges to things like 
federal minimum wage laws and equal pay laws. Those challenges have been 
rejected. But if an employer has a religious objection to paying the minimum 
wage, the government could step in and pay a salary supplement. If an employer 
has a religious objection to paying women as much as men, the government could 
step in and make up the difference directly. United States v. Lee would have 
also come out differently – the government could have chipped in the missing 
social security payments there, too.

And so on and so on: virtually every regulation governing health, safety, wage, 
working conditions – any regulation that requires a private party to do 
something – could be rewritten so that the government performs the action 
itself. If the “public option” is considered to be a less restrictive 
alternative, then we’re in a world of state-run everything.


On Feb 20, 2014, at 7:01 PM, Scarberry, Mark 
mailto:mark.scarbe...@pepperdine.edu>> wrote:

Two quick points before I have to prepare for class:

We are on a slippery slope when we refer to someone as seeking to have “the 
government[] … authorize [it] to act on religious beliefs in ways that harm 
others,” when what is at stake is whether the government can force that person 
to do something for others in violation of religious conscience. This comes 
very close to saying that the government authorizes whatever it does not 
prohibit.

Political considerations should play no role when we ask whether the government 
has another way to advance its interests. Regardless of whether the people or 
their representatives would choose to use that other way, it must be treated as 
available for purposes of constitutional analysis. The choice not to use it may 
show that the government is not terribly committed to advancing the particular 
interest that is at stake, but in any event a refusal of the government (a 
government by the people, right?) to utilize a means of furthering its 
interests is not a reason for limiting the freedoms of those who do not want to 
be used to advance that interest. The costs of using the alternative may be 
relevant, but the refusal of the people to authorize its use is not.

Mark

Mark S. Scarberry
Professor of Law
Pepperdine Univ. School of Law





From: 
religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu<mailto:religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu> 
[mailto:religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu] On Behalf Of Ira Lupu
Sent: Thursday, February 20, 2014 3:44 PM
To: Law & Religion issues for Law Academics
Subject: Re: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

Very good questions, Alan. Three replies (in reverse order of your questions):

1.  Other rights contexts (like free speech) where third party costs are 
present -- Religion is different.  The Establishment Clause is a limit on the 
government's power to authorize one party to act on religious beliefs in ways 
that harm others.   Government vigorously protects labor speech in the 
workplace, even though it may lead workers to unionize and cost employers money 
(way more than de minimis in some cases).   But Thornton v. Caldor explicitly, 
and the Title VII line of cases about religious accommodation (in these, 
implicitly) impose limits on the power of A to shift costs to B to protect A's 
religious commitments.

2.  Less restrictive means (and the power of government to provide 
contraceptive services directly to employees of firms that refuse to insure for 
coverage of those services).  If Hobby Lobby wins, its female employees, and 
the female dependents of all employees, will lose the controverted coverage.  
For some of them, that will mean they cannot afford the safest and most 
effective contraception (perhaps a hormonal IUD, close to $1000 initial 
outlay).  That the government can/might/should fill the gap for these employees 
cannot be a sufficient reason to accept Hobby Lobby's RFRA claim, because the 
government may very well NOT fill the gap. Imagine the politics of the 
gap-filling legislation -- a public option, government financed, for 
contraceptives that some people believe are abortifacients.  Likely to be 
enacted sometime soon?  And if government does not fill that gap, then these 
women and others similarly situated take the full brunt of the loss.   They 
will not have the coverage that, within a few years, almost every woman in the 
U.S. will have. That consequence presents a serious Establishment Clause 
problem, and RFRA should be construed to avoid it.

3.  Why de minimis?  Why not allow even more than de minimis cost-shifting when 
the burden on the objecting company or its owners is substantial?  As we know 
from Caldor, Cutte

RE: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-20 Thread Scarberry, Mark
Two quick points before I have to prepare for class:

We are on a slippery slope when we refer to someone as seeking to have "the 
government[] ... authorize [it] to act on religious beliefs in ways that harm 
others," when what is at stake is whether the government can force that person 
to do something for others in violation of religious conscience. This comes 
very close to saying that the government authorizes whatever it does not 
prohibit.

Political considerations should play no role when we ask whether the government 
has another way to advance its interests. Regardless of whether the people or 
their representatives would choose to use that other way, it must be treated as 
available for purposes of constitutional analysis. The choice not to use it may 
show that the government is not terribly committed to advancing the particular 
interest that is at stake, but in any event a refusal of the government (a 
government by the people, right?) to utilize a means of furthering its 
interests is not a reason for limiting the freedoms of those who do not want to 
be used to advance that interest. The costs of using the alternative may be 
relevant, but the refusal of the people to authorize its use is not.

Mark

Mark S. Scarberry
Professor of Law
Pepperdine Univ. School of Law





From: religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu 
[mailto:religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu] On Behalf Of Ira Lupu
Sent: Thursday, February 20, 2014 3:44 PM
To: Law & Religion issues for Law Academics
Subject: Re: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

Very good questions, Alan. Three replies (in reverse order of your questions):

1.  Other rights contexts (like free speech) where third party costs are 
present -- Religion is different.  The Establishment Clause is a limit on the 
government's power to authorize one party to act on religious beliefs in ways 
that harm others.   Government vigorously protects labor speech in the 
workplace, even though it may lead workers to unionize and cost employers money 
(way more than de minimis in some cases).   But Thornton v. Caldor explicitly, 
and the Title VII line of cases about religious accommodation (in these, 
implicitly) impose limits on the power of A to shift costs to B to protect A's 
religious commitments.

2.  Less restrictive means (and the power of government to provide 
contraceptive services directly to employees of firms that refuse to insure for 
coverage of those services).  If Hobby Lobby wins, its female employees, and 
the female dependents of all employees, will lose the controverted coverage.  
For some of them, that will mean they cannot afford the safest and most 
effective contraception (perhaps a hormonal IUD, close to $1000 initial 
outlay).  That the government can/might/should fill the gap for these employees 
cannot be a sufficient reason to accept Hobby Lobby's RFRA claim, because the 
government may very well NOT fill the gap. Imagine the politics of the 
gap-filling legislation -- a public option, government financed, for 
contraceptives that some people believe are abortifacients.  Likely to be 
enacted sometime soon?  And if government does not fill that gap, then these 
women and others similarly situated take the full brunt of the loss.   They 
will not have the coverage that, within a few years, almost every woman in the 
U.S. will have. That consequence presents a serious Establishment Clause 
problem, and RFRA should be construed to avoid it.

3.  Why de minimis?  Why not allow even more than de minimis cost-shifting when 
the burden on the objecting company or its owners is substantial?  As we know 
from Caldor, Cutter, Texas Monthly, and Amos, the lines here are not bright.  
How much cost-shifting is more than the Establishment Clause will tolerate is a 
matter of degree.  The beauty of "de minimis" as the line is 1) it comes from a 
relevant body of law, related to employer-employee relations,  2) it therefore 
arrives with legal momentum and quantitative precedent; and 3) it offers 
symmetry between employees and employers re: how much cost each can impose on 
the other.  (Alan, you might prefer the Title VII standard for religious 
accommodation to be more generous to employees than "de minimis."  But that's 
not the law.)

Chip

On Thu, Feb 20, 2014 at 4:26 PM, Alan Brownstein 
mailto:aebrownst...@ucdavis.edu>> wrote:
With regard to Jim's post (and Chip and Bob's piece), I appreciate the argument 
that in employment cases RFRA should be interpreted the same way that Title VII 
has been interpreted  --- essentially denying all RFRA claims that would impose 
more than  de minimis costs on third parties or the public. But I have several 
questions about it.

First, if we accept Chip and Bob's argument that accommodating Hobby Lobby 
would impose significant and serious costs on third parties, resolving this 
case against Hobby Lobby doesn't require an interpretation of 

Re: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-20 Thread Ira Lupu
Very good questions, Alan. Three replies (in reverse order of your
questions):

1.  Other rights contexts (like free speech) where third party costs are
present -- Religion is different.  The Establishment Clause is a limit on
the government's power to authorize one party to act on religious beliefs
in ways that harm others.   Government vigorously protects labor speech in
the workplace, even though it may lead workers to unionize and cost
employers money (way more than de minimis in some cases).   But Thornton v.
Caldor explicitly, and the Title VII line of cases about religious
accommodation (in these, implicitly) impose limits on the power of A to
shift costs to B to protect A's religious commitments.

2.  Less restrictive means (and the power of government to provide
contraceptive services directly to employees of firms that refuse to insure
for coverage of those services).  If Hobby Lobby wins, its female
employees, and the female dependents of all employees, will lose the
controverted coverage.  For some of them, that will mean they cannot afford
the safest and most effective contraception (perhaps a hormonal IUD, close
to $1000 initial outlay).  That the government can/might/should fill the
gap for these employees cannot be a sufficient reason to accept Hobby
Lobby's RFRA claim, because the government may very well NOT fill the gap.
Imagine the politics of the gap-filling legislation -- a public option,
government financed, for contraceptives that some people believe are
abortifacients.  Likely to be enacted sometime soon?  And if government
does not fill that gap, then these women and others similarly situated take
the full brunt of the loss.   They will not have the coverage that, within
a few years, almost every woman in the U.S. will have. That consequence
presents a serious Establishment Clause problem, and RFRA should be
construed to avoid it.

3.  Why de minimis?  Why not allow even more than de minimis cost-shifting
when the burden on the objecting company or its owners is substantial?  As
we know from Caldor, Cutter, Texas Monthly, and Amos, the lines here are
not bright.  How much cost-shifting is more than the Establishment Clause
will tolerate is a matter of degree.  The beauty of "de minimis" as the
line is 1) it comes from a relevant body of law, related to
employer-employee relations,  2) it therefore arrives with legal momentum
and quantitative precedent; and 3) it offers symmetry between employees and
employers re: how much cost each can impose on the other.  (Alan, you might
prefer the Title VII standard for religious accommodation to be more
generous to employees than "de minimis."  But that's not the law.)

Chip


On Thu, Feb 20, 2014 at 4:26 PM, Alan Brownstein
wrote:

>  With regard to Jim's post (and Chip and Bob's piece), I appreciate the
> argument that in employment cases RFRA should be interpreted the same way
> that Title VII has been interpreted  --- essentially denying all RFRA
> claims that would impose more than  de minimis costs on third parties or
> the public. But I have several questions about it.
>
>
>
> First, if we accept Chip and Bob's argument that accommodating Hobby Lobby
> would impose significant and serious costs on third parties, resolving this
> case against Hobby Lobby doesn't require an interpretation of RFRA that is
> as limiting as the one that they propose.  Aren't there harms that are more
> than de minimis, yet not sufficiently costly to justify the substantial
> burdening of religious liberty?
>
>
>
> Second, exactly why should the scope of RFRA be so drastically constrained
> in employment cases? What  distinguishes these kinds of cases from other
> accommodation cases - many of which will also impose some costs on third
> parties, the state, or the general public?
>
>
>
> Third, many commentators have argued that the cost of accommodating Hobby
> Lobby should be construed to be the cost of the government setting up an
> alternative insurance framework for providing contraceptive coverage for
> the employees of religiously exempt employers. The literal cost of doing so
> may not be very high. There are ways of conditioning the granting of any
> accommodation to offset whatever those costs may be to a considerable
> extent. Providing insurance coverage would not require administratively
> complex, individualized interventions by the government. And, for many of
> us, the government providing health care coverage is the most desirable and
> efficient way of extending health insurance coverage in our society in the
> first place. The use of employers as a conduit for providing coverage
> provides few if any advantages in comparison to a government insurance
> program. So if we are focusing on the cost of accommodating Hobby Lobby,
> why isn't this the cost we should be evaluating.
>
>
>
> Typically in other rights contexts, we focus on the cost of mitigation,
> not the potential harm of unmitigated consequences. Thus, if an unpopular
> speaker wa

Re: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-20 Thread Marty Lederman
Alan:  I'll let Chip speak for himself, but I don't think the relevant
distinction is so much between employment cases and all others as it is
between cases *in the commercial sector *(especially claims brought by
for-profit enterprises) and all others.  In *Piggie Park*, for example, the
harm was borne by customers, not employees, but the result was the same.




On Thu, Feb 20, 2014 at 4:26 PM, Alan Brownstein
wrote:

>  With regard to Jim's post (and Chip and Bob's piece), I appreciate the
> argument that in employment cases RFRA should be interpreted the same way
> that Title VII has been interpreted  --- essentially denying all RFRA
> claims that would impose more than  de minimis costs on third parties or
> the public. But I have several questions about it.
>
>
>
> First, if we accept Chip and Bob's argument that accommodating Hobby Lobby
> would impose significant and serious costs on third parties, resolving this
> case against Hobby Lobby doesn't require an interpretation of RFRA that is
> as limiting as the one that they propose.  Aren't there harms that are more
> than de minimis, yet not sufficiently costly to justify the substantial
> burdening of religious liberty?
>
>
>
> Second, exactly why should the scope of RFRA be so drastically constrained
> in employment cases? What  distinguishes these kinds of cases from other
> accommodation cases - many of which will also impose some costs on third
> parties, the state, or the general public?
>
>
>
> Third, many commentators have argued that the cost of accommodating Hobby
> Lobby should be construed to be the cost of the government setting up an
> alternative insurance framework for providing contraceptive coverage for
> the employees of religiously exempt employers. The literal cost of doing so
> may not be very high. There are ways of conditioning the granting of any
> accommodation to offset whatever those costs may be to a considerable
> extent. Providing insurance coverage would not require administratively
> complex, individualized interventions by the government. And, for many of
> us, the government providing health care coverage is the most desirable and
> efficient way of extending health insurance coverage in our society in the
> first place. The use of employers as a conduit for providing coverage
> provides few if any advantages in comparison to a government insurance
> program. So if we are focusing on the cost of accommodating Hobby Lobby,
> why isn't this the cost we should be evaluating.
>
>
>
> Typically in other rights contexts, we focus on the cost of mitigation,
> not the potential harm of unmitigated consequences. Thus, if an unpopular
> speaker wants to speak in a location where his message is likely to poorly
> received, the government cannot silence the speaker on the grounds that
> allowing him to speak would cause disorder and damage to property or
> persons. Instead, the harm would be the cost of hiring sufficient police
> and public safety personnel to maintain order at the event. Typically,
> except in the most egregious cases, the government does not have a
> compelling state interest in avoiding those financial costs of mitigation.
>
>
>
> Alan
>
>
>
> On a different note, I want to second Marty's recommendation of the
> symposium over at SCOTUS Blog. Specifically, I highly recommend folks take
> a look at Chip and Bob's piece, which makes an important argument calling
> for symmetry between the treatment of employee accommodations under Title
> VII and employer accommodations under RFRA (in both cases this avoids
> establishment concerns raised by exemptions that impose more than de
> minimis burdens on others). Chip and Bob's piece is available here:
> http://www.scotusblog.com/2014/02/symposium-religious-questions-and-saving-constructions/
>
>
> - Jim
>
>
>
> ___
> To post, send message to Religionlaw@lists.ucla.edu
> To subscribe, unsubscribe, change options, or get password, see
> http://lists.ucla.edu/cgi-bin/mailman/listinfo/religionlaw
>
> Please note that messages sent to this large list cannot be viewed as
> private.  Anyone can subscribe to the list and read messages that are
> posted; people can read the Web archives; and list members can (rightly or
> wrongly) forward the messages to others.
>
___
To post, send message to Religionlaw@lists.ucla.edu
To subscribe, unsubscribe, change options, or get password, see 
http://lists.ucla.edu/cgi-bin/mailman/listinfo/religionlaw

Please note that messages sent to this large list cannot be viewed as private.  
Anyone can subscribe to the list and read messages that are posted; people can 
read the Web archives; and list members can (rightly or wrongly) forward the 
messages to others.

RE: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-20 Thread Alan Brownstein
With regard to Jim's post (and Chip and Bob's piece), I appreciate the argument 
that in employment cases RFRA should be interpreted the same way that Title VII 
has been interpreted  --- essentially denying all RFRA claims that would impose 
more than  de minimis costs on third parties or the public. But I have several 
questions about it.

First, if we accept Chip and Bob's argument that accommodating Hobby Lobby 
would impose significant and serious costs on third parties, resolving this 
case against Hobby Lobby doesn't require an interpretation of RFRA that is as 
limiting as the one that they propose.  Aren't there harms that are more than 
de minimis, yet not sufficiently costly to justify the substantial burdening of 
religious liberty?

Second, exactly why should the scope of RFRA be so drastically constrained in 
employment cases? What  distinguishes these kinds of cases from other 
accommodation cases - many of which will also impose some costs on third 
parties, the state, or the general public?

Third, many commentators have argued that the cost of accommodating Hobby Lobby 
should be construed to be the cost of the government setting up an alternative 
insurance framework for providing contraceptive coverage for the employees of 
religiously exempt employers. The literal cost of doing so may not be very 
high. There are ways of conditioning the granting of any accommodation to 
offset whatever those costs may be to a considerable extent. Providing 
insurance coverage would not require administratively complex, individualized 
interventions by the government. And, for many of us, the government providing 
health care coverage is the most desirable and efficient way of extending 
health insurance coverage in our society in the first place. The use of 
employers as a conduit for providing coverage provides few if any advantages in 
comparison to a government insurance program. So if we are focusing on the cost 
of accommodating Hobby Lobby, why isn't this the cost we should be evaluating.

Typically in other rights contexts, we focus on the cost of mitigation, not the 
potential harm of unmitigated consequences. Thus, if an unpopular speaker wants 
to speak in a location where his message is likely to poorly received, the 
government cannot silence the speaker on the grounds that allowing him to speak 
would cause disorder and damage to property or persons. Instead, the harm would 
be the cost of hiring sufficient police and public safety personnel to maintain 
order at the event. Typically, except in the most egregious cases, the 
government does not have a compelling state interest in avoiding those 
financial costs of mitigation.

Alan

On a different note, I want to second Marty's recommendation of the symposium 
over at SCOTUS Blog. Specifically, I highly recommend folks take a look at Chip 
and Bob's piece, which makes an important argument calling for symmetry between 
the treatment of employee accommodations under Title VII and employer 
accommodations under RFRA (in both cases this avoids establishment concerns 
raised by exemptions that impose more than de minimis burdens on others). Chip 
and Bob's piece is available here: 
http://www.scotusblog.com/2014/02/symposium-religious-questions-and-saving-constructions/

- Jim

___
To post, send message to Religionlaw@lists.ucla.edu
To subscribe, unsubscribe, change options, or get password, see 
http://lists.ucla.edu/cgi-bin/mailman/listinfo/religionlaw

Please note that messages sent to this large list cannot be viewed as private.  
Anyone can subscribe to the list and read messages that are posted; people can 
read the Web archives; and list members can (rightly or wrongly) forward the 
messages to others.

RE: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-20 Thread Douglas Laycock
I assume that Marci wasn’t there for the floor debate. There were many 
statements, they were very explicit, both sides agreed. Corporations would be 
covered based on the religious views of their owners or senior management. What 
takes a tortured reading is not to take those statements at face value.

 

Douglas Laycock

Robert E. Scott Distinguished Professor of Law

University of Virginia Law School

580 Massie Road

Charlottesville, VA  22903

 434-243-8546

 

From: religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu 
[mailto:religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu] On Behalf Of Marci Hamilton
Sent: Thursday, February 20, 2014 1:49 PM
To: Law & Religion issues for Law Academics
Cc: Law & Religion issues for Law Academics
Subject: Re: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

 

As someone who was involved in RLPA in Congress from day one through many 
hearings, only a tortured reading of history supports the notion that Congress 
believed that its proponents believed RFRA should apply to for-profit 
organizations let alone that they intended it to. 

 

 Given current deadlines I cannot add more , but I look forward to reading 
Jim's piece and will be doing something of my own closer to the argument.

 

Marci

 

 


Marci A. Hamilton

Verkuil Chair in Public Law

Benjamin N. Cardozo Law School

Yeshiva University

@Marci_Hamilton 

 

 


On Feb 20, 2014, at 12:34 PM, James Oleske mailto:jole...@lclark.edu> > wrote:

I have a short essay coming out next month that offers a considerably different 
take than Doug on both the legislative history of RLPA and the text of the 1999 
version of RLPA as compared to RFRA. A draft of the essay is available here:

Obamacare, RFRA, and the Perils of Legislative History
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2398763

 

The relevant discussion can be found on pages 5-10 of the draft. My bottom-line 
conclusion is that "the 1998 and 1999 debates over RLPA fall far short of 
demonstrating an 'undisputed public understanding that the language in RFRA 
protected for-profit corporations and their owners.'" 

On the specific claim that the text of RFRA and RLPA were identical, I make the 
same point I see Marty has made in his separate response to Doug -- the 1999 
RLPA has a "broad construction" provision that was in neither the 1998 RLPA or 
RFRA. Thus, the more relevant RLPA legislative history is the 1998 debate, not 
the 1999 debate Doug relies upon in the CLS amicus brief and his SCOTUS Blog 
post. And the 1998 testimony casts considerable doubt on the claim that large 
for-profit businesses are protected by RFRA.  

 

On a different note, I want to second Marty's recommendation of the symposium 
over at SCOTUS Blog. Specifically, I highly recommend folks take a look at Chip 
and Bob's piece, which makes an important argument calling for symmetry between 
the treatment of employee accommodations under Title VII and employer 
accommodations under RFRA (in both cases this avoids establishment concerns 
raised by exemptions that impose more than de minimis burdens on others). Chip 
and Bob's piece is available here: 
http://www.scotusblog.com/2014/02/symposium-religious-questions-and-saving-constructions/


- Jim

 

On Thu, Feb 20, 2014 at 7:30 AM, Douglas Laycock mailto:dlayc...@virginia.edu> > wrote:

I have not gone back to review all the RLPA testimony, but yes we did predict 
that large commercial businesses seeking religious exemptions from civil rights 
laws would generally lose.

 

The context of that testimony was civil rights claims. And it was a prediction 
of what the courts would do in fact, not a judgment about what they should do. 
But I would probably be comfortable with most of the results we predicted.

 

The kinds of civil rights claims RLPA’s supporters wanted to preserve mostly 
did not arise in business situations. Religious discrimination by religious 
organizations setting their criteria for membership, as in CLS v. Martinez, is 
rarely a legitimate business interest. Sex and marital-status discrimination in 
the ordination of a celibate male clergy is not a business interest. 

 

The existing examples at the time were the landlord-tenant cases, all of which 
involved small landlords. People could envision issues with kosher butchers and 
Christian bookstores, and with the broad reach of some state civil rights laws. 
Some state laws prohibit discrimination on the basis of “any lawful off-the-job 
activity.” Think the church secretary moonlighting in an abortion clinic, or a 
strip club, or any other business that is lawful but disreputable in the view 
of some. 

Same-sex marriage was on the far horizon; I don’t recall anyone thinking about 
wedding photographers and the like. 

 

I believed that as the business grows, it becomes less plausible to view it as 
a personal extension of the owner. Mrs. Smith with two duplexes may feel 
morally responsible for every unit, and she may be doing all the work o

Re: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-20 Thread Marty Lederman
A clarification of my own view on this question:  I doubt many members of
Congress in 1998/99 -- let alone in 1993 -- gave any thought at all to the
question of whether large, for-profit companies and/or their owners or
directors could *bring a claim *under RFRA/RLPA.  But I imagine Doug is
right that the vast majority, if asked, would have assumed the answer was
"yes."  Even so, what seems even more certain is that no such enterprise
had ever *prevailed *under RFRA or the FEC, and therefore, virtually all
members of Congress would have shared Doug's view in his testimony that
such enterprises *would virtually never ever prevail*, even if they got
into court.  Indeed, the whole point of the effort of Doug and others
(including some of us in the executive branch) was to reassure the uneasy
members of Congress that the bill, even as amended, would not change the
historical norm.




On Thu, Feb 20, 2014 at 1:49 PM, Marci Hamilton  wrote:

> As someone who was involved in RLPA in Congress from day one through many
> hearings, only a tortured reading of history supports the notion that
> Congress believed that its proponents believed RFRA should apply to
> for-profit organizations let alone that they intended it to.
>
>  Given current deadlines I cannot add more , but I look forward to reading
> Jim's piece and will be doing something of my own closer to the argument.
>
> Marci
>
>
>
> Marci A. Hamilton
> Verkuil Chair in Public Law
> Benjamin N. Cardozo Law School
> Yeshiva University
> @Marci_Hamilton
>
>
>
> On Feb 20, 2014, at 12:34 PM, James Oleske  wrote:
>
> I have a short essay coming out next month that offers a considerably
> different take than Doug on both the legislative history of RLPA and the
> text of the 1999 version of RLPA as compared to RFRA. A draft of the essay
> is available here:
>
> Obamacare, RFRA, and the Perils of Legislative History
> http://ssrn.com/abstract=2398763
>
> The relevant discussion can be found on pages 5-10 of the draft. My
> bottom-line conclusion is that "the 1998 and 1999 debates over RLPA fall
> far short of demonstrating an 'undisputed public understanding that the
> language in RFRA protected for-profit corporations and their owners.'"
>
> On the specific claim that the text of RFRA and RLPA were identical, I
> make the same point I see Marty has made in his separate response to Doug
> -- the 1999 RLPA has a "broad construction" provision that was in neither
> the 1998 RLPA or RFRA. Thus, the more relevant RLPA legislative history is
> the 1998 debate, not the 1999 debate Doug relies upon in the CLS amicus
> brief and his SCOTUS Blog post. And the 1998 testimony casts considerable
> doubt on the claim that large for-profit businesses are protected by RFRA.
>
> On a different note, I want to second Marty's recommendation of the
> symposium over at SCOTUS Blog. Specifically, I highly recommend folks take
> a look at Chip and Bob's piece, which makes an important argument calling
> for symmetry between the treatment of employee accommodations under Title
> VII and employer accommodations under RFRA (in both cases this avoids
> establishment concerns raised by exemptions that impose more than de
> minimis burdens on others). Chip and Bob's piece is available here:
> http://www.scotusblog.com/2014/02/symposium-religious-questions-and-saving-constructions/
>
> - Jim
>
> On Thu, Feb 20, 2014 at 7:30 AM, Douglas Laycock wrote:
>
>> I have not gone back to review all the RLPA testimony, but yes we did
>> predict that large commercial businesses seeking religious exemptions from
>> civil rights laws would generally lose.
>>
>>
>>
>> The context of that testimony was civil rights claims. And it was a
>> prediction of what the courts would do in fact, not a judgment about what
>> they should do. But I would probably be comfortable with most of the
>> results we predicted.
>>
>>
>>
>> The kinds of civil rights claims RLPA's supporters wanted to preserve
>> mostly did not arise in business situations. Religious discrimination by
>> religious organizations setting their criteria for membership, as in *CLS
>> v. Martinez*, is rarely a legitimate business interest. Sex and
>> marital-status discrimination in the ordination of a celibate male clergy
>> is not a business interest.
>>
>>
>>
>> The existing examples at the time were the landlord-tenant cases, all of
>> which involved small landlords. People could envision issues with kosher
>> butchers and Christian bookstores, and with the broad reach of some state
>> civil rights laws. Some state laws prohibit discrimination on the basis of
>> "any lawful off-the-job activity." Think the church secretary moonlighting
>> in an abortion clinic, or a strip club, or any other business that is
>> lawful but disreputable in the view of some.
>>
>> Same-sex marriage was on the far horizon; I don't recall anyone thinking
>> about wedding photographers and the like.
>>
>>
>>
>> I believed that as the business grows, it becomes less plausib

Re: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-20 Thread Marci Hamilton
As someone who was involved in RLPA in Congress from day one through many 
hearings, only a tortured reading of history supports the notion that Congress 
believed that its proponents believed RFRA should apply to for-profit 
organizations let alone that they intended it to. 

 Given current deadlines I cannot add more , but I look forward to reading 
Jim's piece and will be doing something of my own closer to the argument.

Marci



Marci A. Hamilton
Verkuil Chair in Public Law
Benjamin N. Cardozo Law School
Yeshiva University
@Marci_Hamilton 



> On Feb 20, 2014, at 12:34 PM, James Oleske  wrote:
> 
> I have a short essay coming out next month that offers a considerably 
> different take than Doug on both the legislative history of RLPA and the text 
> of the 1999 version of RLPA as compared to RFRA. A draft of the essay is 
> available here:
> 
> Obamacare, RFRA, and the Perils of Legislative History
> http://ssrn.com/abstract=2398763
> 
> The relevant discussion can be found on pages 5-10 of the draft. My 
> bottom-line conclusion is that "the 1998 and 1999 debates over RLPA fall far 
> short of demonstrating an 'undisputed public understanding that the language 
> in RFRA protected for-profit corporations and their owners.'" 
> 
> On the specific claim that the text of RFRA and RLPA were identical, I make 
> the same point I see Marty has made in his separate response to Doug -- the 
> 1999 RLPA has a "broad construction" provision that was in neither the 1998 
> RLPA or RFRA. Thus, the more relevant RLPA legislative history is the 1998 
> debate, not the 1999 debate Doug relies upon in the CLS amicus brief and his 
> SCOTUS Blog post. And the 1998 testimony casts considerable doubt on the 
> claim that large for-profit businesses are protected by RFRA.  
> 
> On a different note, I want to second Marty's recommendation of the symposium 
> over at SCOTUS Blog. Specifically, I highly recommend folks take a look at 
> Chip and Bob's piece, which makes an important argument calling for symmetry 
> between the treatment of employee accommodations under Title VII and employer 
> accommodations under RFRA (in both cases this avoids establishment concerns 
> raised by exemptions that impose more than de minimis burdens on others). 
> Chip and Bob's piece is available here: 
> http://www.scotusblog.com/2014/02/symposium-religious-questions-and-saving-constructions/
> 
> - Jim
> 
>> On Thu, Feb 20, 2014 at 7:30 AM, Douglas Laycock  
>> wrote:
>> I have not gone back to review all the RLPA testimony, but yes we did 
>> predict that large commercial businesses seeking religious exemptions from 
>> civil rights laws would generally lose.
>> 
>>  
>> 
>> The context of that testimony was civil rights claims. And it was a 
>> prediction of what the courts would do in fact, not a judgment about what 
>> they should do. But I would probably be comfortable with most of the results 
>> we predicted.
>> 
>>  
>> 
>> The kinds of civil rights claims RLPA’s supporters wanted to preserve mostly 
>> did not arise in business situations. Religious discrimination by religious 
>> organizations setting their criteria for membership, as in CLS v. Martinez, 
>> is rarely a legitimate business interest. Sex and marital-status 
>> discrimination in the ordination of a celibate male clergy is not a business 
>> interest.
>> 
>>  
>> 
>> The existing examples at the time were the landlord-tenant cases, all of 
>> which involved small landlords. People could envision issues with kosher 
>> butchers and Christian bookstores, and with the broad reach of some state 
>> civil rights laws. Some state laws prohibit discrimination on the basis of 
>> “any lawful off-the-job activity.” Think the church secretary moonlighting 
>> in an abortion clinic, or a strip club, or any other business that is lawful 
>> but disreputable in the view of some.
>> 
>> Same-sex marriage was on the far horizon; I don’t recall anyone thinking 
>> about wedding photographers and the like.
>> 
>>  
>> 
>> I believed that as the business grows, it becomes less plausible to view it 
>> as a personal extension of the owner. Mrs. Smith with two duplexes may feel 
>> morally responsible for every unit, and she may be doing all the work of 
>> leasing and maintenance herself. A landlord with multiple apartment 
>> complexes is less likely to feel that moral responsibility, and less likely 
>> to persuade a court that he does. He certainly does not have to become 
>> personally involved with what he considers the immoral use of his property 
>> by particular tenants. And as the business grows, the government’s interest 
>> grows.
>> 
>>  
>> 
>> I did not envision at the time, and I don’t know that anyone else did, a 
>> case like Hobby Lobby. Here the business is large, but it is closely held by 
>> devoutly religious and religiously unanimous owners. The government is 
>> demanding a decision that must be made at the level of senior management for 
>> the entire cor

Re: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-20 Thread James Oleske
I have a short essay coming out next month that offers a considerably
different take than Doug on both the legislative history of RLPA and the
text of the 1999 version of RLPA as compared to RFRA. A draft of the essay
is available here:

Obamacare, RFRA, and the Perils of Legislative History
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2398763

The relevant discussion can be found on pages 5-10 of the draft. My
bottom-line conclusion is that "the 1998 and 1999 debates over RLPA fall
far short of demonstrating an 'undisputed public understanding that the
language in RFRA protected for-profit corporations and their owners.'"

On the specific claim that the text of RFRA and RLPA were identical, I make
the same point I see Marty has made in his separate response to Doug -- the
1999 RLPA has a "broad construction" provision that was in neither the 1998
RLPA or RFRA. Thus, the more relevant RLPA legislative history is the 1998
debate, not the 1999 debate Doug relies upon in the CLS amicus brief and
his SCOTUS Blog post. And the 1998 testimony casts considerable doubt on
the claim that large for-profit businesses are protected by RFRA.

On a different note, I want to second Marty's recommendation of the
symposium over at SCOTUS Blog. Specifically, I highly recommend folks take
a look at Chip and Bob's piece, which makes an important argument calling
for symmetry between the treatment of employee accommodations under Title
VII and employer accommodations under RFRA (in both cases this avoids
establishment concerns raised by exemptions that impose more than de
minimis burdens on others). Chip and Bob's piece is available here:
http://www.scotusblog.com/2014/02/symposium-religious-questions-and-saving-constructions/

- Jim

On Thu, Feb 20, 2014 at 7:30 AM, Douglas Laycock wrote:

> I have not gone back to review all the RLPA testimony, but yes we did
> predict that large commercial businesses seeking religious exemptions from
> civil rights laws would generally lose.
>
>
>
> The context of that testimony was civil rights claims. And it was a
> prediction of what the courts would do in fact, not a judgment about what
> they should do. But I would probably be comfortable with most of the
> results we predicted.
>
>
>
> The kinds of civil rights claims RLPA's supporters wanted to preserve
> mostly did not arise in business situations. Religious discrimination by
> religious organizations setting their criteria for membership, as in *CLS
> v. Martinez*, is rarely a legitimate business interest. Sex and
> marital-status discrimination in the ordination of a celibate male clergy
> is not a business interest.
>
>
>
> The existing examples at the time were the landlord-tenant cases, all of
> which involved small landlords. People could envision issues with kosher
> butchers and Christian bookstores, and with the broad reach of some state
> civil rights laws. Some state laws prohibit discrimination on the basis of
> "any lawful off-the-job activity." Think the church secretary moonlighting
> in an abortion clinic, or a strip club, or any other business that is
> lawful but disreputable in the view of some.
>
> Same-sex marriage was on the far horizon; I don't recall anyone thinking
> about wedding photographers and the like.
>
>
>
> I believed that as the business grows, it becomes less plausible to view
> it as a personal extension of the owner. Mrs. Smith with two duplexes may
> feel morally responsible for every unit, and she may be doing all the work
> of leasing and maintenance herself. A landlord with multiple apartment
> complexes is less likely to feel that moral responsibility, and less likely
> to persuade a court that he does. He certainly does not have to become
> personally involved with what he considers the immoral use of his property
> by particular tenants. And as the business grows, the government's interest
> grows.
>
>
>
> I did not envision at the time, and I don't know that anyone else did, a
> case like *Hobby Lobby*. Here the business is large, but it is closely
> held by devoutly religious and religiously unanimous owners. The government
> is demanding a decision that must be made at the level of senior management
> for the entire corporation; in 1998 and 99, people were thinking about
> issues posed by one customer somewhere, to be dealt with by a rank-and-file
> employee where it arose. And the owners and senior management understand
> the decision the government wants to be profoundly evil - to require that
> they cause their corporation to pay for, contract for, arrange for, and
> provide to their employees and present as normal the option of killing
> innocent human beings. That's not my view of emergency contraception and
> IUDs, but it is theirs.
>
>
>
> I would not want a decision in *Hobby Lobby* limited to those facts, and
> I'm not sure where I would draw the line. But no one in 1998 and 1999 was
> thinking about, or predicting judicial reaction to, a case like this.
>
>
>
> Douglas Laycock
>
> Robert E. Scot

Re: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-20 Thread Marty Lederman
P.S.  None of this is germane to my principal point, which was simply that
it is a mistake to say that "If these plaintiffs will not pay for what they
believe to be such an extraordinary wrong, then in the government's view, *they
are barred from owning any business with more than fifty employees*."

One can certainly argue that federal law imposes substantial pressure *not
to drop one's employee plan*, and to instead include contraception coverage
(I disagree, but I understand the argument).  But *that *is the consequence
at issue -- *not* being "barred from owning any business with more than
fifty employees."


On Thu, Feb 20, 2014 at 11:56 AM, Marty Lederman
wrote:

> Quick responses to these two points:
>
> 1.  When I referred to differences between RLPA and RFRA, I was alluding
> to the amendment to RLPA at that time providing that "This Act should be
> construed in favor of a broad protection of religious exercise, *to the
> maximum extent permitted* *by its terms* and the Constitution."  IIRC,
> that amendment caused much consternation about how RLPA, much more than
> RFRA and the FEC, would lead to civil rights exemptions.
>
> 2.  Many thousands of employers will in fact drop (or decline to offer in
> the first instance) an employee health plan--so it's not remotely
> unthinkable; it's expected to occur quite frequently (although predictions
> vary on the percentages).  More to the point, *I *don't have to persuade
> you, nor does the government, that it is a "viable" option.  The burden is *on
> the plaintiffs *to demonstrate that federal law imposes substantial
> pressure on them *not* to drop their plans -- and they haven't introduced
> or alleged any evidence at all to that effect, let alone alleged facts that
> would survive *Iqbal/Trombley*.
>
> Moreover, even if the plaintiffs had alleged facts to demonstrate that
> *some* employees would be upset if the plan were dropped, so what?  There
> still wouldn't be proof (i) that federal law (as opposed to the
> Obama-hatred you invoke) would be the cause of that hatred; (ii) that a
> greater number of employees in the case of these employers wouldn't be
> *happier* with a combination of subsidized, full plans on the exchange
> and increased salaries; or (iii) most importantly, that any resulting
> employee resentment would impose *substantial pressure *on the companies
> to keep their plans, even if it meant including contraception coverage.
>
>
> On Thu, Feb 20, 2014 at 10:07 AM, Douglas Laycock 
> wrote:
>
>> Marty raises multiple issues here.
>>
>>
>>
>> *First*: The operative language of RLPA was identical to RFRA. They
>> inserted restrictions that limited the application of that language to
>> cases that affected commerce, arose in programs receiving federal financial
>> assistance, or involved individualized assessments of regulated activity.
>> They moved a modifying clause from the end of what it modified to the
>> beginning of what it modified. But on the section setting out exercise of
>> religion, substantial burden, compelling interest, and least restrictive
>> means, they changed nothing that could remotely have affected substance.
>>
>>
>>
>> *Second*: Employers could just drop health insurance, but I'm not sure
>> anyone but Marty is persuaded that that's a viable option. Certainly there
>> is no evidence in the record of either case showing that either employer
>> could drop health insurance, pay the fines, give the employees a big enough
>> raise that they could all bluy individual coverage on the exchanges, and
>> everyone breaks even or comes out ahead.
>>
>>
>>
>> Nor is there any reason to think that an employer could do this without
>> generating massive employee ill will and seriously damaging its competitive
>> position in the market place. For starters, all the people who hate Barack
>> Obama and anything he has ever touched or endorsed, and many of those who
>> oppose the Affordable Care Act on more rational grounds, would be furious
>> at being "dumped" into the exchanges. A very large minority of the
>> company's employees would be angry, and a very large minority of the
>> potential employment pool would view the employer as a much less desirable
>> place to work. Many employees of all political views might prefer that
>> their employer do the work of evaluating health plans and choosing a good
>> one, sparing them the burden.
>>
>>
>>
>> And for decades, a job with full benefits has been the marker of
>> first-tier employment; jobs without health insurance are distinctly
>> inferior. That may eventually change, when political passions have cooled,
>> when the exchanges are functioning smoothly, when their continuous
>> existence seems assured. But we certainly aren't there yet. An employer
>> following Marty's strategy would suffer serious damage in the employment
>> market, and suffer that damage for its owners' religious exercise. As in 
>> *Sherbert
>> v. Verner*, that economic damage is a burden on the underlying

Re: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-20 Thread Marty Lederman
Quick responses to these two points:

1.  When I referred to differences between RLPA and RFRA, I was alluding to
the amendment to RLPA at that time providing that "This Act should be
construed in favor of a broad protection of religious exercise, *to the
maximum extent permitted* *by its terms* and the Constitution."  IIRC, that
amendment caused much consternation about how RLPA, much more than RFRA and
the FEC, would lead to civil rights exemptions.

2.  Many thousands of employers will in fact drop (or decline to offer in
the first instance) an employee health plan--so it's not remotely
unthinkable; it's expected to occur quite frequently (although predictions
vary on the percentages).  More to the point, *I *don't have to persuade
you, nor does the government, that it is a "viable" option.  The burden is *on
the plaintiffs *to demonstrate that federal law imposes substantial
pressure on them *not* to drop their plans -- and they haven't introduced
or alleged any evidence at all to that effect, let alone alleged facts that
would survive *Iqbal/Trombley*.

Moreover, even if the plaintiffs had alleged facts to demonstrate that
*some* employees would be upset if the plan were dropped, so what?  There
still wouldn't be proof (i) that federal law (as opposed to the
Obama-hatred you invoke) would be the cause of that hatred; (ii) that a
greater number of employees in the case of these employers wouldn't be
*happier* with a combination of subsidized, full plans on the exchange and
increased salaries; or (iii) most importantly, that any resulting employee
resentment would impose *substantial pressure *on the companies to keep
their plans, even if it meant including contraception coverage.


On Thu, Feb 20, 2014 at 10:07 AM, Douglas Laycock wrote:

> Marty raises multiple issues here.
>
>
>
> *First*: The operative language of RLPA was identical to RFRA. They
> inserted restrictions that limited the application of that language to
> cases that affected commerce, arose in programs receiving federal financial
> assistance, or involved individualized assessments of regulated activity.
> They moved a modifying clause from the end of what it modified to the
> beginning of what it modified. But on the section setting out exercise of
> religion, substantial burden, compelling interest, and least restrictive
> means, they changed nothing that could remotely have affected substance.
>
>
>
> *Second*: Employers could just drop health insurance, but I'm not sure
> anyone but Marty is persuaded that that's a viable option. Certainly there
> is no evidence in the record of either case showing that either employer
> could drop health insurance, pay the fines, give the employees a big enough
> raise that they could all bluy individual coverage on the exchanges, and
> everyone breaks even or comes out ahead.
>
>
>
> Nor is there any reason to think that an employer could do this without
> generating massive employee ill will and seriously damaging its competitive
> position in the market place. For starters, all the people who hate Barack
> Obama and anything he has ever touched or endorsed, and many of those who
> oppose the Affordable Care Act on more rational grounds, would be furious
> at being "dumped" into the exchanges. A very large minority of the
> company's employees would be angry, and a very large minority of the
> potential employment pool would view the employer as a much less desirable
> place to work. Many employees of all political views might prefer that
> their employer do the work of evaluating health plans and choosing a good
> one, sparing them the burden.
>
>
>
> And for decades, a job with full benefits has been the marker of
> first-tier employment; jobs without health insurance are distinctly
> inferior. That may eventually change, when political passions have cooled,
> when the exchanges are functioning smoothly, when their continuous
> existence seems assured. But we certainly aren't there yet. An employer
> following Marty's strategy would suffer serious damage in the employment
> market, and suffer that damage for its owners' religious exercise. As in 
> *Sherbert
> v. Verner*, that economic damage is a burden on the underlying  religious
> exercise.
>
>
>
> *Third* is the testimony supporting RLPA in 98 and 99. I'll put that in a
> separate post.
>
>
>
> Douglas Laycock
>
> Robert E. Scott Distinguished Professor of Law
>
> University of Virginia Law School
>
> 580 Massie Road
>
> Charlottesville, VA  22903
>
>  434-243-8546
>
>
>
> *From:* religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu [mailto:
> religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu] *On Behalf Of *Marty Lederman
> *Sent:* Wednesday, February 19, 2014 10:33 PM
> *To:* Law & Religion issues for Law Academics
> *Subject:* recommended Hobby Lobby posts
>
>
>
> I have some further posts up on Balkinization.  More importantly, both
> Chip Lupu/Bob Tuttle and Doug Laycock have excellent posts up as part of
> the SCOTUSblog symposium, which I commend to all of yo

Re: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-20 Thread Marty Lederman
I'm a bit confused by Doug's explanation of why this case is different from
the civil rights cases that he testified the state would (and usually
should) win.  I don't share Doug's view of how to characterize what the
Greens are required to do here (see my many posts); but for now, let's
assume he's right, and that this law would in effect coerce the Greens to
do something their religion prohibits.

OK, but that was true in the civil rights cases, too -- no one denied, even
in *Piggy Park*, that the owners/landlords, etc., believed they were being
coerced to cooperate in evil, in a way their religion prohibited.  In other
words, those cases -- the ones Doug thinks the state would and (usually)
should win -- involved a much clearer case of a substantial burden on
religious exercise.

I had expected Doug to say instead that the difference in the cases was on
the government interest side of the line.  Is that not what's driving most
people's instincts here -- that the state interest here is thought by many
(albeit wrongly, in my view) to be less compelling than the interest in
preventing discrimination?


On Thu, Feb 20, 2014 at 10:30 AM, Douglas Laycock wrote:

> I have not gone back to review all the RLPA testimony, but yes we did
> predict that large commercial businesses seeking religious exemptions from
> civil rights laws would generally lose.
>
>
>
> The context of that testimony was civil rights claims. And it was a
> prediction of what the courts would do in fact, not a judgment about what
> they should do. But I would probably be comfortable with most of the
> results we predicted.
>
>
>
> The kinds of civil rights claims RLPA's supporters wanted to preserve
> mostly did not arise in business situations. Religious discrimination by
> religious organizations setting their criteria for membership, as in *CLS
> v. Martinez*, is rarely a legitimate business interest. Sex and
> marital-status discrimination in the ordination of a celibate male clergy
> is not a business interest.
>
>
>
> The existing examples at the time were the landlord-tenant cases, all of
> which involved small landlords. People could envision issues with kosher
> butchers and Christian bookstores, and with the broad reach of some state
> civil rights laws. Some state laws prohibit discrimination on the basis of
> "any lawful off-the-job activity." Think the church secretary moonlighting
> in an abortion clinic, or a strip club, or any other business that is
> lawful but disreputable in the view of some.
>
> Same-sex marriage was on the far horizon; I don't recall anyone thinking
> about wedding photographers and the like.
>
>
>
> I believed that as the business grows, it becomes less plausible to view
> it as a personal extension of the owner. Mrs. Smith with two duplexes may
> feel morally responsible for every unit, and she may be doing all the work
> of leasing and maintenance herself. A landlord with multiple apartment
> complexes is less likely to feel that moral responsibility, and less likely
> to persuade a court that he does. He certainly does not have to become
> personally involved with what he considers the immoral use of his property
> by particular tenants. And as the business grows, the government's interest
> grows.
>
>
>
> I did not envision at the time, and I don't know that anyone else did, a
> case like *Hobby Lobby*. Here the business is large, but it is closely
> held by devoutly religious and religiously unanimous owners. The government
> is demanding a decision that must be made at the level of senior management
> for the entire corporation; in 1998 and 99, people were thinking about
> issues posed by one customer somewhere, to be dealt with by a rank-and-file
> employee where it arose. And the owners and senior management understand
> the decision the government wants to be profoundly evil - to require that
> they cause their corporation to pay for, contract for, arrange for, and
> provide to their employees and present as normal the option of killing
> innocent human beings. That's not my view of emergency contraception and
> IUDs, but it is theirs.
>
>
>
> I would not want a decision in *Hobby Lobby* limited to those facts, and
> I'm not sure where I would draw the line. But no one in 1998 and 1999 was
> thinking about, or predicting judicial reaction to, a case like this.
>
>
>
> Douglas Laycock
>
> Robert E. Scott Distinguished Professor of Law
>
> University of Virginia Law School
>
> 580 Massie Road
>
> Charlottesville, VA  22903
>
>  434-243-8546
>
>
>
> *From:* religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu [mailto:
> religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu] *On Behalf Of *Marty Lederman
> *Sent:* Wednesday, February 19, 2014 10:33 PM
> *To:* Law & Religion issues for Law Academics
> *Subject:* recommended Hobby Lobby posts
>
>
>
> I have some further posts up on Balkinization.  More importantly, both
> Chip Lupu/Bob Tuttle and Doug Laycock have excellent posts up as part of
> the SCOTUSblog symposium, which I co

RE: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-20 Thread Douglas Laycock
I have not gone back to review all the RLPA testimony, but yes we did
predict that large commercial businesses seeking religious exemptions from
civil rights laws would generally lose.

 

The context of that testimony was civil rights claims. And it was a
prediction of what the courts would do in fact, not a judgment about what
they should do. But I would probably be comfortable with most of the results
we predicted.

 

The kinds of civil rights claims RLPA's supporters wanted to preserve mostly
did not arise in business situations. Religious discrimination by religious
organizations setting their criteria for membership, as in CLS v. Martinez,
is rarely a legitimate business interest. Sex and marital-status
discrimination in the ordination of a celibate male clergy is not a business
interest. 

 

The existing examples at the time were the landlord-tenant cases, all of
which involved small landlords. People could envision issues with kosher
butchers and Christian bookstores, and with the broad reach of some state
civil rights laws. Some state laws prohibit discrimination on the basis of
"any lawful off-the-job activity." Think the church secretary moonlighting
in an abortion clinic, or a strip club, or any other business that is lawful
but disreputable in the view of some. 

Same-sex marriage was on the far horizon; I don't recall anyone thinking
about wedding photographers and the like. 

 

I believed that as the business grows, it becomes less plausible to view it
as a personal extension of the owner. Mrs. Smith with two duplexes may feel
morally responsible for every unit, and she may be doing all the work of
leasing and maintenance herself. A landlord with multiple apartment
complexes is less likely to feel that moral responsibility, and less likely
to persuade a court that he does. He certainly does not have to become
personally involved with what he considers the immoral use of his property
by particular tenants. And as the business grows, the government's interest
grows.

 

I did not envision at the time, and I don't know that anyone else did, a
case like Hobby Lobby. Here the business is large, but it is closely held by
devoutly religious and religiously unanimous owners. The government is
demanding a decision that must be made at the level of senior management for
the entire corporation; in 1998 and 99, people were thinking about issues
posed by one customer somewhere, to be dealt with by a rank-and-file
employee where it arose. And the owners and senior management understand the
decision the government wants to be profoundly evil - to require that they
cause their corporation to pay for, contract for, arrange for, and provide
to their employees and present as normal the option of killing innocent
human beings. That's not my view of emergency contraception and IUDs, but it
is theirs.

 

I would not want a decision in Hobby Lobby limited to those facts, and I'm
not sure where I would draw the line. But no one in 1998 and 1999 was
thinking about, or predicting judicial reaction to, a case like this.

 

Douglas Laycock

Robert E. Scott Distinguished Professor of Law

University of Virginia Law School

580 Massie Road

Charlottesville, VA  22903

 434-243-8546

 

From: religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu
[mailto:religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu] On Behalf Of Marty Lederman
Sent: Wednesday, February 19, 2014 10:33 PM
To: Law & Religion issues for Law Academics
Subject: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

 

I have some further posts up on Balkinization.  More importantly, both Chip
Lupu/Bob Tuttle and Doug Laycock have excellent posts up as part of the
SCOTUSblog symposium, which I commend to all of you:

Chip/Bob:
http://www.scotusblog.com/2014/02/symposium-religious-questions-and-saving-c
onstructions/

Doug:
http://www.scotusblog.com/2014/02/symposium-congress-answered-this-question-
corporations-are-covered/

I have questions/reactions to a couple of things in Doug's post:

First, Doug argues that many or all members of Congress during the RLPA
debate assumed that the bill, which at the time was similar (but not
identical) to RFRA, would at least allow for-profit corporations or their
directors/owners to bring claims.  But as I recall, Doug and others also
reassured members of Congress, in public testimony, that large for-profit
companies would always or almost always lose under RLPA.  Doug, do you think
this is one of the rare or exceptional cases where the large for-profit
plaintiffs should win, and, if so, why is this the outlier?

Second, Doug writes that "If these plaintiffs will not pay for what they
believe to be such an extraordinary wrong, then in the government's view,
they are barred from owning any business with more than fifty employees."
But it is simply not true that the consequence of excluding contraception
from the plan would be that the plaintiffs are "barred from owning any
business with more than fifty employees."  Even if the company had fewer
than 50 employees, its pl

RE: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

2014-02-20 Thread Douglas Laycock
Marty raises multiple issues here.

 

First: The operative language of RLPA was identical to RFRA. They inserted
restrictions that limited the application of that language to cases that
affected commerce, arose in programs receiving federal financial assistance,
or involved individualized assessments of regulated activity. They moved a
modifying clause from the end of what it modified to the beginning of what
it modified. But on the section setting out exercise of religion,
substantial burden, compelling interest, and least restrictive means, they
changed nothing that could remotely have affected substance.

 

Second: Employers could just drop health insurance, but I'm not sure anyone
but Marty is persuaded that that's a viable option. Certainly there is no
evidence in the record of either case showing that either employer could
drop health insurance, pay the fines, give the employees a big enough raise
that they could all bluy individual coverage on the exchanges, and everyone
breaks even or comes out ahead. 

 

Nor is there any reason to think that an employer could do this without
generating massive employee ill will and seriously damaging its competitive
position in the market place. For starters, all the people who hate Barack
Obama and anything he has ever touched or endorsed, and many of those who
oppose the Affordable Care Act on more rational grounds, would be furious at
being "dumped" into the exchanges. A very large minority of the company's
employees would be angry, and a very large minority of the potential
employment pool would view the employer as a much less desirable place to
work. Many employees of all political views might prefer that their employer
do the work of evaluating health plans and choosing a good one, sparing them
the burden.

 

And for decades, a job with full benefits has been the marker of first-tier
employment; jobs without health insurance are distinctly inferior. That may
eventually change, when political passions have cooled, when the exchanges
are functioning smoothly, when their continuous existence seems assured. But
we certainly aren't there yet. An employer following Marty's strategy would
suffer serious damage in the employment market, and suffer that damage for
its owners' religious exercise. As in Sherbert v. Verner, that economic
damage is a burden on the underlying  religious exercise.

 

Third is the testimony supporting RLPA in 98 and 99. I'll put that in a
separate post.

 

Douglas Laycock

Robert E. Scott Distinguished Professor of Law

University of Virginia Law School

580 Massie Road

Charlottesville, VA  22903

 434-243-8546

 

From: religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu
[mailto:religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu] On Behalf Of Marty Lederman
Sent: Wednesday, February 19, 2014 10:33 PM
To: Law & Religion issues for Law Academics
Subject: recommended Hobby Lobby posts

 

I have some further posts up on Balkinization.  More importantly, both Chip
Lupu/Bob Tuttle and Doug Laycock have excellent posts up as part of the
SCOTUSblog symposium, which I commend to all of you:

Chip/Bob:
http://www.scotusblog.com/2014/02/symposium-religious-questions-and-saving-c
onstructions/

Doug:
http://www.scotusblog.com/2014/02/symposium-congress-answered-this-question-
corporations-are-covered/

I have questions/reactions to a couple of things in Doug's post:

First, Doug argues that many or all members of Congress during the RLPA
debate assumed that the bill, which at the time was similar (but not
identical) to RFRA, would at least allow for-profit corporations or their
directors/owners to bring claims.  But as I recall, Doug and others also
reassured members of Congress, in public testimony, that large for-profit
companies would always or almost always lose under RLPA.  Doug, do you think
this is one of the rare or exceptional cases where the large for-profit
plaintiffs should win, and, if so, why is this the outlier?

Second, Doug writes that "If these plaintiffs will not pay for what they
believe to be such an extraordinary wrong, then in the government's view,
they are barred from owning any business with more than fifty employees."
But it is simply not true that the consequence of excluding contraception
from the plan would be that the plaintiffs are "barred from owning any
business with more than fifty employees."  Even if the company had fewer
than 50 employees, its plan would still have to include contraception.  If
any employer, with fewer or more than fifty employees, does not wish to
include all required services in an employee benefit plan, it has two
choices:  either be subject to prohibitive payments (in effect fines) or get
rid of their employee plan (in which case most of their employees would be
eligible for a subsidized plan on an exchange).  A more accurate way of
stating the law would be:  "If these plaintiffs, or any other employers, do
not include coverage in their companies' plans for what they believe to be
such an extraordinary wrong, the